A clash of regulatory paradigms: when should policymakers promote competition, and when should they accept and regulate monopoly?
Yoo, Christopher S.
U.S. telecommunications policy has reached a crossroads. During the
1980s and 1990s, regulations focused primarily on mandating access to
the portions of the local telephone network that still represented a
natural monopoly. This policy was epitomized by the two great landmarks
of modern telecommunications policy: the breakup of AT&T in 1982 and
the Telecommunications Act of 1996. The basic policy approach was
eventually extended to broadband networks as well and has been widely
emulated by other countries.
At the prompting of the courts, the Federal Communications
Commission began to retreat from this policy during the 2000s in favor
of a more deregulatory course. In response to the grow-ins levels of
competition, the FCC took steps toward eliminating mandatory access
requirements on both telephone and broadband networks. Once the 2005
Brand X decision effectively signaled the Supreme Court's accession
to this deregulatory trend, the FCC eliminated all major access
requirements on telephone and broadband systems alike.
Despite this checkered historical record regarding mandatory
network access, the FCC has mandated access to broadband networks under
the policy initiative known as "network neutrality." This
article reviews the history of traditional telephone network regulation,
focusing on the rationales and critiques surrounding three separate
regulatory approaches.
Mandating Access to Local Telephone Systems
Since at least the days of John Stuart Mill, natural monopoly has
represented one of the central justifications for rate regulation.
Natural monopoly occurs when a single firm can serve the entire market
more cheaply than can two firms, a characteristic known as
"subadditivity." A sufficient condition for subadditivity is
the existence of scale economies throughout the entire range of
production, such as occurs when fixed costs are very high. These scale
economies permit the firm with the largest volume to enjoy the lowest
costs, which in turn permits the firm to underprice all of its rivals.
The resulting transfer of sales volume to the market-leading firm causes
its cost and price advantage to widen still further until it is the only
firm remaining in the industry. Thus, large economies of scale can cause
markets that begin with multiple producers to collapse into monopoly.
Throughout most of the history of the telephone industry, the fact
that telephone service required large fixed costs led most observers to
believe that the entire telephone system was a single, fully integrated,
natural monopoly. During the 1960s, however, policymakers began to
question that premise. For example, telephone handsets, fax machines,
answering machines, and other devices employed by end users to connect
to the network-collectively known as customer premises equipment
(CPE)--were nothing more than small appliances that could be
manufactured efficiently at fairly low volumes. In addition, the advent
of microwave transmission, pioneered by a company known as Microwave
Communications Inc. (later better known by its initials, MCI), allowed
providers to offer long distance service without having to spend the
large fixed costs needed to establish large networks of wires. Lastly,
firms began to offer innovative new services that combined data
processing with traditional transmission. These precursors to the modern
Internet, initially called "enhanced services" and later
"information services," were not characterized by the large
fixed costs associated with natural monopoly.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
At that time, local telephone service remained characterized by the
high fixed costs associated with natural monopoly. Policymakers became
concerned that the continued existence of monopoly over local telephone
service would allow the Bell System to prevent the emergence of
competition in these other areas of the industry. One concern was that
local telephone companies could use supracompetitive returns earned in
local telephone markets to cross-subsidize their own proprietary CPE,
long distance, and information services. Another was that local
telephone companies would use exclusivity or tying arrangements to
foreclose competitive providers of those complementary services. Yet
another worry was that the Bell System could avoid rate regulation of
local telephone services by bundling them with unregulated services and
charging prices for those unregulated services that would allow it to
earn the supracompetirive returns denied to them by rate regulation of
local services.
The historic solution was to segregate those portions of the
telephone system that still exhibited natural monopoly characteristics
(in this case, local telephone service) from complementary services that
are potentially competitive, and require the local telephone provider to
make its network available to all providers of complementary services on
an equal basis. Most dramatically, the court order breaking up AT&T
required that the Bell System spin off its local telephone and CPE
manufacturing operations into independent companies, mandated that the
newly created local telephone companies provide equal access to all
providers of complementary services, and forbade the newly created local
telephone companies from providing long distance, CPE, or information
services. The decision was anticipated by both the FCC's 1968
Carterfone decision, which eventually led to regulations requiring the
Bell System to open its network to CPE manufactured by competitive
providers, and the FCC's second Computer Inquiry decision, which
required that large carriers that wished to offer enhanced services do
so through a separate subsidiary while offering unaffiliated enhanced
service providers nondiscriminatory access to their transmission
facilities.
