What happens when local phone service is deregulated? Early returns suggest liberalization benefits consumers just as long distance deregulation did.
Eisenach, Jeffrey A. ; Caves, Kevin W.
After more than half a century of monopoly and public utility-style
regulation of retail telephone rates, in the early 1980s the United
States embarked on a path of regulatory liberalization. Monopolies on
long distance service and, later, local service were eliminated,
allowing new entrants to compete for customers by lowering prices and
offering new and improved services. As competition has developed, price
controls have been removed gradually, allowing both entrants and
incumbents to compete head-to-head to win customers. The evidence
strongly suggests that the combination of de-monopolization and price
deregulation has generated substantial benefits for consumers.
Nearly two decades after liberalization began, the process is now
nearing completion. Federal price controls on long distance service are
a distant memory and state-administered price controls on local services
have been removed for most services in most areas. There are two main
exceptions: First, most rural carriers, which typically face less robust
competition than those serving urban areas, remain subject to either
rate-of-return regulation or price caps. Second, most states continue to
impose price controls on "basic" service, i.e., a local access
line capable of receiving calls from anywhere and of making an unlimited
number or calls within a local calling area (but not including either
long distance service or "enhanced" services such as voicemail
or call-forwarding). Since 2006, however, 12 states have removed price
controls on basic service for at least some carriers in at least some
areas.
What are the effects of liberalizing price controls on basic
telephone service? Proponents of continued regulation charge that
incumbent telephone companies--even in highly competitive urban
areas--continue to have market power over basic service and, on that
basis, argue that regulation should remain in place. They contend that
the removal of price controls will result in substantial rate increases,
making even a basic telephone line "unaffordable" or leading
to "excessive" rates, despite the continued availability in
all states of subsidized telephone service for low-income customers.
Liberalization advocates, on the other hand, argue that the removal of
price controls will facilitate entry, enhance competition, promote
investment and innovation, and ultimately lead to both lower costs and
prices.
The removal of price controls in some states but not others
constitutes a natural experiment that can be used to assess the actual
effects of this policy change. In this article we do just that. We
conclude that in terms of rates and utilization, consumers in
deregulated states are at least as well off as consumers in regulated
states.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Liberalization and Telecom Prices
Regulatory liberalization of telephone services has taken place in
two primary stages, each associated with the de-monopolization of a
major industry sector. First, the breakup of AT&T and the
termination of its monopoly on long distance service led to the
elimination of price controls on long distance services. Second, the
Telecommunications Act of 1996, building on the efforts of some states,
ended the statutory monopoly on local service. The ensuing competition
prompted state public utility commissions (at varying paces and to
different extents) to remove price controls on various local services,
again reflecting the development of competition. There is widespread
agreement that liberalization has led to lower prices, improved
performance, and substantial consumer benefits.
The AT&T breakup
Competition in the long distance telephone business began in the
1970s after the Federal Communications Commission's 1969 approval
of a petition by startup Microwave Communications Inc. (later known as
MCI) to compete with AT&T by offering "specialized" long
distance services via microwave between St. Louis and Chicago. In the
ensuing years, AT&T fought aggressively against the further
expansion of competition, sometimes with the apparent support of the
FCC. Ultimately, it took an antitrust lawsuit by the U.S. Department of
Justice to inject competition fully into the marketplace, resulting in
the famous 1982 Modified Final Judgment, leading to the 1984 breakup of
AT&T into a long distance company and seven "regional Bell
operating companies" (RBOCs).
Regulation of the long distance industry did not end with the
breakup. The FCC continued to regulate AT&T's long distance
prices until 1995 and RBOCs were not permitted to offer long distance
services in any states until 1999. There is substantial disagreement
among academics about whether price liberalization should have occurred
sooner than it did, and also about whether the RBOCs' entry into
long distance service should have been delayed as long as it was. There
is no disagreement, however, that long distance prices have fallen
sharply since liberalization. As shown in Figure 1, in real terms, the
price of long distance service fell by more than 70 percent between 1984
and 2006.
