Paying bank examiners for performance: should regulators receive bonuses for effectively guarding the public interest?
Henderson, M. Todd ; Tung, Frederick
Few doubt that executive compensation arrangements encouraged the
excessive risk taking by banks that led to the financial crisis of 2008.
Accordingly, academics and lawmakers have called for the reform of
banker pay practices. But regulator pay is to blame as well, and fixing
it may be easier and more effective than reforming banker pay.
Regulatory failures during the crisis resulted at least in part
from a lack of sufficient incentives for bank examiners to act
aggressively to prevent excessive risk taking by banks. While banker pay
may have been too high-powered-too focused on shareholder value and
insufficiently sensitive to potential losses, which would ultimately be
borne by taxpayers-bank regulators' pay was not high-powered enough
and therefore, ironically, also insufficiently sensitive to potential
losses to taxpayers.
Bank regulators are not paid for performance. They are civil
servants paid a fixed salary that does not depend on whether their
actions improve banks' performance, protect banks from failure, or
increase social welfare. In fact, trying to curb risk taking at a bank
may be personally very costly for a bank regulator. Without a larger
upside than what civil service compensation offers, regulators too often
do the rational thing and play it safe, shying away from confrontation
over potentially ill-advised bank policies.
To create better incentives, we propose that regulators,
specifically bank examiners, be compensated in part with periodic
bonuses tied to the value of bank debt and equity, as well as a separate
bonus linked to the timing of the decision to take over a failing bank.
Giving examiners a stake in bank performance, both upside and downside,
will improve their incentives to act in the public interest. In contrast
to most other types of bureaucratic functions, objective metrics exist
to help measure the alignment of bank regulators' activities with
the public interest. With the right mix of banks' debt and equity
securities, public trading prices for these securities serve this
purpose. A pay-for-performance culture therefore offers special promise
for banking regulation as compared to other areas of regulation or
government bureaucracy.
Because examiners have shown a bias toward nonintervention, we
propose a debt-heavy mix of bank securities so that regulators bear the
downside risk of nonintervention. To address insider trading and
government ownership issues, we propose that regulators hold
"phantom" securities whose payout is linked with actual bank
debt and equity prices.
Though we do not discount the value of public spiritedness and
reputation as inducements toward conscientious regulation,
regulators' dismal performance in the recent financial crisis makes
us skeptical that public-spirited motivations are sufficient incentive.
At scores of banks, examiners and other regulators were well aware of
operational deficiencies and excessive risk taking several years before
those banks failed. But regulators stood still in the face of this
information. Instead of demanding corrective action by banks, examiners
continued to rate risky institutions as "fundamentally sound."
Washington Mutual (WaMu), the largest bank to fail in U.S. history at
the time, enjoyed a "fundamentally sound" rating until six
days before its collapse. This regulatory failure was not a result of
insufficient information or attention on the part of regulators. In the
three years before WaMu's collapse, examiners spent over 100,000
hours over 400 days inspecting its assets and operations. Despite the
wealth of information, examiners failed to do the heavy lifting required
to stop the excessive risk taking. The WaMu example is hardly unique.
Adding or subtracting examiner pay based on bank capital costs
incentivizes regulators toward striking a socially optimal balance
between increasing bank values and credit and reducing the costs of bank
failure. This could mean more or less regulation, depending on the bank
and the circumstances. For instance, examiners with pay linked to bank
debt may pursue a more interventionist approach in some cases, since
they bear some of the losses arising from the socially inefficient risk
that exists on their watch. Regulators incentivized to worry about
losses to taxpayers may be more diligent in their supervision of bank
assets and management, may be more aggressive in assuring that
corrective recommendations are implemented, may encourage or require
changes to bank balance sheets, and so on.
Similarly, examiners who gain from increases in bank values (for
example, by holding phantom bank stock) may take steps to make the
examination process more efficient, to get the amount and type of
disclosures right, and to encourage valuable lending and risk taking.
While we leave it to agency heads to develop optimal compensation
practices over time, even small steps in the direction of our proposal
could have large effects on the efficiency of banking regulation. The
need to incentivize regulators is especially important after the 2010
Dodd-Frank financial reform legislation, whose say-on-pay provision is
likely to generate even higher-powered incentives for managers to
maximize shareholders' private interests. High-powered bank CEO
incentives require a corresponding impetus for regulators to proactively
constrain bank risk taking.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Regulators' Pay and Its Discontents
We are not the first to point out the problems with the standard
pay structure for bureaucrats. Four decades ago, Gary Becker and George
Stigler published a seminal article arguing for incentive pay for the
enforcement of laws. Their suggestions were perhaps ahead of their time.
