A new approach to SSDI reform: more people with disabilities would return to work if they faced better incentives.
Gokhale, Jagadeesh
The Social Security Disability Insurance (SSDI) program is rapidly
approaching insolvency. According to the Social Security Trustees, the
program-s trust fund will be exhausted sometime in early 2016, forcing a
reduction in financial support for individuals with a disability.
Although many lawmakers in Congress appreciate this problem, most of
them appear unwilling to propose reforms to the program. One explanation
for this inaction is the availability of an easy short-term fix:
temporarily transferring funds from SSDI's larger companion trust
fund, the Social Security Old Age and Survivor Insurance (OASI) program.
According to the Trustees, the OASI Trust Fund will not be exhausted
until 2034. Were a temporary transfer made from the OASI to the SSDI
trust fund, the combined (OASDI) trust funds would not be exhausted
until 2033.
Another explanation for congressional inaction is that the two
major political parties are so far apart on how to reform SSDI that
there is little chance of developing a workable coalition. Some
Republicans and conservatives may view the program as riddled with
loopholes, subjective decisionmaking, and a predilection for unwarranted
allowances on the part of adjudicators using flawed evaluation
procedures. (See "What Should We Do about Social Security
Disability?" Fall 2011; "What We Should Do about Social
Security Disability," Spring 2012.) They may also believe that many
undeserving claimants exist on SSDI rolls and many work-capable
individuals are being allowed onto the program. Some Democrats and
liberals, however, appear to believe that the program is operating as
intended, the overall allowance rate is not excessive, and claim
procedures take too long. They may also believe that benefit levels are
too low and individuals with disabilities are ill-served by having to
wait many months before becoming eligible for monetary benefits and two
years before obtaining access to health care under the program's
rules.
Although SSDI keeps many people out of poverty, it continues to be
beset with poor performance along many dimensions. Applications and
enrollments have been growing from the after-effects of the recession,
population aging, and poor (ex-post) policy compliance, including
inadequate Continuing Disability Reviews (CDR) of beneficiaries'
medical status to determine if they should continue to receive SSDI
benefits. This does not reflect poor intentions and ability on the part
of SSDI adjudicators as much as the difficulty of determining whether a
person is truly disabled within a system that allows only a "yes or
no" distinction and one that involves subjective evaluations of
mental and musculoskeletal impairments. As a result, many commentators
today believe that a significant number of SSDI beneficiaries have work
capabilities, but beneficiaries are unwilling to participate in the work
force because they face a steep "cash cliff": the loss of
benefits and valuable health care coverage if they work and earn above
the Substantial Gainful Activity (SGA) level, currently $1,040 per
month.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The unwillingness of work-capable SSDI beneficiaries to join the
labor force implies losses to the economy in terms of lost output,
reductions in tax revenues for the government, and most significantly
the loss of gainful careers for younger work-capable beneficiaries.
Those lost careers mean the loss of a number of important benefits,
including higher incomes and living standards, participation in
community activities through work, and the psychological benefit of
enhanced self-worth that accompanies gainful employment.
Encouraging the Return to Work
The Social Security Administration (SSA) is charged with
discovering beneficiaries whose medical condition has improved and
exploring ways to incentivize those beneficiaries to seek gainful
employment. SSA's CDR program is intended to examine and detect
cases of medical improvement among SSDI beneficiaries and remove those
who have recovered sufficiently so that they no longer meet SSDI's
definition of disability. SSA has, however, accumulated a substantial
backlog of CDR cases as other workloads increased when the recent
recession began.
The SSA provides the Ticket to Work program to new beneficiaries,
offering counseling and vocational rehabilitation services to those who
may wish to pursue job opportunities despite their disabilities. As was
expected, the take-up rate on Ticket to Work has been very low. However,
a sizable number of SSDI beneficiaries appear to have work abilities and
could re-engage in the work force if not for the disincentive created by
the cash cliff. Most work-capable beneficiaries are unwilling to
jeopardize their eligibility for SSDI's monetary and health
benefits by working beyond the SGA earnings level as insurance against a
relapse of their disabling medical conditions or loss of labor-market
opportunities.