The 1996 Telecom Act
The success of long distance liberalization led directly to efforts
in some states to open local markets. Those efforts, in turn, led to the
Telecom Act of 1996, which was signed into law by President Bill Clinton
in February of that year after having passed both houses of Congress
with large, bipartisan majorities. The act eliminated any statutory
monopoly on local telephone service previously held by the RBOCs and
other incumbent local exchange carriers (ILECs), opening the market to
competition from competitive local exchange carriers (CLECs), cable
companies, and various other competitors. In order to encourage the
RBOCs to open up their local markets, it allowed them to enter the
lucrative long distance market only after demonstrating they had opened
their local markets to competition by completing a "14-point
checklist."
The course taken by the FCC in implementing the act was highly
controversial, but the end result is not in dispute: the market today is
far more competitive than when the act was passed.
Indeed, state regulators from coast to coast have concluded that
competition from cable, wireless, CLECs, and internet "VoIP"
providers effectively disciplines prices in most areas and for most
products. In 2006, for example, the New York State Public Service
Commission found:
Today, cable providers, using the infrastructure that they
constructed over the past several decades to provide video
services, now offer telephone and internet services as well.
Companies are also providing internet-based phone services that
enable customers to call anywhere in the world at dramatically
reduced prices, or, in some cases, for free. These services are
generally less expensive for customers and incorporate value-added
innovations ranging from caller ID to the ability to use one's home
telephone at any internet connection. Wireless networks have also
evolved and some consumers have adopted cell phones and other
wireless communication devices as a replacement for their
traditional wireline voice service. In short the provision of
telephone service is no longer a natural monopoly.
In response to arguments sometimes made by regulation advocates
that the telecommunications market is really a "duopoly"
between cable and telephone companies, the New York PSC concluded:
We are also not convinced that our actions should be restrained by
a concern that the telephone market is or is becoming a duopoly.
There are three, not two, major pathways into the customer's
premises: traditional wire, wireless, and broadband via cable.
Furthermore, within each pathway there are multiple providers of
telephone services, especially so for providers of telephone
service over broadband.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
New York's findings were repeated nearly verbatim by the
California Public Utilities Commission later the same year. In deciding
to remove public utility-style regulation from virtually all telephone
services (except Lifeline and other services supported by state
universal service funds), the commission addressed the contention that
simply because two services are not identical, they cannot be
competitors. To the contrary, the commission found:
[A] service need not be identical to provide a competitive
substitute. For example, we see that ballpoint pens, fountain pens,
roller pens, and pencils all serve as writing instruments in the
market-place today. While no one pen or pencil is a perfect
substitute for another, they often compete in serving a customer's
need for a writing instrument. Similarly, a landline telephone, a
wireless telephone, and a VoIP telephone all may compete to serve a
consumer's need for voice communications.
The California PUC also directly addressed and rejected another
concern sometimes raised by critics of liberalization: that competition
would somehow work for everyone except those with lower incomes.
According to the PUC:
We also find no compelling reason to segment the market further by
user characteristics, such as income or use characteristics (e.g.,
business or residential use, or level of use). In particular, there
is no persuasive evidence that the patterns of use by low-income
customers differ enough from other customers to be considered a
separate market, or that competition in voice communications market
will not benefit low-income customers.
Other states have reached similar conclusions. In 2007, for
example, the Virginia State Corporation Commission lifted price
regulation for nearly all telephone services, including for basic rates
in the vast majority of the state. The Virginia commission specifically
addressed the role of wireless service, ruling that "while wireless
is not a perfect substitute for Verizon's landline service ... , a
competitor does not have to be a perfect substitute to Verizon's
landline service to act as a price regulator of Verizon's local
telephone service." Accordingly, the commission found "that it
is appropriate to include wireless competition to Verizon in the
geographic market areas in which it is available."