Not until nearly 20 years later did performance pay for CEOs become
common practice. It would likely have been something of a stretch to
adopt performance pay for government agents before private sector
actors.
Our incentive compensation proposal borrows not only from the
neglected economics literature of the past. It also finds hope in
changed pay practices for government officials implemented in the last
few years. The Obama administration has dramatically increased
regulators' salaries. According to public records, the number of
federal government officials earning six-figure salaries has
skyrocketed. In addition, bank regulatory agencies have begun using
bonuses ostensibly tied to performance. During the period 2003 2006,
three regulator agencies the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,
Office of Thrift Supervision, and Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency-paid out nearly $20 million in retention and performance
bonuses to bank examiners and other regulators. In 2006 alone, the FDIC
gave bonuses to 2,000 bank examiners.
While perhaps a step in the right direction, those modest moves
toward performance pay for regulators are less than ideal. Ex post
bonuses are not likely to yield incentives as high-powered as our
approach, which relies on ex ante incentive contracts tied to outside
metrics. Prior to the 1990s, CEOs routinely received cash bonuses and
yet pay and performance were not as tightly linked as when stock and
stock options came into use. To the extent that ex post bonus payments
are discretionary, they allow for the intrusion of nonperformance-based
criteria, such as favoritism, political affiliation, and so on. The
linkage between bonuses and conduct that maximizes social welfare may
therefore be tenuous. Ex post bonuses are also likely to be
one-sided-that is, paid in good times but not recouped in bad times.
This is likely in bias regulation in a particular direction.
Regulator Pay and the 2008 Crisis
There is widespread agreement that regulators failed to act
aggressively enough during the recent financial crisis. The problem was
not one primarily of access to information, lack of expertise, or
resource constraints. Reviewing regulators' performance following
bank failures, regulatory agencies' inspectors general reached the
same conclusion: regulators did a satisfactory job of identifying
problems well in advance of failure, but they failed to act aggressively
enough to remedy the identified problems. The problem, in our view, was
that regulators did not have the right incentives to turn their
recommendations into actual reforms of bank policies.
Regulatory failure | The examination process has two broad goals:
review of the quality of bank assets, with special focus on the
bank's most important assets, its loans; and analysis of the
bank's financial condition and the quality of its management and
operations. Examiners enjoy wide discretion as to the volume of loans
reviewed, the nature of the examination, the time spent on each
analysis, and the consequences of the examination results. Examiners
make local judgments about the credit quality of each asset. After
discussion with loan officers and bank managers, examiners make final
determinations (effectively unreviewable) about how to classify
particular loans for input into a final supervisory rating. Examiners
also review loan portfolios as a whole for issues such as concentration
risk, violations of legal rules, and deviations from bank loan and
underwriting policies. They assess the behavior and impact of
subsidiaries and affiliates, risks from litigation, the costs and
benefits of off-balance-sheet activities, and the activities of
insiders. Based on this process, examiners determine the bank's
CAMELS rating, which is the single metric used by regulators to capture
bank safety and soundness. ("CAMELS" is an acronym for Capital
adequacy, Asset quality, Management, Earnings, Liquidity, and
Sensitivity to market risk.).
Regulators have tremendous power to influence bank decision-making.
Much of the actual power resides with bank examiners in their conduct of
bank examinations. For example, the decision to change a bank's
CAMELS rating from 2 to 3 (moving the bank from "fundamentally
sound" to indicating "some degree of supervisory
concern") is largely if not entirely within the discretion of the
bank examiner. Because any regulatory intervention depends on examiners
to identify problems and pursue initial ratings downgrades, effective
incentives for examiners to act are crucial for optimal regulation.
Examiner passivity, by contrast, effectively insulates a troubled bank
from higher-level scrutiny and corrective sanctions.
Reports by inspectors general of the Treasury Department conclude
that regulators did not do enough to prevent multiple banks from taking
excessive risk and failing. Although acute funding constraints were a
precipitating factor for many bank failures, this shock was not
sufficient to explain bank failures. One report explains, "Although
the deterioration in the bank's financial condition was severe in
2008, the underlying risks were evident in the preceding years."