To examine the likelihood of re-engaging SSDI beneficiaries in the
work force through a better incentive system, the SSA has been
conducting demonstration projects to assess the work capabilities of
SSDI beneficiaries. These demonstrations replace the cash cliff with a
more gradual reduction in benefits (a "benefit offset") as
SSDI beneficiaries' earnings increase. The projects assess
increases in employment rates, average earnings, and the fraction of
beneficiaries earning above the SGA level.
Unfortunately, the results from these assessments are not as
conclusive as was initially expected. One reason for this may be that
the benefit offset design does not provide a sufficiently robust work
incentive to SSDI beneficiaries. Moreover, as will be explained below,
eliminating the cash cliff makes existing SSDI benefits inframarginal to
beneficiaries' decisions about whether and how much to work and
earn, which may increase their reservation wages for entering the job
market.
This article proposes a different approach to providing work
incentives to SSDI beneficiaries, one that involves benefit offsets but
provides greater flexibility to beneficiaries in selecting their level
of work activity. The Generalized Benefit Offset (GBO) program that I
propose would eliminate the cash cliff, but it conditions the change on
observed earnings. GBO allows reversion to beneficiary status when labor
force attachments cease, at the full discretion of SSDI beneficiaries.
The sections that follow describe the results from the SSA's
benefit offset demonstrations, provide analytical justification for
GBO's new approach, and discuss how to operationalize GBO by
introducing its benefit schedule several months after a claimant has
been allowed onto SSDI's rolls.
SSDI Pilots and Demonstration Projects
Two investigations conducted by the SSA explore the effects of
offering a "benefit offset" to SSDI beneficiaries: the Benefit
Offset Pilot Demonstration (BOPD) and its broader follow-up, the Benefit
Offset National Demonstration (BOND).
BOPD studied the effect of replacing the steep loss of benefits
consequent to working above SGA with a"$1-for-$2" offset. That
is, benefits would be reduced by $1 for every $2 of earnings above SGA
after a nine-month trial work period. The gradual reduction of benefits
eliminated the cash cliff and BOPD's designers believed it would
incentivize more SSDI beneficiaries to enter the work force at
higher-than-SGA earnings levels.
The SSA staff certainly expected to see strong effects from
providing the $1-for-$2 benefit offset rate. Unfortunately, the results
from BOPD projects that were implemented in four states were not stellar
and were more variable than seems reasonable.
Responses to the $1-for-$2 benefit offset from the treatment group
compared to the control group were very weak in Wisconsin's BOPD:
average earnings differences (treatment minus control) were mostly
negative, overall employment rate differences were close to zero, and
the rate of above-SGA earnings was higher for the treatment group by
just 2 percentage points (17 versus 15 percent). In Vermont's BOPD,
the $1,256 per-month average earnings for the treatment group were
marginally higher (by $51); the rate of above-SGA earnings was also only
marginally higher (18 versus 15 percent), as was the overall employment
rate (49 versus 47 percent). The Utah BOPD yielded larger outcome
differences between the two groups: by the end of the trial, treatment
group mean earnings were higher by more than $245 per month; the rate of
above-SGA earnings was higher by 5 percentage points (19.5 versus 14.5
percent); and the overall employment rate was also higher by 4
percentage points (47 versus 43 percent). The strongest results, by far,
were obtained from the Connecticut BOPD, with the rate of above-SGA
earnings for the treatment group being 12 percentage points above that
of the control group (29 versus 17 percent), on average. At $2,115, mean
earnings were $410 higher for the treatment group, but the difference in
employment rates was just 3.5 percentage points (64 percent versus 61
percent).