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Based on findings such as these, most states have now determined
that incumbent telephone companies face sufficient competition, at least
in urban areas, to warrant the relaxation or removal of incumbent price
controls on nearly all types of telephone service. (Prices charged by
telephone competitors, such as cable companies and wireless telephones,
have never been subject to price controls.) Many states have completely
removed price controls on bundled offerings (defined as packages
containing, e.g., local service, long distance service, and
"discretionary" offerings such as caller ID) and created
significant flexibility for discretionary offerings purchased "a la
carte," while leaving in place caps on basic local exchange
telephone service (BLETS) prices. Beginning in 2006, however, several
states have decided to liberalize all telephone prices, including BLETs.
Thus, although some states have gone further than others, there has been
a clear and accelerating progression in the direction of increased
pricing freedom for local telephone service.
Throughout this period, critics have argued that incumbent
telephone companies continue to have monopoly power and predicted that
loosening or removing price controls would result in large price
increases. The evidence demonstrates otherwise. Trends in telephone
price indices show that state regulators were correct in concluding that
competition would discipline the price of telephone service. Indeed,
prices for telephone service, including both wireless service (which has
never been subject to price controls) and landline service, have fallen
consistently in real terms since the mid-1990s. Telephone prices have
also declined relative to income, while expenditures on telephone
service have remained stable as a share of total consumer expenditures.
For example, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics has reported a
general price index for telephone services (incorporating both landline
telephony and wireless telephony) since the late 1990s. Figure 2
compares the annual year-to-year change in the BLS telephone services
price index with the yearly increases in the Consumer Price Index.
Telephone prices have actually dropped in six of the 13 years for which
data are available and have risen less than overall consumer prices in
every year but one (2009). In 2011, the latest full year for which data
are available, consumer prices increased by 3.2 percent, while the
telephone price index fell by 1.1 percent.
Figure 3 shows the BLS data on a monthly basis from December 1997
to the present, showing that telephone prices have fallen consistently
relative to consumer prices generally. As of April 2012, real telephone
prices had fallen by nearly 30 percent in the years since passage of the
1996 Telecom Act.
More recently, the BLS has begun to publish indices that explicitly
differentiate between landline telephony, wireless telephony, and
internet service. Although these revised communications price indices
span a relatively short time period, the data are nonetheless consistent
with the patterns observed in the traditional BLS telephone pricing
index. As seen in Figure 4, the prices of all three services are falling
compared to the CPI.
State public utilities commissions that have studied the effects of
liberalization have reached similar conclusions. For example, the
Florida Public Service Commission tracked rate changes in the wake of
2009 legislation permitting rate flexibility and found that--even for
basic rates, which had failed to keep up with inflation for many
years--none of the state's incumbent carriers increased rates by
more than 2 percent, leading it to conclude that "these rate
increases and price regulation, in general, have had a negligible impact
on the overall affordability of telephone service." Similarly, the
California PUC reported in 2010 that while basic telephone service rates
had gone up in nominal terms, "the rate increases approved for 2009
and 2010 result in rates that are less than or equal to prior rates
approved by the CPUC." Indeed, a late-2010 survey by the commission
found that the top reason given by California consumers for their
concerns about the affordability of telephone service was "Fees,
taxes and surcharges," which concerned 54 percent of
respondents--exactly twice as many as expressed concern about their
local phone bill.
It is also worth noting that telephone prices have declined
relative to household income, while the share of consumer expenditures
on telephone service (both wireless and landline) has remained stable.
Since 1998, the BLS telephone price index has fallen approximately 20
percent relative to median household income, as reported by the Census
Bureau. In addition, according to the BLS, expenditures on telephone
services--including both landline and wireless telephony--have remained
stable as a share of total consumer expenditures since 1996, fluctuating
between 2.2 and 2.4 percent.
In summary, predictions that prices would increase with the
elimination of price controls have proven not just unfounded, but
completely wrong. As the FCC unanimously concluded in 2008,
"Competition has resulted in dramatically lower prices for
telephone service, and the introduction of innovative broadband products
and services has fundamentally changed the way we communicate, work, and
obtain our education, news, and entertainment."