The consensus seems to be that if regulators had been more aggressive,
hundreds of billions in losses could have been avoided.
In general, regulatory failures fell into two broad but discrete
categories that correspond to the supervisory functions. The first
category is the failure to adequately inspect and supervise bank risk
taking during "good" times-that is, periods without financial
stress. We might think of this as a failure to do adequate preventive
medicine. The failure reports describe many instances in which the
regulators did not ensure compliance with basic risk policies and/or
restrict certain types of risk taking. For instance, regarding the
failure of IndyMac in 2008, the inspector general of the Treasury
Department concluded that "examiners did not identify or
sufficiently address the core weaknesses that ultimately caused the
thrift to fail until it was too late." As noted above, problems
often resulted from the failure to deploy regulatory tools as banks took
increasingly large and risky positions.
The second category is the failure to react to signs of distress
and intervene quickly enough to prevent further damage. The $2.5 billion
collapse of NetBank illustrates. According to the Treasury Department
inspector general, the Office of Thrift Supervision "did not react
in a timely and forceful manner to certain repeated indications of
problems." A similar lapse preceded the $2 billion failure of ANB
Financial. The regulator-the Office of the Comptroller of
Currency--"did not issue a formal enforcement action in a timely
manner" after the bank began to suffer losses and experience
distress.
The failure reports show that, in both categories of supervision,
regulators engaged in more box-checking and paperwork than aggressive
oversight. Bank examiners did the important work of assessing bank
assets and risk. They saw deficiencies and recommended changes, but then
never followed up to see if those changes were implemented. For
instance, WaMu's regulator did not "formally track the status
of examiner recommendations and [required] corrective actions."
Another (typical) report concluded:
We found that bank management did not effectively implement key
examiner recommendations over several examination cycles regarding
such controls as loan-to-value limits, interest reserve policies,
stress testing and establishing meaningful concentration limits,
and maintenance of a sufficient [allowance for losses] and adequate
capital structure. (Emphasis added.)
This same phenomenon recurred with shocking frequency in the recent
bank failures.
Regulators' incentives | Why would examiners, who repeatedly
identified problem areas, continue to rate WaMu and other banks so
highly in the face of obvious shortcomings in their business models and
practices? Why did examiners err so egregiously on the side of
nonintervention, in the face of specific policy guidance to the
contrary? The answer is incentives.
Like everyone else, bank examiners maximize according to the
incentive structure in which they find themselves. Bank examiners are
paid almost entirely in fixed salary that varies primarily by seniority.
Examiners also cannot easily be terminated. They enjoy the special job
security fashioned by the civil service rules. This job security may
make some sense. With their fixed salaries, if examiners could be
terminated for poor performance, they might be extremely risk averse.
For example, if a bank failure on an examiner's watch significantly
increased her risk of termination, the regulator's incentive would
be to ensure that the bank was not taking much risk. Though good for the
regulator, the social cost from reduced credit availability and lost
bank profits might be quite high. Reduced job security might also
subject examiners to political pressure for doing their jobs too well.
Regulated banks might be able to bring political pressure to bear on
conscientious regulators unwilling, say, to allow a failing bank to
continue operating or to permit a bank's excessive risk taking. Job
security therefore reduces counterproductive risk aversion and the risk
of political capture, giving examiners discretion in applying
regulation, perhaps in ways that improve social welfare.
But without additional incentives, the civil service rules may also
create perverse incentives by insulating regulators too well from the
consequences of their job performance. With pay delinked from an
objective performance metric, regulators may naturally focus on
bureaucratic tasks with observable outcomes, rather than on more
aggressive and costly actions with more complex and less transparent
cause-and-effect relationships.
Performing the examination and filling out examination reports is
entirely within the examiners' control. This output is subject to
objective performance metrics (e.g., is the report completed on time and
in a competent manner?). And reports alone are unlikely to generate
collateral costs for examiners. In contrast, aggressive follow-up
enforcement is likely to raise the personal costs to examiners
significantly, with little or no personal benefit. As the work moves
from investigation to persuasion-both of
higher-ups and the regulated party, each of which may push back
strongly costs for regulators will rise. Regulators interested in not
appearing before congressional committees, defending budgets, and being
forced to testify in court would likely err on the side of regulatory
restraint, especially when they do not capture the upside from
aggressive regulation and do not bear much of the downside cost of
laxity.