The four-state BOPD results exhibit high variability and therefore
do not seem as reliable as policymakers are likely to demand. The
general conclusion from the BOPD study was that a benefit offset can
have a significant, large, and enduring effect on the SGA rate of
certain beneficiaries, but the effect may be limited to a subset of
individuals who are more able and/or more motivated to work than the
average SSDI beneficiary. The pilot also had drawbacks: Those SSDI
beneficiaries who were more than 72 months beyond the end of their trial
work period--a grace period during which the SSA does not eliminate
benefits despite working and earning more than the SGA level--were
excluded from enrollment. This may have eliminated the most persistent
earners among SSDI beneficiaries. However, beneficiaries knew that BOPD
was time-limited and may, therefore, have been unwilling to commit to
higher-paying career paths. Finally, BOPD's implementation of the
offset treatment was hampered by technical issues and beneficiaries may
have avoided earning more because of fears of repeated errors that would
endanger critical state and federal benefits on which they depended.
The four-state BOPD trials were marginally successful and suggested
the need for a broader demonstration project. Unfortunately, the
SSA's follow-up BOND investigation has been a failure. Out of more
than 77,000 treatment group participants, the BOND take-up was a
miserable 21 cases. This project is known to be riddled with
methodological and technical defects that compromise the quality of its
treatment and control beneficiary samples, ultimately generating poor
results. Several groups of disability advocates, policy practitioners,
and even nonpartisan groups, including the Social Security Advisory
Board, are now advocating that BOND be terminated.
A Better Approach
The relatively weak boost to employment and earnings generated by
the $1-for-S2 offset policy is not surprising. That benefit offset
design actually provides a relatively strong work disincentive at the
margin. The attempt is to trade-off elimination of a huge marginal
disincentive to work--the cash cliff prospect of losing all SSDI
benefits for exceeding SGA earnings by even $1--against the prospect of
losing only $1 for every $2 earned above SGA. The problem is that one
marginal disincentive to work, the cash cliff, is replaced by another,
the $1-for-S2 benefit offset that represents a high (S0 percent)
marginal tax rate on beneficiaries' earnings.
The BOPD's weak results should have indicated that, at the
margin, a 50 percent marginal tax rate on earnings also generates a
sizable disincentive to work, especially for those with a disability.
This switch from the cash cliff to the $1-for-$2 deal makes existing
SSDI benefits (including health care coverage) inframarginal, thereby
worsening the rate at which beneficiaries would be willing to exchange
more work for more dollars. Even at low resource levels, those with
disabilities are likely to require substantial compensation at the
margin to induce labor force attachments.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Applying standard consumer-preference analysis, Figure 1 explains
this reasoning in greater detail: The x-axis in Figure 1 represents the
daily time endowment, T, of 24 hours. Points further to the left on the
x-axis represent greater time devoted to non-work activities, called
"leisure" for short (though it includes "personal
time" that is relatively inflexibly devoted to sleep and personal
care). The vertical line marked A0 reflects the assumption that even
those without disabilities require leisure time of at least 10 hours per
day, cutting the daily time endowment that is potentially available for
market work to 14 hours.
In Figure 1, the disability of an SSDI beneficiary with residual
work capacity is characterized as an expansion of the inflexible
"personal time" portion of the day and a corresponding
shrinkage of the hours potentially available for market work. This
reflects the additional, inflexible "personal time" required
to take care of disabling conditions. Two alternative cases of this type
are depicted as the vertical lines marked A1 and A2. Compared to A1, a
person at A2 has a disability that leaves less time for market work.
Under current SSDI rules, a beneficiary who is receiving benefits
of $B per day can work and earn up to the SGA level of earnings and
continue to receive $B from the program. However, if earnings in excess
of the SGA level are sustained beyond the trial work period (which lasts
for nine months after the first excess-earnings occurrence), SSDI
benefits are suspended and eventually terminated. This policy implies
that SSDI beneficiaries eventually face a cash cliff at the SGA level of
earnings. Figure 1 shows this at point P with daily income at $B + $SGA:
At the market wage rate available (shown by the slope of the budget line
WW'), working for S hours yields the SGA level of earnings.