Requiring potentially competitive and inherently monopolistic lines
of business to be structurally separated into distinct corporate
entities made it more difficult for enterprises to use profits from
their monopoly businesses to cross subsidize business units that faced
competition. Structural separation also made discrimination against
unaffiliated providers of complementary services easier to police.
Regulators could simply insist that local telephone companies offer to
competitors the same terms of interconnection that it provided to its
own affiliated complementary services. If properly implemented, this
approach would allow consumers to enjoy the benefits of relying on
competition instead of direct governmental intervention to discipline
industry actors, while still protecting consumers against potential
anticompetitive abuses in those portions of the industry that remained
uncompetitive.
The Inevitability of Rate Regulation
This solution did come at a cost. Compelling access to a bottleneck
facility to promote competition in complementary services is generally
regarded as being based on what lower courts have called the
"essential facility doctrine." Indeed, the doctrine formed the
explicit basis for the breakup of AT&T. Leading commentators have
noted that the central concern of the essential facility doctrine is
vertical integration, specifically that an enterprise that controls a
monopoly input may be able to harm a vertically related market by
refusing to share it. Indeed, courts and agencies ordering access to
local telephone systems and commentators calling for access to last-mile
broadband facilities acknowledge that their claims are fundamentally
complaints about vertical integration.
The essential facility doctrine has been subject to extensive and
trenchant critique. As an initial matter, the doctrine requires direct
regulation of rates. Although some have suggested that these problems
can be avoided simply by imposing a nondiscrimination mandate, such a
mandate would not prevent a vertically integrated monopolist from simply
charging both its own affiliate and competitors interconnection fees
that are prohibitively expensive. Doing so would not affect the
monopolist's bottom line, since any losses incurred by the
complementary services division would be offset dollar-for-dollar by
higher profits earned by its local telephone operations. It would,
however, effectively lock out competitors. In the absence of some
control of rates, compelling access simply requires that the monopolist
share the essential facility with its competitors without providing any
benefits to consumers. If rates are not regulated, one would expect the
monopolist simply to share the facility with everyone willing to pay the
monopoly price.
Compelling access to a monopoly facility thus requires rate
regulation in order to be effective. Such access will engender incessant
complaints about the rate being charged. As Phillip Areeda and Herbert
Hovenkamp noted in Antitrust Law, once access is ordered,
[t]he plaintiff is likely to claim that the defendant's price for
access to an essential facility (1) is so high as to be the
equivalent of a continued refusal to deal, or (2) is unreasonable,
or (3) creates a "price squeeze" in that the defendant charges so
much for access and so little for the product it sells in
competition with the plaintiff that the latter cannot earn a
reasonable profit.
Policymakers have struggled to develop a principled basis for
evaluating the reasonableness of rates. Rate regulation has long raised
difficult questions of valuation and allocation of joint costs. The
classic ratemaking methodology also provides insufficient incentive to
reduce costs and encourages firms to use capital-intensive methods even
when doing so is inefficient. It raises difficult questions about the
proper rate of return and whether returns should be based on
assets' historical or replacement cost. Lastly, it subjects
economic pricing to the delays and biases inherent in the regulatory
process. As the Supreme Court recognized in Smyth v. Ames and Justice
Brandeis's celebrated concurrence in Missouri ex reL Southwestern
Bell Telephone Co. v. Public Service Commission, determining what
constitutes a reasonable rate has proven to be an "embarrassing
question" as well as a "laborious and baffling task."
Moreover, disputes over the reasonableness of rates are especially
difficult to resolve when the service subject to rate regulation varies
in quality. This is the case with broadband, in which quality of service
varies along as many as four dimensions: bandwidth, delay, jitter, and
reliability. When quality varies, the regulated firm can evade the
effect of rate regulation simply by degrading quality. Indeed, this is
just what occurred during prior attempts to subject the cable industry
to rate regulation: regulation failed to lower quality-adjusted cable
rates.