There is also the revolving door problem. Some regulators are bound
to get some of their expected compensation from future employment with
regulated banks. These banks may prefer as future employees those
examiners who show diligence in their work but passivity in the face of
bank interests or pressure.
Examiners may also fear making a mistake by restricting the lending
of a seemingly successful bank. This problem may be exacerbated by the
fact that examiners routinely work with the same bank for extended
periods. They often go to work every day at the bank they are examining.
While it is possible that familiarity breeds contempt, the opposite
effect-akin to the Stockholm syndrome-may also skew regulatory
decisions, especially where actions require confrontation.
Moreover, the relative secrecy surrounding bank examinations may
also encourage regulatory inertia. Secrecy no doubt plays a useful role
in encouraging bankers to be forthcoming with their examiners. Secrecy
also insulates banks from the possibility of public overreaction to
negative assessments from bank examinations, thereby avoiding the runs
that deposit insurance and banking regulation were meant to cure. At the
same time, however, secrecy also insulates examiners and the examination
process from public accountability. When the Securities and Exchange
Commission or the Environmental Protection Agency issues an order or
takes other regulatory action against a violator, that action attracts
public scrutiny. Failure to act in the face of egregious circumstances
similarly attracts public attention. While public perception may not
always be a useful metric for evaluating regulatory action, at the least
it forces regulators to explain their actions-or inactions. Bank
supervision, by contrast, is largely free from this accountability
because of the secrecy of bank examinations.
Examiner passivity could be deterred by the loss of reputation,
money, or other benefit because of the examiner's failure to act
against a bank that later collapses. But no such deterrent currently
exists. If a bank fails, there are multiple causes to which blame can be
assigned. In contrast, there is only the examiner to blame if reports
are not accurately completed and done well. Under existing incentives,
examiners might naturally conclude that their job is well done simply by
accurately describing problems and bringing them to the attention of
management and senior regulators. They have no stake in doing more. Job
and salary security reduce incentives to do "good" work,
however defined, since the consequences of "bad" work are
reduced.
To be sure, many regulators value doing the right thing and serving
the public interest. But given the ambiguity of these terms and the
potential for rationalization, the absence of monetary or reputational
rewards or sanctions means examiners care less than they would in the
presence of more high-powered incentives. We do not doubt the honesty or
good faith of the regulators who felt that they were doing the best they
could do. We simply observe that regulators are influenced in ways
beyond their ken, just as we all are. They respond rationally to the
incentives they face, and can rationalize their conduct to fit to those
incentives. We propose to change the incentives.
The Structure of Regulator Pay for Performance
The regulatory laxity preceding the recent crisis involved two
distinct types of regulatory failure: the failure to apply preventive
medicine when times were good and the failure to act aggressively when a
bank showed signs of distress. Our incentive pay proposal has two
distinct components to address those separate problems.
Bank debt-equity portfolio | First, offering a bonus linked to a
bank debt-equity portfolio would offer real-time market feedback and
long-run incentives to the examiner regarding the bank's risk
taking and its potential rewards. This component would matter primarily
during good times, while the bank is operating in the ordinary course.
Its purpose is to incentivize preventive and remedial measures well
before a bank approaches distress.
We consider two potential debt benchmarks:
* a subordinated debt security issued by the bank, and
* a credit default swap contract (CDS) referencing a junior debt
obligation of the bank holding company parent of the regulated bank
(BHC).
The prices of publicly traded subordinated debt securities and CDS
contracts reflect the market's best estimate of the risk of the
bank's default on its debt. Holding this risk-sensitive instrument
gives the examiner a personal financial incentive to curb excessive risk
at the bank. (Some amount of BHC equity should be included as well in
order to guard against undue examiner risk aversion.) With both the debt
and equity components, we suggest a relative performance approach, which
would filter out the effect of industry-wide or market-wide price
movements. As noted, the lion's share of this "preventive
medicine" component of incentive pay should be debt-based.
To encourage a medium- to long-term regulatory perspective, each
periodic phantom debt-equity allocation would have a specified medium-
to long-term maturity. At maturity, say three to five years after the
initial award, the allocation would be cashed out at the then-market
values of its underlying debt and equity components. With regular
periodic allocations, the examiner would hold multiple tranches of
phantom securities with staggered payouts, giving the examiner incentive
to consider the long-term as well as short-term consequences of her
regulatory decisions, and making short-term manipulations of securities
prices an unattractive strategy.