Increasing earning beyond SGA by even $1 more by working for more than S
hours (moving leftward on the x-axis from point T - S) pushes the
beneficiary to point CC (the cash cliff point on the budget line
TT', which is parallel to WW' but starts at $0 instead of $B)
as the daily SSDI benefit of $B is eliminated. The cash cliff,
therefore, induces many work-capable SSDI beneficiaries to
"park" at point P--that is, they work and earn no more than
the SGA level. Were the cash cliff absent--that is, were they
unconditionally eligible to work as much as they could with no loss of
eligibility to SSDI benefits, those who could (those able to work more,
shown by the vertical line A1) would choose work at point [E.sub.0],
with a much higher welfare level shown by the welfare curve [IC.sup.3] .
Note that the welfare level [IC.sup.3] is higher than that passing
though point P ([IC.sup.1]).
Providing a benefit offset for earnings beyond the SGA level
implies offering the tradeoff represented by the budget line OO'
(to the left of point P). Additional work and (gross) earnings along the
budget line WW' are offset by reducing benefits by $1 for each $2
of additional earnings. Because OO' incorporates a marginal tax
rate of 50 percent, its smaller gradient implies tangency with the
beneficiary's indifference curve IC2 at a point ([E.sub.1])
involving less work effort than at [E.sub.0]. Thus, a benefit offset of
the type incorporated in the BOPD and BOND demonstrations would not be
expected to produce strong labor market responses by beneficiaries.
First, to the extent that beneficiaries generally require larger
compensation increases to elicit a given amount of work effort (their
indifference curves are likely to be steeper), the offer of a benefit
offset of OO' would cause their optimal choice point ([E.sub.1]) to
be closer to P. Second, the fact that the existing SSDI benefit ($B) is
rendered inframarginal under BOPD and BOND also reduces their most
preferred work choices in response to the benefit offset (points such as
[E.sub.1]) closer to P.
There is unlikely to be political support to provide unconditional benefits to those on SSDI's rolls (to allow access to [E.sub.0]).
After all, SSDI is an insurance program to protect people with a
sufficient work history against the loss of earnings (and health
coverage) from developing a work-disabling condition. Providing
unconditional benefits to those who were found eligible for SSDI would
be in direct conflict with SSDI's eligibility requirements. And it
would be a policy that could cause a surge of SSDI applications even by
work-capable individuals with physical or mental impairments that may
not meet SSDI's definition of disability. At best, that policy
would cause SSA's processing costs to spiral from such induced
entry into the SSDI program. At worst (if many of those induced to apply
are also allowed onto SSDI's rolls), it would increase taxpayer
burdens from providing unconditional benefits to a growing number of
beneficiaries who are work-capable or who eventually recover close to
full work capacity.
However, the cash cliff that the current policy incorporates
discourages partially work-capable beneficiaries from participating in
the work force, a situation that Congress has sought to ameliorate. The
Ticket to Work program and benefit offset demonstration projects were
designed to explore ways of incentivizing work-capable SSDI
beneficiaries to return to work. As already noted, those efforts have
fallen short of expectations, producing only marginal increases in the
labor force attachments of SSDI beneficiaries beyond the SGA level.
Proposal: The Generalized Benefit Offset
The way to improve upon the benefit offsets offered to SSDI
beneficiaries becomes clear once it is recognized that the $1-for-$2
benefit offset, albeit a better option compared to the current cash
cliff, is itself a relatively poor work incentive because it involves a
marginal tax on earnings of 50 percent. The resulting increase in work
effort beyond SGA for someone with a minor disability (shown by vertical
line A1 in Figure 1) is much smaller (point [E.sub.1]) than the
potential increase in work effort (point [E.sub.0]). This result arises
because under a simple benefit offset, current SSDI benefits become
inframarginal, which increases the marginal compensation (at points
northward along any vertical line from the x-axis) that the beneficiary
requires to provide additional work effort. The key is to trade off
inframarginal SSDI benefits for a more generous benefit offset. This is
shown in Figure 2 by the budget line DD'.