Liberalization and Usage
While telecommunications deregulation clearly has not led to higher
telephone prices overall, opponents of liberalizing price controls on
basic rates have argued that ending price regulation would lead to
higher BLETS prices, make basic service unaffordable for at least some
consumers, and thus lead to lower utilization. As we explain below, we
conducted a regression analysis that shows that BLETS liberalization has
not led to higher rates. Before reporting on that analysis, however, we
first discuss the current status of BLETS regulation, and then provide
some comparative statistics indicating that liberalization has not led
to lower utilization.
Liberalization of price controls
We classify the states' regulatory treatment of BLETS prices
as falling into one of three reasonably well-defined categories:
* Rate-of-return regulation
* Price cap regulation
* Liberalization (i.e., no price controls)
In some states, incumbent carriers remain bound by rate-of-return
regulation, although there is some variation in the degree of pricing
flexibility afforded to individual services. For example,
Qwest/CenturyLink in Arizona is subject to a rate-of-return regime that
allows some pricing flexibility for non-basic services but none for
BLETS. In other states, such as Alaska and Montana, rate-of-return
regulation is coupled with substantial pricing flexibility for a range
of services, including basic local exchange service. However, even
revenues derived from "flexibly priced" services still count
against a carrier's allowable rate of return. For example, Qwest in
Montana found itself obliged to lower rates substantially to both
business and residential subscribers in 2009 after the carrier was
determined to have earned excess returns. Rates in other rate-of-return
jurisdictions have still less flexibility. In Hawaii, rates for even
non-basic services lack upward pricing flexibility and full rate cases
take place very infrequently. In Washington state, Frontier
Communications is subject to a similar regime.
A growing set of jurisdictions has replaced traditional
rate-of-return regulation with price cap regulation. Under price cap
regimes, incumbents are permitted to adjust rates within the limits
specified by the regulator, with earnings and profits no longer subject
to regulation. Price cap regulation provides additional incentives for
incumbents to operate efficiently because they participate in the upside
(downside) of any cost savings (inefficiencies).
Under price cap regulation, rates are sometimes tied to a general
inflation index, typically the GDP deflator. Alternatively, rate
adjustments may be restricted to a fixed percentage or dollar amount
determined by the regulator. As a general rule, basic local exchange
services are subject to more stringent caps than non-basic and/or
competitive service offerings, which may be granted more extensive
pricing flexibility or fully liberalized. For example, the existing
price cap plan in North Carolina ties AT&T's BLETS rates
directly to the GDP deflator while rates for all other services are
liberalized. In Nebraska and Utah, incumbents have broad pricing
flexibility for all retail services without any well-defined
constraints. However, because the regulator in each state has the power
to review rate adjustments, prices are not fully liberalized. In
Nebraska, the regulator may initiate a review on its own or ratepayers
may petition the regulator to do so. In Utah, price adjustments are
subject to review according to a "just and reasonable"
standard.
A dozen states have opted to liberalize price controls entirely on
all local telephone rates, including BLETS, either through legislation
(e.g., the Alabama Communications Reform Act of 2005 eliminated the
Alabama Public Service Commission's jurisdiction over
telecommunications services) or administrative action (e.g., in its
Uniform Regulatory Framework decision of 2006, the California PUC
established a liberalization framework for large to medium-sized ILECs,
including a phased-in transition to the elimination of price controls on
BLETS).
In many cases, liberalization has been phased in after a period of
continuing price controls. For example, AT&T in Chicago is currently
under a transitory price cap that will expire in 2013, followed by
complete pricing flexibility for all retail services. Similarly, under a
2007 order, BLETS prices in Virginia remain subject to price caps until
December 31, 2012, at which point rates are slated to be liberalized.
(Regulators there are now considering extending the cap for two more
years, until 2014.)
Even in liberalized jurisdictions, certain incumbents, such as
small rural carriers, may remain subject to price controls. In addition,
rates for some services in some liberalized jurisdictions where price
caps have been removed remain subject to price floors. For example, the
Alternative Regulation Plan governing Verizon in Rhode Island explicitly
permits rates and charges "for all regulated retail services"
to "increase or decrease in response to market conditions."