The appropriate debt-equity mix in the regulator's portfolio
will depend on a number of factors, some of which will be specific to
the regulated bank, to the regulating agency, to the particular times,
and perhaps even to the individual examiner. We therefore make no
attempt to offer firm prescriptions for the optimal ratio. The mix
should induce regulators to care about bank profits but not at the
expense of risk shifting to creditors. In the face of excessive risk,
the negative reaction from debt markets should reduce the value of the
debt component of the portfolio by more than any positive reaction from
equity markets would augment the value of the equity component.
Takeover bonus | Our second component, the takeover bonus, becomes
important as a bank approaches distress. The examiner would be eligible
for a cash bonus based on the timing of her decision to take over a
failing bank. Regulators have a number of reasons to wait too long
before effecting a takeover. This bonus would ameliorate the problem.
Bank regulators are by statute tasked with the specific goal of
minimizing losses to the Deposit Insurance Fund (DIF). The bonus could
therefore be tied specifically to the ultimate losses sustained by the
DIF at the resolution of the FDIC's receivership proceeding. We
suggest several approaches to estimating these losses ex ante in order
to incentivize improved timing of bank takeover decisions.
The takeover decision requires special treatment for a number of
reasons. First, it is the most difficult and drastic decision the
regulator must make in her supervision of the bank. The regulator has a
number of reasons for being reluctant to pull the plug on a failing
bank. Regulatory capture and the Stockholm effect may dissuade the
regulator from taking over the bank. Pulling the plug might also
highlight the regulator's past mistakes in not intervening more
forcefully. At any given point, the regulator might prefer to wait and
see, hoping the bank will turn itself around. As the recent financial
crisis illustrates-like all others before it-regulators tend to err on
the side of taking over too late rather than too early. This delay in
the crisis exacerbated banks' losses and the ultimate costs to the
DIE A resolution bonus would offer a direct incentive to make the right
timing decision at a critical juncture.
Moreover, although the FDIC is charged by statute with the specific
goal of minimizing DIF losses in its dealings with troubled banks, the
FDIC is typically not involved in the takeover decision, which rests
with each bank's chartering agency or primary federal regulator.
The FDIC takes over only after a bank has been declared insolvent and
put into resolution. Because the other agencies do not have their own
money at stake in the timing of the takeover, the incentives to wait and
see may be overwhelming.
Market discipline from the regulator's bank debt-equity
portfolio may not be useful in optimizing the timing of takeover because
of information asymmetry. Market signals are likely to be noisy as a
bank nears distress. Optimal timing will depend to a great extent on
fine-grained private information, which is available only to the
regulator and is constantly being updated once takeover becomes a real
possibility. A one-time bonus distinct from any market assessment of the
decision is therefore advisable.
Because of the importance of minimizing DIF losses, low losses
should trigger high bonuses and vice-versa. In theory, then, if an
examiner were to put a bank into resolution at time [T.sub.1], and as a
result the FDIC losses were 100, the examiner would get a larger bonus
than if the decision were made at [T.sub.2] when the FDIC losses would
be 200.
Implementing this simple idea may not be straightforward. First, if
we could discern the counterfactual losses that would have occurred at
[T.sub.2], then the calculation would be simple. But, of course, a
takeover at [T.sub.1] makes it impossible to know the counterfactual
[T.sub.2] outcome. Second, it is entirely possible that a conscientious
examiner might decide, given the information available to her at
[T.sub.1], to wait until [T.sub.2] for more information. Important
developments concerning the bank's prospects-the direction of
certain asset or lending markets, for example-might be worth waiting
for. Perhaps paradoxically, the more uncertain are the bank's
prospects, the more value there is in waiting. Third, even if a
regulator made an (ex ante) optimally timed decision to resolve a failed
bank, disposing of the bank's assets may take several years. That
process will affect the ultimate DIF loss figures and will not be under
the examiner's control. So a "final" resolution will be
hard to predict at the time of takeover.