Under the GBO offer shown by budget line DD' in Figure 2, SSDI
benefits are reduced (point D is below point W = $B) but the benefit
offset is a more generous $1-for-$4 instead of $1-for-$2. By reducing
SSDI benefits by a small amount (W- D), the work-capable beneficiary
would work as much as he wants above SGA along DD', the most
preferred choice being the tangency point of the indifference curve
[IC.sub.2] with the budget line DD' at [E.sub.2]. Figure 2 shows
that this choice involves more work than under the simple $1-for-$2
benefit offset at SGA (point [E.sub.1]). This is the result of removing
the "wealth effect" (by reducing inframarginal benefits) from
the total "price effect" of an improved benefit offset rate.
The remaining "substitution effect" (movement from [E.sub.1]
to [E.sub.2]) would make the beneficiary willing to be more active on
the labor market.
Under GBO, the beneficiary is offered a schedule of choices: either
remain disengaged from the work force with a benefit of $B or work and
earn along the budget line DD' involving a small reduction in
initial SSDI benefits and a $1-for-$4 benefit offset. This more
marginally generous benefit offset will induce those with the A1 work
time availability to work at point [E.sub.2]. Note that at this point,
SSDI beneficiaries would receive the same welfare level, [IC.sup.2], as
those disabled who were offered the $1-for-$2 benefit offset beginning
at the SGA benefit level (at point [E.sub.1] along budget line
PO'). Those with work time availability at, A2 would choose a
feasible point that is lower along the DD' budget line (at the
intersection of A2 and the budget line DD' in Figure 2). The GBO
schedule of initial benefits and benefit offsets offered to SSDI
beneficiaries would incentivize beneficiaries to sort along the DD'
budget line, providing the amount of market labor supply consistent with
maximizing their welfare level.
Indeed, the GBO schedule presented thus far could be improved by
adding more elements as shown in Figure 3. For example, adding the offer
shown by the budget line FF' would involve a steeper reduction in
initial benefits but an even more generous benefit offset. Indeed, the
marginal benefit offset may even be negative in that working and earning
fetches a subsidy much like the federal Earned Income Credit (EIC)
program subsidizes earnings at very low levels. Along FF', SSDI
beneficiaries' initial benefit would be reduced by about 50
percent, but they would receive a subsidy of $1 for each $6 earned. On
this schedule, beneficiaries for whom it is feasible would choose to
work and earn at point [E.sub.3].
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Finally, those beneficiaries who have very limited work potential
may benefit from an offer of GG'. This offer involves an increase
in the initial benefit but a much less generous benefit offset. Under
GG', for example, the initial SSDI benefit is increased by 50
percent, but earnings are subject to an 80 percent ($4-for-$5) marginal
tax rate. Those with limited work potential could work and earn at point
[E.sub.4], involving only a slight increase in earnings above SGA. But
their living conditions would be better from the inframarginal increase
in SSDI benefits.
Described thus far, GBO still has a problem of inducing a
separation of beneficiaries according to their work abilities. In Figure
3, the different GBO offers are intended to induce SSDI beneficiaries to
separate along different work and earnings levels shown as points
[E.sub.1] through [E.sub.4]. However, in the hypothetical example of
Figure 3, all of those points yield the same welfare level of
[IC.sup.2]. Thus there is nothing to prevent a beneficiary with high
work capability to select point [E.sub.4] (with high initial benefits
but with a higher marginal tax rate) instead of point [E.sub.3].
This is the so-called information revelation problem of providing a
set of incentive-compatible offers that would induce beneficiaries to
sort across the available schedule of GBO offers according to their work
abilities and preferences. Incorporating incentive compatibility across
the offer schedule requires the payment of a premium to the most
work-capable to ensure that their work choices remain effectively
distinct from the choices of those who are less work-capable. This calls
for a set of GBO offers shown in Figure 4.