However, the plan also specifies that any proposed decreases in retail
rates must include "a certification that such reduced rates ... are
not less than the Long Run Incremental Cost (LRIC) of such services or
offerings."
Utilization
If liberalization has made telephone service less affordable, we
would expect to observe differential quantity responses in states that
have liberalized price controls relative to those that have not. We
examine rates of landline attrition, participation rates in low-income
telephone subsidy programs, and rates of substitution toward wireless
telephony, and conclude that none have been affected by deregulation.
First, if liberalization made telephone service less affordable,
then states that liberalized price controls would be expected to
experience greater decreases in ILEC wireline penetration (if only ILEC
prices have risen) or in overall wireline penetration (if all wireline
rates have risen). This hypothesis can be tested empirically using
state-level panel data available from the FCC, which reports the number
of residential end-user switched access lines in service for both ILECs
and CLECs on a uniform basis from 2005 to 2010. To obtain a measure of
wireline penetration, we express these data as a fraction of a given
state's population to obtain state-level estimates of wireline
penetration. Figure 5 displays state-level trends in ILEC wireline
penetration from 2005 to 2010, grouping the states in our sample
according their regulatory regime at the end of the period.
Both the observed levels and the changes in ILEC residential
wireline penetration are remarkably similar for the states in our
sample, regardless of the regulatory environment. On average, ILEC
wireline penetration fell from 32.2 percent to 19.6 percent, with the
same fundamental pattern observed across liberalized, price cap, and
rate-of-return jurisdictions. Although there is some variation from one
state to another, there is no indication that the drop in penetration in
jurisdictions with liberalized and/or flexible prices is systematically
higher or lower than in jurisdictions with more stringent price
regulation. A simple statistical test confirms that ILEC penetration
declined equally across the three groups.
The data on total wireline penetration, defined as the ratio of
ILEC and CLEC residential access lines (including cable) to a
state's population, tell a very similar story. As seen in Figure 6,
from 2005 to 2010, average wireline penetration declined from about
36-37 percent to roughly 21 percent, regardless of the telecom policy
environment. As before, although all states experienced substantial
declines in total penetration over this timeframe, there is no evidence
that jurisdictions with liberalized and/or flexible prices experienced
systematically greater declines than did jurisdictions with more
stringent price regulation. On average, the decline was slightly steeper
in price cap jurisdictions, but the differences across policy
environments are small and statistically insignificant.
Affordability can also be assessed by examining participation in
the subsidy programs that provide low-cost telephone service to
low-income consumers. If liberalization has resulted in economically
significant rate increases, and if consumers view basic local wireline
service as "essential," one would expect to observe consumers
substituting toward subsidized alternatives, which are known as
"Lifeline" programs. All else equal, states that have removed
BLETS price controls would be expected to experience greater increases
in participation. This hypothesis can be tested empirically using
state-level data on Lifeline participation, which are available from the
FCC's Universal Service Monitoring Reports.
Figure 7 reports levels and changes in Lifeline penetration for the
states in our sample for the years 2000-2009. On average, liberalized
jurisdictions began the decade with a Lifeline penetration rate of
approximately 1.9 percent, and increased by 1 percentage point by 2009.
In contrast, Lifeline penetration in rate-of-return jurisdictions
increased by 2.5 percentage points, although the differences across
regulatory environments are not statistically significant. Thus, the
observed patterns in Lifeline penetration do not support the hypothesis
that liberalizing leads to increased dependence on subsidized telephone
service.
An economically significant rate increase would also be expected to
accelerate the rate of substitution toward competitive alternatives such
as wireless telephony. This hypothesis can be tested using state-level
data on the proportion of households and/or individuals in a given
geographic region that have abandoned landline telephony entirely and
chosen to rely exclusively on wireless voice service. The Centers for
Disease Control has surveyed "wireless-only" households and
individuals for several years, and recently released a panel of
geographically disaggregated data spanning the time period from 2007 to
2010.