The Inability to Realize Efficiencies of Vertical Integration
In addition, mandating structural separation and equal access
necessarily limits firms' ability to enjoy the benefits of vertical
integration. Although the law and scholarly commentary were once quite
hostile toward the practice, vertical integration is now widely
recognized as giving rise to substantial efficiencies. Some efficiencies
are technological. Consider caller ID and voice mail, which have become
increasingly popular features in telephone systems. As it turned out,
the most efficient way to provide these services was through the switch
already used to route the call, which was essentially a small computer
that already had the capability and the information to perform these
functions.
Other efficiencies are more price-theoretic. For example,
economists have long recognized that two successive monopolists in a
single chain of production may both try to charge the entire monopoly
markup, which can lead to higher prices than if those two monopolists
merged through vertical integration. Similarly, vertical integration can
enhance economic welfare when a monopolist controls an input that can be
combined with other inputs in variable proportions. Charging a
supracompetitive price for the monopoly input causes downstream firms to
substitute other inputs. On the one hand, this input substitution
benefits consumers by limiting the monopolist's ability to capture
supracompetitive returns. On the other hand, it simultaneously harms
consumers by using a mixture of inputs that is suboptimal and thus more
expensive. Whether vertical integration under these circumstances causes
economic welfare to increase or decrease depends on which of these two
effects dominates.
Finally, as emphasized in the work of Nobel Prize winner Oliver
Williamson, vertical integration can also benefit consumers by
eliminating the transaction costs needed to guard against opportunistic
behavior. For example, when firms must make relationship-specific
investments, they become vulnerable to being held up, which occurs when
the purchaser balks at paying for goods after the fixed costs of
investment have been incurred and when the goods cannot be repurposed to
another use. If the transaction costs needed to negotiate a contract
protecting the parties against such behavior become sufficiently large,
firms may find it preferable to use vertical integration to eliminate
the incentive for one level of production to appropriate surplus at the
expense of the other.
The theoretical models showing that vertical integration tends to
be welfare enhancing are supported by a substantial empirical literature
confirming that vertical integration tends to benefit consumers in the
vast majority of cases. One leading study focuses on voice messaging
services, such as voice mail, which were made impossible by the line of
business restrictions imposed during the breakup of AT&T and by the
FCC's second Computer Inquiry. By requiring that such services
would be provided by third parties, the FCC delayed the introduction of
such services for 10 years, which reduced consumer welfare by over $1
billion annually.
The broader empirical literature on vertical integration leads to
similar conclusions. For example, Francine Lafontaine and Margaret Slade conducted a comprehensive review of the empirical literature on vertical
integration. Although they did not have any particular conclusion in
mind when they began their review of the evidence, they were somewhat
surprised to find that, aside from a few isolated studies, the weight of
the evidence indicated that "under most circumstances,
profit-maximizing vertical-integration decisions are efficient, from
firms' and consumers' points of view." The survey
concluded that "faced with a vertical arrangement, the burden of
evidence should be placed on competition authorities to demonstrate that
that arrangement is harmful before the practice is attacked."
Moreover, the survey found "clear evidence that restrictions on
vertical integration that are imposed ... on owners of retail networks
are usually detrimental to consumers." They thus called on
"government agencies to reconsider the validity of such
restrictions." A recent survey of the literature by leading
vertical integration theorist and former FCC chief economist Michael
Riordan similarly concludes, "A general presumption that vertical
integration is pro-competitive is warranted by a substantial economics
literature identifying efficiency benefits of vertical integration,
including empirical studies demonstrating positive effects of vertical
integration in various industries."
Lafontaine and Slade's separate review of the empirical
literature on vertical contractual restraints drew similar conclusions.
As a general matter, "privately imposed vertical restraints benefit
consumers or at least do not harm them." In contrast, government
mandates or prohibitions of vertical restraints "systematically
reduce consumer welfare or at least do not improve it." The authors
conclude that "the empirical evidence suggests that in fact a
relaxed antitrust attitude towards [vertical] restraints may well be
warranted." Again, this conclusion came as something of a surprise:
Lafontaine and Slade found the empirical evidence to be "quite
striking," "surprisingly consistent," "consistent
and convincing," and even "compelling."