In Figure 4, the four budget lines [S.sub.1], [S.sub.2], [S.sub.3],
and [S.sub.4] indicate elements of a GBO schedule, each with a different
combination of an initial benefit reductions and benefit offset (or
earnings subsidy) intensity. Each successive element involves a larger
reduction in initial benefits combined with a more generous benefit
offset. The tradeoffs are designed to provide those with larger
work-abilities or capacities to achieve a higher welfare level than
those less capable to work. Thus, beneficiaries who are more
work-capable and could work and earn at point [E.sub.1] would not choose
to be at any of the other three points, [E.sub.2], [E.sub.3], or
[E.sub.4].
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Of course, one could argue that such a schedule of offers could be
designed only if the underlying structure of work abilities and
preferences of SSDI beneficiaries--how much more they would be able and
willing to work for given additional compensation at different initial
benefit levels--were known with certainty. In reality, different
beneficiaries will differ in terms of their work potentials (the amount
of time that they could potentially devote to labor market activity) and
in their willingness to trade work time for dollars (the shape of their
indifference mappings between time use and compensation).
Lacking definitive distributional information about the severity of
disabilities and beneficiaries' preferences structures, how could
one design a GBO-style post-entitlement SSDI reform? The answer is
simply to mimic private sector providers in residential and commercial
property, vehicular, health, and other insurance sectors. In these
industries, insurance contracts provide property owners with a range of
pre-determined combinations of deductibles and premium rates. The
choices are designed so that clients would sort themselves according to
their types: risky, moderately risky, or safe (alternatively, in the
health insurance sector, those with chronic conditions, moderately
healthy, and healthy). The latter types would select high-deductible
policies with low premium rates and the former types would select
low-deductible policies with high premiums, provided that the schedule
of choices contains sufficient diversity to induce such separation among
clients. That is, the contract schedule's high deductible policies
have sufficiently lower premium rates to attract the low risk (or
healthy) types but not the riskier (less healthy) clients. In the case
of SSDI, designing a schedule of GBO offers should also be feasible to
provide better living conditions to those with almost no work ability
and stronger work incentives to those capable of devoting more time to
market work. Based on these considerations, the U.S. Congress should
alter SSDI's benefit schedule to incorporate such potentially
incentive-compatible offers for both current beneficiaries and new
entrants.
Operationalizing GBO
The GBO schedule should be designed to be sufficiently generous in
the benefit offset (or wage subsidy) relative to the initial SSDI
benefit (increase or reduction) offered under each GBO schedule element.
Such a schedule would generate a distribution of responses from
beneficiaries along a range of work/leisure and earnings choices. That
distribution would automatically reveal the extent of work capabilities
among SSDI beneficiaries, producing clear benefits to SSDI beneficiaries
as well as to the economy.
An important issue concerns how to design and operationalize a
GBO-type benefit schedule for the SSDI beneficiaries and incorporate it
within the current SSDI system. Under current law, an application for
SSDI benefits generates a "protective filing date" for each
beneficiary--the date when the claimant reports the intent to apply for
benefits and reports the "alleged" date of the
disability's onset. Once the intention is established, current law
states that a disability award is contingent upon SSA determination that
the claimant's disability is sufficiently severe that it will
result in death or preclude work above SGA for a continuous period of 12
months. Obviously, the applicant must immediately cease working (above
SGA level) to qualify. The definition of disability and its application
in determining eligibility, therefore, precludes the adoption of GBO
during the process of determining eligibility to SSDI.
After eligibility has been established, benefits are paid for a
maximum of 12 months retroactively from the "established"
disability onset date. Indeed, retroactive benefits are also awarded for
the period between that date and the date of final allowance. Under GBO,
however, current-law benefits could be continued for N months beyond the
date of final allowance--as few as is administratively feasible and the
fewer the better. Unlike the current SGA limit on working and earning,
current-law post-entitlement benefits would be payable under the new
system with no limitation on beneficiaries' gainful employment
activity. However, N months after the date of SSDI allowance, the
benefit would be determined by comparing earnings during the previous N
months against a schedule. The schedule could specify
higher-than-current-law benefits at zero earnings and a graduated
reduction in those benefits with higher earnings during the past N
months. Under the pre-determined GBO schedule, the change in SSDI
benefits would result in higher total income (benefits plus earnings)
for those with higher earnings.