Figure 8 reports levels and changes in rates of wireless
substitution (defined as the percentage of adults aged 18 and over
living in wireless-only households) for the states in our sample. From
2007 to 2010, average rates of wireless substitution increased from
roughly 15 percent to roughly 25 percent, regardless of the telecom
policy environment. On average, the observed increase was nearly
identical in liberalized jurisdictions (11.1 percentage points) and
rate-of-return jurisdictions (11.0 percentage points). Although the
increase was slightly lower in price cap jurisdictions (10.1 percentage
points), there are no statistically significant differences across
regulatory environments.
In summary, regardless of whether demand is measured in terms of
the rate of landline attrition, participation rates in low-income
telephone subsidy programs, or rates of substitution toward wireless
telephony, the data provide no indication that the relaxation or removal
of price controls has led to differential responses in the quantity of
telephone service demanded across different jurisdictions. Given that
quantity is a function of price (and vice-versa), the data do not
support the hypothesis that liberalization of basic telephone rates has
made BLETS service less affordable.
Liberalization and basic service
In addition to the comparisons above, we report on the results of
our econometric analysis of the effects of price controls on BLETS
services based on the natural experiment created by the removal of
controls in 12 states beginning in 2006.
We base our analysis on two rich data sets. First, for more than
two decades, the FCC collected uniform data on the price of basic local
exchange telephone service for a sample of 95 urban areas in 40 states.
Unfortunately for researchers, the FCC discontinued the series in 2007,
just as many states had begun to liberalize price controls on BLETS. In
mid-2011, we gathered directly comparable data on residential BLETS
prices for the same sample of 95 cities used by the FCC. While the
resulting data set is missing three years of observations (2008-2010),
the important fact is that it includes "before" and
"after" observations for the recent period of BLETS
liberalization and thus allows us to assess the impact of liberalization
on prices.
Second, as noted above, we compiled detailed information, over
time, on the pricing regulations governing the basic service offerings
of incumbent carriers serving the 95 FCC jurisdictions. Specifically, we
determined what type of regulatory regime--rate-of-return, price cap, or
liberalized--pertained to BLETS prices in each jurisdiction for each
year throughout the period 2007-2011. The result is a robust,
methodologically sound database of the prices and regulations for basic
residential telephone service spanning the recent period of BLETS
liberalization.
In addition to liberalization efforts, there are a host of
factors--demand characteristics, cost characteristics, the extent of
competition, cross-subsidies, etc.--that may affect the price of basic
local telephone service. To disentangle those factors from the effects
of liberalization, we analyzed a panel dataset spanning five years of
basic telephone pricing history (2007-2011, the period during which
BLETS liberalization policies have taken effect) for a sample of
incumbent carriers serving urban areas across the United States. Our
analysis exploits the available variation in policy environments within
jurisdictions and over time in order to identify the relationship
between various forms of regulation and the evolution of BLETS prices.
We applied several regression models to our dataset. In each
specification, the independent variable is the real price of basic local
exchange service in a given jurisdiction at a given point in time. The
key explanatory variable captures the effects of the policy environment
on the price level, using an indicator equal to 1 if the jurisdiction is
liberalized at a given point in time and 0 otherwise. Several additional
control variables are included to account for several additional factors
that may affect telephone prices, including proxies for wireline and
wireless competition, cross-subsidization between business and
residential rates, lifeline penetration, population density, income, and
state fixed effects.
Overall, we find that the elimination of BLETs price controls
either results in lower prices or has no statistically significant
effect. Simply put, jurisdictions subject to traditional rate-of-return
regulation have higher prices, holding other factors constant, than
jurisdictions with flexible and/or liberalized regimes for basic local
service. More specifically, our regression analysis shows that, after
con trolling for other factors, rates in liberalized jurisdictions are
significantly lower (by about $5.25 per month, or one-third of the
average) than rates in price cap jurisdictions. Further, rates are
highest (by about $2.46, or one-sixth of the average) in jurisdictions
subject to traditional rate-of-return regulation. Accordingly, we
conclude that the confluence of competition and liberalization has
resulted in lower consumer prices for basic local telephony than would
have been the case in the absence of liberalization.