Despite these seeming hurdles, a resolution bonus may still offer
important motivation for a regulator to act promptly in putting a bank
into resolution, as compared to the current compensation system. The
timing of the takeover will no doubt have an important effect on the
severity of DIF losses, and warning signs in terms of bank
characteristics and practices that lead to large resolution losses are
not so mysterious. Researchers have identified factors that correlate
with increased losses and estimated the economic magnitudes of these
effects. The findings generally comport with common intuition. Bank
asset composition and quality affect ultimate losses, as does liability
structure. For example, brokered deposits--"hot money"
aggregated by brokers seeking higher yields--are positively associated
with high-cost bank failures and shorter time to failure. The same is
true for real estate owned and loans past due. Uncollected
income--basically, nonperforming loans--correlates with high-cost
failures. Local economic conditions also matter. State personal income
growth and the health of the local banking industry are negatively
correlated with FDIC losses, while in-state bankruptcy growth and the
unemployment rate are positively correlated with FDIC losses.
The depth of existing research strongly suggests that a resolution
bonus algorithm could be constructed to both guide and cabin
regulators' discretion as to the timing of a bank takeover. Some
trial and error would be involved in optimizing the bonus structure in
pursuit of minimizing DIF losses, but with learning and experience it
might be possible to design a fully automated system in which market and
other data are incorporated into the bonus algorithm.
Short of that, agencies can develop a mechanism for estimating what
losses would have been had the examiner not acted when she did. For
example, post-mortem reports, like those described above, could be
helpful. The inspector general of the FDIC could estimate losses at
hypothetical future intervals had the examiner not taken over the bank
when she did. These reports could deploy a mix of economic models,
learning from past failures, and expert opinions from inside and outside
the regulatory agency.
Could the takeover bonus induce the regulator to act too hastily in
seizing a bank? Premature takeover is no more desirable than waiting too
long; both destroy value. The regulator's debt-equity portfolio
would ameliorate the problem to a great extent because it gives the
regulator a financial stake in the bank's recovery. The key is to
scale the takeover bonus relative to the potential value of the
regulator's debt-equity portfolio so that she neither permits
futile gambles for solvency nor pulls the plug too early. Agencies might
even implement non-trivial penalties for a takeover decision if the DIF
ultimately suffers no losses because the examiner pulled the plug too
soon.
Even if predicting ultimate FDIC losses is not an exact science for
the regulator making the takeover decision, neither is the loss
assessment inscrutable. A lack of research or analysis is unlikely to be
the reason why regulators have been too slow to pull the plug on failed
banks. Empirical studies-many done by the FDIC--and post-mortem reports
offer regulators a wealth of research to support the goal of minimizing
DIF losses. Instead, regulators may simply need better incentives to get
it right. A well-structured bonus may help ameliorate this problem.
Qualifications and Objections
Incentive structures may sometimes generate not only desired
outcomes but also some that are unintended and undesired. Our regulator
incentive pay proposal is no exception. We do believe, however, that
potential problems either can be overcome or are not sufficiently
serious to preclude the experimentation along the lines we suggest.
Crowding out the public interest | Some might object that incentive
pay is fundamentally inconsistent with public service. Financial rewards
for "success" might change the public-regarding culture within
regulatory agencies; financial incentives may crowd out the public
spiritedness that would otherwise motivate employees. Instead of
diligent altruistic service to the public, regulators and other agency
employees might begin to view their roles in terms of market exchange.
Regulators desiring higher compensation would pursue the proffered
financial rewards, while those who value leisure might feel free to work
less and forgo the rewards for diligence. Once diligence has been
priced, perhaps some regulators will slack.
In addition, the type of person that chooses to he a bank examiner
could change. Regulators have employment choices, and their choice to be
regulators likely derives at least in part from their interest in public
service. This public spirit is an important regulatory asset and should
be husbanded. Public service motives might be displaced by financial
motivations among new hires after implementation of an incentive
compensation scheme. Eventually, the composition of the regulatory
agency could change for the worse.
We do not discount these concerns. Social scientists have
documented the crowding-out effect in experimental settings. We do not
believe, however, the effect is necessarily universal or sufficiently
well understood that experimentation with incentive compensation for
regulators should be precluded. Moreover, as described above, the
federal government has already begun experimenting with financial
incentives for regulators. Enormous pay raises have been implemented at
several executive agencies. Bank regulators have received bonuses for
"good" performance during the crisis, although without any
transparency or standards of which we are aware. These examples suggest
that public spiritedness and financial reward are not mutually
exclusive, at least up to a point. Our innovation is to rely on market
pricing and specific observable outcomes to set bonus pay, instead of
relying on fiat. Our approach makes incentive pay more transparent, more
sensitive to performance, and less subject to political, class, gender,
racial, or other biases.