A similar review of the empirical literature on vertical restraints
conducted by four members of the Federal Trade Commission's senior
staff found "a paucity of support for the proposition that vertical
restraints/vertical integration are likely to harm consumers." Of
the 22 empirical studies they identified that analyzed the impact of
vertical restraints on consumer welfare, only one found that vertical
integration harmed consumers, and in that study the welfare losses were
"miniscule." On the other hand, "a far greater number of
studies found that the use of vertical restraints in the particular
context studied improved welfare unambiguously." The survey thus
concluded, "Most studies find evidence that vertical
restraints/vertical integration are pro-competitive." The weight of
the evidence thus "suggests that vertical restraints are likely to
be benign or welfare enhancing," which, in turn, provides empirical
support for placing the burden on those opposing the practice.
The theoretical and empirical literature on vertical integration
thus both strongly suggest that regulatory regimes mandating structural
separation and prohibiting vertical integration impose substantial
consumer harm. The loss of these welfare benefits represents another way
in which compelling access can harm consumers.
Local Loop Unbundling
The growing recognition that the bar to vertical integration
implicit in structural separation was preventing the realization of
important efficiencies led the FCC to explore ways that firms could
provide both types of services on an integrated basis while still
guarding against potentially anticompetitive activity. As a result, the
FCC's third Computer Inquiry amended the rules to allow major local
telephone companies to provide information services on a vertically
integrated basis so long as they gave other information service
providers equal access to every element of their local telephone
networks on an unbundled basis. The Telecommunications Act of 1996
similarly required all incumbent local telephone companies to provide
unbundled access to all of their network elements at any technically
feasible point. The unbundling requirement imposed by the act did
include one key limitation: it required the FCC to determine whether
access to those elements was "necessary" and whether the
failure to provide access to those elements would "impair" the
requesting carrier's ability to provide the services that it seeks
to offer. The key network element was the wire connecting
customers' premises to the telephone company's central office,
known as the "local loop."
The FCC initially applied unbundling to a wide range of elements
associated with local telephone service. The FCC has also imposed a
variety of unbundling requirements on digital subscriber line (DSL)
networks, including local loops. Perhaps most importantly, the
FCC's Line Sharing Order in 1999 mandated unbundled access to the
high-frequency portion of the local loop used to carry DSL so that
competitors could provide services over the same loop without having to
offer conventional telephone service on the lower frequencies
simultaneously.
The FCC was considerably more tentative in its regulatory approach
to cable modem service. It postponed addressing the proper regulatory
classification for cable modem service for several years before finally
ruling that it was an interstate "information service" exempt
from both the common carriage regime governing telecommunications
services, the regulatory regime governing cable television services, and
the tariffing and unbundling requirements created by the Computer
Inquiries. In so ruling, the agency noted that it previously "has
applied these obligations only to traditional wireline services and
facilities, and has never applied them to information services provided
over cable facilities." In addition, the FCC declined to impose the
tariffing and unbundling requirements created by the Computer Inquiries
to cable modem service. The Supreme Court's 2005 decision in
National Cable & Telecommunications Association v. Brand X Internet
Services subsequently upheld the FCC's decision.
Administrative difficulties
Local loop unbundling has been subjected to extensive criticism. As
an initial matter, unbundling requires extensive rate regulation to
prevent the local telephone company from undermining access simply by
charging excessive prices.
Moreover, unbundling poses numerous administrative difficulties.
Unlike the access required following the breakup of AT&T, unbundling
gives competitors access to portions of the local telephone
companies' networks rather than their entire networks. Unbundling
thus requires local telephone companies to offer services at points in
the middle of their networks where they have never before offered
service. This in turn requires the local telephone company to create
interfaces and put into place processes for provisioning, monitoring,
and billing the services provided at those interfaces.
As a result, local loop unbundling is likely to be very difficult
to administer. As Justice Breyer warned in his separate opinion in
AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board, "Even the simplest kind of
compelled sharing ... means that someone must oversee the terms and
conditions of that sharing," which, in turn, can give rise to
"significant administrative and social costs." Breyer
continued:
The more complex the facilities, the more central their relation to
the firm's managerial responsibilities, the more extensive the
sharing demanded, the more likely these costs will become
serious.... And the more serious they become, the more likely they
will offset any economic or competitive gain that a sharing
requirement might otherwise provide.
Thus, "[r]ules that force firms to share every resource or
element of a business would create not competition, but pervasive
regulation, for the regulators, not the marketplace, would set the
relevant terms. "Justice Breyer reiterated these concerns in
Verizon Communications Inc. v. FCC, adding the observation that
unbundling produces only a thin form of competition that, instead of
stimulating entry by competitors, focuses on "widespread sharing of
entire incumbent systems under regulatory supervision-a result very
different from the competitive market that the statute seeks to
create."