One consideration in setting the GBO schedule is that beneficiary
earnings statements (from state unemployment insurance agencies) would
only report total earnings and not hours and wage rates. In general,
however, the GBO's objective is to incentivize high total earnings
regardless of whether they result from high work hours by low-wage
beneficiaries or high wage rates paid to SSDI beneficiaries with high
skills despite working only a few hours. Thus, a schedule such as the
one shown in Table 1 (or a variation thereof based on additional prior
information about the distribution of work abilities among SSDI
beneficiaries) could deliver better work incentives.
One noteworthy omission from Table 1 is the consideration of
inframarginal health care coverage for SSDI beneficiaries. Such coverage
is mainly through Medicare, although some beneficiaries are dually
eligible for Medicaid as well. Under the new Obamacare law, and
consistent with implementing a GBO schedule as outlined in this article,
health care subsidies would automatically be reduced as beneficiary
incomes increase for those younger than age 65. Consideration of whether
and how Obamacare subsidies should be modified for such SSDI
beneficiaries--under a new "Medicaid buy-in" allowance--is not
discussed herein.
In Table 1, the first two columns show alternative ranges of a
beneficiary's reported average monthly wages over the previous N
months. The third column shows the worker's base SSDI benefit ors
1,000 in 2013 dollars. The base SSDI benefit shown in Table 1 is simply
an example. This benefit will be different across beneficiaries
depending on the length of their work history and average annual
earnings. In general the schedule described in this section could be
made more (or less) progressive for those with smaller base SSDI
benefits.
For the case shown in Table 1, applying the earnings-contingent
rates in column 4 determines the worker's SSDI benefit during the
current month. This amount would decline as the worker's average
earnings during the previous N months increases. But because the initial
benefit reduction rate is negative at low earning rates, low-earner
beneficiaries receive more ($1,100) than their base benefit level
($1,000).
Applying the earnings-contingent benefit offset rate (column 6)
yields earnings net of the benefit offset as shown in column 7 (for
earnings assumed to be those in column 2). The offset amount declines
and earnings net of the offset increase with higher earnings. The
beneficiary's total income, which equals earnings net of benefit
offset plus earnings-contingent initial SSDI benefit, also increases
with earnings (column 8). Because earnings net of offset increase faster
than the decline in the initial benefit, total income increases at a
faster rate at higher earnings levels--up to a point. This is shown in
Figure 5, where total income increases at an increasing rate with the
beneficiary's market earnings. Note that this path is qualitatively
similar to that traced by incentive-compatible decision points [E.sub.1]
through [E.sub.4] in Figure 4.
Column 9 of Table 1 shows the marginal tax rate implied by the GBO
schedule computed as the change in income per dollar of earnings. In the
example of Table 1, the marginal tax rate is 100 percent at the lowest
earnings level. As earnings increase, the marginal tax rate declines and
eventually becomes negative at earnings between $1,000 and $2,000 per
month. This provides and Earned Income Credit-type tax incentive to
induce more work by work-capable beneficiaries. Of course, at yet higher
earnings, this work incentive may have to be withdrawn--as shown in the
last four rows of Table 1 where the marginal tax rate (column 9) is
positive. Table 1 also shows that a beneficiary who earns $2,750 or more
per month would be, economically speaking, "off SSDI rolls."
Ira relapse of an SSDI-eligible individual's disabling condition
prevents high earnings during certain periods, the person could reduce
labor force activity or exit the work force. In that case, SSDI benefits
would automatically resume as average monthly earnings (potentially
computed over rolling periods of the previous N months) decline over
time.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Lawmakers could tailor the GBO schedule according to the strength
of the work incentive that is deemed appropriate at the target earning
range. In general, however, a steeper increase in net-of-GBO income at
higher earnings levels would make the "contract curve"
incentive-compatible and more likely to induce SSDI beneficiaries to
sort according to their work abilities rather than park at the SGA
earnings level.