As for selection effects, our incremental approach suggests that
such effects from variability of pay are likely to be minor, at least in
the early stages. More generally, the possibility that increased pay
variability might change the mix of individuals opting to serve as
examiners could be a good thing. Examiners screened by their commitment
to the public interest were in fact insufficiently attentive to that
interest during the recent crisis. Accordingly, attracting individuals
interested in a variable pay-for-social-performance compensation
structure may be a beneficial change.
Noisy proxies | A basic objection to our approach is that it simply
won't work. Our market-based incentives may be too blunt to be
effective. Even after adjustments for relative performance, many
important influences besides the regulator's input will affect the
market pricing of the bank's debt and equity securities. Decisions
by the CEO and senior officers, for example, will generally dwarf the
regulator's influence over the bank's performance and the
market price of its securities. If the regulator's decisions have
little impact on the bank or the price of its securities, the argument
goes, then our scheme will have weak if any incentive effects on
regulators.
Moreover, though private firms often extend option compensation to
rank-and-file employees, and not just executives, there is some debate
as to whether broad-based option plans create effective performance
incentives. No matter how much harder they work, individual employees
are not likely to be able to exert much influence on firm value. Given
their individual small shares in their firms, they might rather free
ride than increase their effort.
These potential obstacles to performance pay schemes in private
firms should not deter us, however. Our situation is different.
Regulators are not tasked with the general goal of increasing
banks' value. Their charge is far more specific and their incentive
structure is more targeted. Regulators' charge is to guard against
excessive bank risk taking, and our debt-heavy portfolio of phantom bank
securities focuses regulators on that task. In a well-run bank that does
not incur excessive risk, it may be true as with rank-and-file employees
in private firms that examiners' ability to affect the value of the
bank's securities and their own debt-heavy portfolios is weak or
non-existent. But that is as it should be. The regulator has only a
minor role to play at a bank that is not pushing the risk envelope.
Moreover, in that situation, the costs to the government of performance
incentives are low since the market value of the bank's debt will
probably not move much. The bank's debt will enjoy a consistently
low risk premium.
However, in the opposite scenario, when a bank pushes the risk
envelope and the market value of its debt declines, examiners have
personal financial incentives to respond. This is the situation where
performance incentives cause the regulator's self-interest to
correspond with social welfare interests, inducing the regulator's
vigilance. If that situation never comes to pass, all the better, It may
be that, especially during good times, regulatory action has little
effect on most banks' value or the value of most banks'
securities. However, when a bank strays, prompt and effective regulatory
action may be critical to avoiding large losses. For this bank and this
regulator, the incentives will matter.
Conclusion
There is no reason we can think of why bank regulators should not
be paid for performance. The crucial issues are whether one can identify
what "good" and "bad" performance are, whether
contracts can be written ex ante that operationalize these metrics, and
whether the potential negative effects from introducing a
pay-for-performance culture for regulators outweigh the potential social
welfare gains. We have argued that bank regulation is an area where
there are readily available metrics, where plausible contracts or
payment schedules could be devised, and where the potential for
crowd-out or other downsides from incentive pay are limited.
Accordingly, we propose that bank examiners be paid in part with a
mix of debt-heavy incentives linked to bank equity and debt values. This
pay should represent a substantial but not dominant part of examiner
pay, should be paid out over a number of years, and should adjust in
order to maintain incentives aligned with the regulatory mission of
ensuring that bank risk taking is aligned with the social welfare. A
separate takeover bonus would encourage examiners to make bank takeover
decisions optimally to minimize DIF losses.
Although seemingly radical, our proposal is consistent with recent
moves by regulators to pay bonuses for good work and to generally
increase the quality and efficiency of regulation, It is also consistent
with laws and academic proposals to alter bank CEO pay to take greater
account of the social component of bank losses. Our contribution is to
merely point out that regulator incentives are an overlooked but crucial
factor affecting bank risk taking, and that improving the social
performance of banks and the banking system requires a consideration of
the incentives not only of bank CEOs but also of bank regulators.
Insofar as we can improve the efficiency of government regulators, we
need to worry less about the structure of private incentives, which are
further from the control of government.
By M. TODD HENDERSON University of Chicago School of Law And
FREDERICK TUNG Boston University Law School
M. TODD HENDERSON is professor of law at the University of Chicago
Law School. FREDERICK TUNG is the Howard Zhang Faculty Research Scholar
and professor of law at Boston University School of Law.