A majority of the Supreme Court expanded on these concerns in its
2004 decision in Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
Trinko, LLP, in which the Court noted, "Enforced sharing ...
requires antitrust courts to act as central planners, identifying the
proper price, quantity, and other terms of dealing." Furthermore,
because unbundled access affects network elements "deep within the
bowels" of a local telephone network, they can only be made
available if"[n]ew systems [are] designed and implemented simply to
make that access possible." Additionally, requests for unbundled
access "are difficult for antitrust courts to evaluate, not only
because they are highly technical, but also because they are likely to
be extremely numerous, given the incessant, complex, and constantly
changing interaction of competitive and incumbent LECs [local exchange
carriers] implementing the sharing and interconnection
obligations."
As a result, the essential facility doctrine necessarily requires
the government to oversee the entire business relationship. The
difficulties the FCC confronted when attempting to implement other
access regimes, such as long distance interconnection and leased access
to cable television systems in the early 1990s provide further
demonstration of these problems. It is particularly telling that two
distinguished scholars of network industries, Paul Joskow and Roger
Noll, who are not particularly noted for deregulatory views, have
suggested that access regimes have proven so unworkable that they should
be abandoned.
The Impact on Investment Incentives
Perhaps the most controversial aspect of local loop unbundling is
the manner in which it reduces incentives to invest in alternative
network capacity that would compete with the monopoly facility. The well
known "tragedy of the commons" demonstrates the tendency of
people to overuse and underinvest in resources that are shared. Even
more importantly, as Areeda and Hovenkamp note, "the right to share
a monopoly discourages firms from developing their own alternative
inputs." Justice Breyer expressed the same concern in his separate
opinion in Iowa Utilities Board:
[A] sharing requirement may diminish the original owner's incentive
to keep up or to improve the property by depriving the owner of the
fruits of value-creating investment, research, or labor. ... Nor can
one guarantee that firms will undertake the investment necessary to
produce complex technological innovations knowing that any
competitive advantage deriving from those innovations will be
dissipated by the sharing requirement.
In Trinko, a majority of the Supreme Court agreed, noting,
"Compelling such firms to share the source of their advantage ...
may lessen the incentive for the monopolist, the rival, or both to
invest in those economically beneficial facilities." In other
words, without access, those firms would have to invest in alternative
sources of supply. By rescuing those firms from having to undertake
those investments, compelling access threatens to entrench the
monopolist. Indeed, the imposition of rate regulation eliminates the
supracompetitive returns that spur competitive investment in the first
place.
This underscores the extent to which mandating access to a
bottleneck facility represents surrender to the bottleneck. Compelling
firms to share their networks might be appropriate if entry by a
competitor to the bottleneck were infeasible. In that event, any
dampening of incentives to invest in alternative network capacity would
be beside the point because such entry would not be forthcoming. Indeed,
that was the case with the breakup of AT&T, where local telephone
service was still regarded as an intractable natural monopoly. As a
result, there seemed little point in trying to promote entry by new
local telephone facilities competing directly with the incumbent, and it
was appropriate for policymakers to focus their attention on the
secondary goal of promoting competition in complementary services.
The situation is quite different, however, when competitive entry
is feasible. When that is the case, competition policy should focus on
stimulating the investments needed to dissipate the monopoly. The
problem is that continued imposition of unbundling requirements deters
investment in alternative network capacity. Indeed, a growing body of
empirical work has failed to confirm that unbundling has promoted
investments in competitive local telephone services. Indeed, many
studies indicate that access actively discouraged such investments. Even
more importantly, studies have drawn similar conclusions that mandating
access has had no significant effect or a negative effect on invest
ments in last-mile broadband access services. At the same time,
empirical studies generally indicate that competition from new,
facilities-based entrants is a more effective driver of broadband
deployment and adoption.
Ladder of investment?
Later commentators, particularly those based in Europe, have
developed a third justification for mandating access, known as "the
ladder of investment." Unlike previous theories, the ladder of
investment does not provide access to elements that regulators regard as
natural monopolies and are thus inherently incapable of being rendered
competitive. The hope is that by providing access to elements that can
feasibly be replicated, new entrants can enter more easily by simply
reselling the incumbent's services. Over time, they can begin
offering additional services until eventually they become full-blown
facilities-based competitors.