Conclusion
Congress has consistently sought to incentivize SSDI beneficiaries
to return to work. Most efforts to date, however, have not produced
significant and reliable responses by SSDI beneficiaries. Many believe
that despite significant work capabilities, SSDI beneficiaries are
reluctant to join the work force for fear of losing eligibility for SSDI
and health benefits.
A recent pilot project and a national demonstration project to
assess the effect of eliminating the cash cliff facing beneficiaries
under current SSDI rules with a $1-for-$2 benefit offset have yielded
clues about the existence of work abilities among SSDI beneficiaries.
Unfortunately, both projects suffered from several technical and
implementation problems and the information generated to date exhibits
considerable variability.
One key shortcoming of these efforts was the poor design of the
benefit offset. Providing a $1-for-$2 benefit offset option with full
protection of existing SSDI benefits including health care coverage
eliminates the cash cliff but makes those benefits inframarginal to
beneficiaries' work decisions. Moreover, the 50 percent marginal
tax on benefits also provides a work disincentive at the margin. In
contrast, the GBO approach as described in this article would trade off
reductions in initial benefits against sufficiently generous benefit
offsets including federal EIC-like wage subsidies, if necessary. Under
GBO, one would expect beneficiaries to sort themselves according to
their work abilities along the GBO schedule rather than park at the SGA
earnings level. The distribution of resulting work and earning choices
by SSDI beneficiaries would generate direct benefits to the economy and
to SSDI beneficiaries themselves. GBO should receive broad support from
disability advocates, policy practitioners, and (most importantly)
lawmakers from both sides of the aisle because it combines key elements
that their constituents are demanding: better support for individuals
with disabilities but also opportunities to work whenever their health
impairments permit market participation. GBO eliminates the cash cliff
and would, if adopted, introduce stronger and more effective work
incentives for work-capable beneficiaries while retaining SSDI insurance
for individuals with disabilities.
JAGADEESH GOKHALE is a senior fellow with the Cato Institute and a
member of the Social Security Advisory Board.
The author thanks, without implicating, the Social Security
Advisory Board staff for their helpful comments.
TABLE 1
One Potential Formula for the GBO Schedule
Average Monthly Earnings over Base SSDI Initial Benefit
previous N=12 months is: Monthly Adjustment
Benefit * Rate
Greater But less than
than or equal to
Col. 1 Col. 2 Col. 3 Col. 4
0 250 1000 -0.1000
250 500 1000 0.0000
500 750 1000 0.1000
750 1000 1000 0.2000
1000 1250 1000 0.3000
1250 1500 1000 0.4000
1500 1750 1000 0.5000
1750 2000 1000 0.6000
2000 2250 1000 0.7000
2250 2500 1000 0.8000
2500 2750 1000 0.9000
2750 3000 1000 1.0000
Initial SSDI Benefit Earnings Net
Benefit Offset of Benefit
[col. 3 x Rate Offset
(1-col. 4)] [col. 2 x
(1 col.6)] **
Col. 5 Col. 6 Col. 7
1100 1.000 0
1000 0.800 100
900 0.600 300
800 0.400 600
700 0.200 1000
600 0.000 1500
500 -0.200 2100
400 -0.400 2800
300 -0.200 2700
200 0.000 2500
100 0.000 2750
0 0.000 3000
Total Marginal Tax
Income Rate on
Earnings
Col. 8 Col. 9
1100 NA
1100 100
1200 60
1400 20
1700 -20
2100 -60
2600 -100
3200 -140
3000 180
2700 220
2850 40
3000 40
* The Base Monthly SSDI Benefit is based on the beneficiary's earnings
history and projected earnings through retirement. ** Earnings assumed
to be those shown in column 2.
Source: Example based on the author's calculations.