Under this approach, the role of the government is not to oversee
access to portions of the network that are inherently uncompetitive.
Instead, this approach calls for regulators to manage access to portions
of the network that can feasibly be competitively provided, but that
would initially be too burdensome for new entrants to provide completely
for themselves.
There is, however, an internal contradiction in this argument. As
the Supreme Court noted in Trinko, "The indispensable requirement
for invoking the [essential facility] doctrine is the unavailability of
access to the 'essential facilities.'" It is for this
reason that courts have insisted that the essential facility doctrine
apply only to facilities that cannot be obtained from other sources. The
logic of the essential facility doctrine fails when the firm requesting
access can build the facility itself. As the Seventh Circuit noted when
rejecting a similar request by MCI for access to portions of
AT&T's long distance network when MCI had not yet extended its
own network to some parts of the country, "There was no sufficient
explanation as to why MCI, on the one hand, was building its own
network, and, on the other, was entitled to access in the interim to
AT&T's facilities." Moreover, because mandating access
discourages rivals from investing in new networks, unless carefully
managed, such a regulatory regime could well have the perverse effect of
forestalling competition from emerging at all.
Any regulator attempting to manage competition in the manner called
for by the ladder of investment must calibrate its intervention very
carefully. Setting prices too high causes access to be uneconomical, in
which case the regulatory intervention will serve no purpose. Setting
prices too low destroys incentives for competitors to invest in
substitute resources. Not only must regulators set prices correctly;
they must also credibly commit to eliminating this access over time.
Otherwise, competitors can be expected to rely on the regulatory regime
indefinitely rather than building alternative network capacity of their
own.
These considerations make ladder-of-investment regulation very
difficult to implement. A substantial theoretical literature has arisen
identifying the substantial problems with implementing this approach.
Although some reports offered some preliminary observations suggesting
the theory's viability, formal empirical analyses failed to show
that its implementation promoted investment or facilitated competitive
entry.
The Deregulatory Alternative
As Europe was developing new theories to justify continuing to
mandate access to telecommunications networks, the United States
embarked on a more deregulatory path. For example, in 2002, the D.C.
Circuit struck down the FCC's decision requiring line sharing. The
FCC's landmark 2003 Triennial Review Order eliminated unbundling
requirements on most DSL-related network elements, and its attempt to
retain unbundling requirements on local telephone service was overturned
by the courts and subsequently eliminated. As noted earlier, the Supreme
Court's 2005 Brand X decision upheld the FCC's 2002 decision
exempting cable modem service from access regulation. Shortly
thereafter, the FCC eliminated any remaining access requirements on DSL.
The FCC has also issued rulings declaring that broadband over power line
and wireless broadband constitute information services.
Emergence of competition
This deregulatory transformation in U.S. telecommunications policy
was driven in no small part by the emergence of competition. With
respect to telephony, incumbent local telephone companies face fierce
competition from internet-based VoIP and wireless telephone providers.
The number of traditional wireline telephones has declined sharply,
dropping from a high of 193 million in December 2000 to a low of 112
million as of June 2011.
With respect to broadband, courts have held that the level of
competition that already exists between DSL and cable modem systems is
sufficient to undercut the justification for requiring last-mile
providers to provide unbundled access to their competitors. The
feasibility of competitive entry is further underscored by recent
investments in fiber to the home (such as Verizon's FiOS network)
and 4G wireless technologies (such as LTE and WiMax). Although the scale
economies inherent in telecommunications will necessarily prevent
markets from being fully competitive, any regulatory regime must bear in
mind that regulation is not costless. As former FCC chief economist
Howard A. Shelanski has pointed out, while unregulated monopoly performs
so poorly to tip the balance in favor of incurring the costs of
regulatory intervention, unregulated oligopoly performs sufficiently
better to tip the balance in favor of deregulation.
The emergence of competition effectively undercuts the case for
continuing to mandate access to the existing network. In many cases,
anyone who is denied service by one provider should have sufficient
options to obtain service from another.
Impact on investment incentives
The shift to deregulation may still be justified even if the market
has not yet become sufficiently competitive. This is because granting
access would make it far less likely that the competing network will
ever be built. In short, the existence of an access requirement would
rescue any one needing access to the facility from having to undertake
the risks of building a competing network. Denying access would provide
the strongest incentives for creating the alternative network capacity.
Although denying access would cause static efficiency losses in the
short run, stimulating entry by a competitor would promote dynamic
efficiency gains in the long run.
For this reason, policymakers should refuse to impose an access
regime whenever entry is feasible. The fact that competitive entry may
take a long time and be quite expensive does not justify imposing access
because--in short--late is better than never. Approaches that dislodge
bottlenecks by stimulating competitive entry rather than simply
requiring that they be shared have the further advantage of having
built-in exit strategies embedded within them. In contrast, by
curtailing investment incentives, mandated sharing of a bottleneck
facility implicitly presumes that the monopoly facility (and the
regulatory regime overseeing how it will be shared) will persist
indefinitely. Rather than committing to using behavioral regulation to
engage in ongoing oversight indefinitely, deregulation promotes a
structural solution that is less intrusive and requires much less
ongoing supervision.
The inevitable lag in adjusting regulation also raises the risk
that regulations, such as mandated access, that protect incumbents from
new entry will continue to exist long after the justifications for
enacting the regulation have disappeared. At best, the inevitable lag in
enacting new regulations will cause economic losses. At worst, by
destroying incentives to build new technologies, regulation might cement
into place the market concentration that represents the central focus of
broadband policy.
Deciding Between Regulation and Deregulation
How then should policymakers determine the choice between
deregulation and reregulation? The foregoing analysis suggests the
following considerations: As an initial matter, policymakers should
calibrate regulation to ensure that it applies only if competitive
options do not exist in the market. If sufficient competitive
alternatives exist, consumers are unlikely to be harmed by the refusal
of any one provider to offer service.
If sufficient competitive alternatives are not available,
policymakers should ask whether competitive entry is feasible. If so,
they should assess the likely short-run static efficiency losses
incurred while waiting for entry to occur against the long-run dynamic
efficiency gains. Some scholars have categorically asserted that because
the dynamic efficiency gains will be compounded over time, they will
invariably dominate the short-run static efficiency losses. However,
whether the dynamic efficiency gains will dominate the static efficiency
losses depends on the magnitude of the gains and losses, the speed of
entry, and the appropriate discount rate, among other considerations.
Determining the welfare implications of network diversity requires a
multifaceted inquiry that is not susceptible to a simple policy
inference.
Finally, policymakers must take institutional considerations into
account. The fact that deregulation focuses on structural rather than
behavioral relief increases its implementability. In addition,
deregulation decentralizes decisionmaking and minimizes the potential
adverse impact of regulatory delay. In addition, any access regime must
take into account the fact that regulatory agencies reflect public
preferences only imperfectly and that agency decisionmaking is
frequently influenced by political goals and public interest pressures
that are not always consistent with good policy. Policymakers may be
susceptible to undervaluing the future benefits associated with the
entry of alternative network capacity, which will no doubt seem
uncertain and contingent, in favor of the immediate and concrete
benefits of providing consumers with more choices in the here and now.
Administrative agencies are also often thought to exhibit a tendency to
enlarge their jurisdiction even when the proper response would be to
contract it.
Consider, for example, the emergence of a technological alternative
to a network that had previously been a natural monopoly. The proper
policy response would be to deregulate the previously regulated
industry, since the emergence of competition would vitiate the
justification for regulation in the first place. An agency, however, has
the incentive to do precisely the opposite. Rather than deregulate the
old industry, all too often agencies respond by asserting jurisdiction
over the new industry and extending the same restrictive legacy
regulations applied to the old industry to the new one. This is exactly
what happened when the emergence of the trucking industry eliminated
whatever natural monopoly power was enjoyed by railroads. Rather than
deregulating railroads, the Interstate Commerce Commission extended the
regulatory regime governing railroads to the new competitor. A similar
pattern emerged when cable television circumvented the supposed scarcity
of the electromagnetic spectrum that justified intrusive regulation of
broadcasting.
The reaction is understandable. Agency personnel have every reason
to be reluctant to eliminate the justification for their continued
employment. In addition, they no doubt grow to identify with the
regulatory regimes that they administer and are likely to resent and try
to control anything that disrupts them. But the emergence of competition
in a previously uncompetitive industry is precisely the type of
disruption that should be embraced. Giving regulatory authorities
gatekeeper authority over network architecture necessarily puts network
policy in the crosshairs of this tension.
Only if entry is impossible can policymakers justify abandoning the
primary goal of trying to promote entry by new local telecommunications
networks and focusing instead on the secondary goal of promoting
competition in complementary services through access regulation. In
deciding whether to do so, they should take into account the
institutional limitations of regulatory agencies. They should also
include some mechanism for eliminating access mandates as soon as
competition becomes feasible to make sure that regulation does not
itself become the reason for the suppression of competition.
Conclusion
The decision whether to mandate access to telecommunications
networks thus presents policymakers with a choice between two regulatory
paradigms. One focuses on breaking down the monopoly by stimulating
competitive entry; the other surrenders to the monopoly and simply seeks
to allocate the monopoly facility. The theoretical and empirical
literature both suggest that whenever competition is feasible,
policymakers should generally follow the first course by refusing to
mandate access. Moreover, when competition is feasible but not yet
present, policymakers should mandate access only if the short-run static
efficiency losses from monopoly dominate the long-run dynamic efficiency
gains and should undertake a realistic assessment of the proposed
regulatory authority's institutional capabilities. Access
regulation is justified only if all of these criteria are satisfied.
Given the overall level of competition that already exists in these
markets and the current pattern of entry by new technologies, it is
likely that the scope of this justification is already small and will
only become smaller in the years to come.
READINGS
* Adjusting Regulation to Competition: Toward a New Model for U.S.
Telecommunications Policy," by Howard A. Shelanski. Yale Journal on
Regulation, Vol. 24 (2007).
* Antitrust and Vertical Integration in 'New Economy'
Industries with Application to Broadband Access," by Bruce M. Owen.
Review of Industrial Organization, Vol. 38 (2011).
* Antitrust Law, by Phillip E. Areeda and Herbert Hovenkamp. Aspen
Publishing, 2008.
* "Broadband Investment and Regulation: A Literature
Review," by Carlo Cambini and Yanyan Jiang. Telecommunications
Policy, Vol. 33 (2009).
* "Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration," by
Michael H. Riordan. In Handbook of Antitrust Economics, edited by Paolo
Buccirossi; MIT Press, 2008.
* "Encouraging Infrastructure Competition via the Ladder of
Investment," by Martin Cave. Telecommunications Policy, Vol. 30
(2006).
* "Exclusive Contracts and Vertical Restraints: Empirical
Evidence and Public Policy," by Francine Lafontaine and Margaret
Slade. In Handbook of Antitrust Economics, edited by Paolo Buccirossi;
MIT Press, 2008.
* Markets and Hierarchies, by Oliver E. Williamson. Free Press,
1975.
* Networks in Telecommunications." Economics and Law, by
Daniel F. Spulber and Christopher S. Yoo. Cambridge University Press,
2009.
* Public Policy toward Cable Television, by Thomas W. Hazlett and
Matthew L. Spitzer. MIT Press and AEI Press, 199Z
* "Rivalrous Telecommunications Networks With and Without
Mandatory Sharing," by Thomas W. Hazlett. Federal Communications
Law Journal, VoI. 58 (2006).
* "The Bell Doctrine: Applications in Telecommunications,
Electricity, and Other Network Industries," by Paul L. Joskow and
Roger G. Noll. Stanford Law Review, Vol. 51 (1999).
* "The Influence of Market Developments and Policies on
Telecommunication Investment," by Yoshikazu Okamoto. OECD Digital
Economy Papers No. 151, 2009.
* "Valuing the Effect of Regulation on New Services in
Telecommunications," by Jerry A. Hausman. Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity: Microeconomics, Vol. 28 (1997).
* "Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of
Interference," by James C. Cooper et al. International Journal of
Industrial Organization, Vol. 23 (2005).
* "Vertical Integration and Firm Boundaries: The
Evidence," by Francine Lafontaine and Margaret Slade. Journal of
Economic Literature, Vol. 45 (2007).
This article is based on Voo's paper "Deregulation vs.
Reregulation of Telecommunications: A Clash of Regulatory
Paradigms," Journal of Corporation Law, Vol. 36, No. 4 (2011).
CHRISTOPHER S. Voo is the John H. Chestnut Professor of Law,
Communication, and Computer and Information Science at the University of
Pennsylvania and founding director of the school's Center for
Technology, Innovation, and Competition.