Conclusion
The process of de-monopolization and price liberalization of retail
telephone services has been underway in the United States for several
decades. Price controls on long distance service were removed many years
ago, and liberalization of local service prices began in the 1990s. In
recent years, roughly a dozen states have completed the liberalization
process by eliminating price controls on basic telephone service.
Opponents of price liberalization have claimed that the removal of price
controls would lead to higher (even "unaffordable") rates. Our
regression analysis, however, demonstrates that, holding other factors
constant, liberalization has led to lower prices. Moreover, looking at
several indices of utilization, we find no evidence that rates have
become less affordable as a result of liberalization. Given the broad
consensus that liberalization contributes to innovation and overall
economic welfare, and the strong evidence that the removal of price
controls on other telephone services has benefited consumers, we
conclude that liberalizing price controls on basic telephone service
will benefit consumers and contribute to economic growth.
This article is condensed from their paper "The Effects of
Liberalizing Price Controls on Local Telephone Service: An Empirical
Analysis," February 2012 (SSRN #2006594). The authors thank Chris
Holt and Carey Ransone for research support.
The views expressed are the authors' and do not necessarily
represent those of Navigant Economics LLC or its parent, Navigant
Consulting Inc., nor of their officers, principals, affiliates, or
employees.
JEFFREY A. EISENACH is managing director of Navigant Economics and
a visiting scholar at the American Enterprise Institute. KEVIN W. CAVES
is director of Navigant Economics.
FIGURE 4
Change in Communications
Prices and Overall Consumer
Prices (Annualized rate,
January 2010-April 2012)
Wireless telephony -2.2%
Internet services 0.8%
Landline telephony 1.8%
Consumer price index 2.3%
Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics
Note: Table made from bar graph
FIGURE 5
Trends in ILEC Wireline Penetration 2005-2010
Liberalized Price cap Rate of return
Average Average
All Jurisdictions Liberalized Jurisdictions
ILEC Wireline 32.2% 30.8%
Penetration, 2005
ILEC Wireline 19.6% 18.8%
Penetration, 2010
Percentage Point -12.6% -12.0%
Change, 2005-2010
Average Price Average
Cap Jurisdictions ROR Jurisdictions
ILEC Wireline 32.9% 31.8%
Penetration, 2005
ILEC Wireline 20.1% 18.7%
Penetration, 2010
Percentage Point -12.8% -13.0%
Change, 2005-2010
Note: Our analysis focuses on the 40 states for which the FCC
collected retail price data through 2007
FIGURE 6
Trends in Total (ILEC + CLEC) Wireline Penetration 2005-2010
Liberalized Price cap Rate of return
Average Average
All Jurisdictions Liberalized Jurisdictions
ILEC + CLEC Wireline 37.4% 36.4%
Penetration, 2005
ILEC + CLEC Wireline 21.3% 21.0%
Penetration, 2010
Percentage Point -16.1% -15.4%
Change, 2005-2010
Average Price Average
Cap Jurisdictions ROR Jurisdictions
ILEC + CLEC Wireline 37.9% 36.4%
Penetration, 2005
ILEC + CLEC Wireline 21.5% 20.8%
Penetration, 2010
Percentage Point -16.4% -15.6%
Change, 2005-2010
Note: Alaska omitted due to redacted CLEC access line data.
FIGURE 7
Trends in Lifeline Penetration 2000-2009
Liberalized Price cap Rate of return
Average Average
All Jurisdictions Liberalized Jurisdictions
Lifeline 1.4% 1.9%
Penetration, 2000
Lifeline 2.4% 2.9%
Penetration, 2009
Percentage 2000-2009 1.1% 1.0%
Average Price Average
Cap Jurisdictions ROR Jurisdictions
Lifeline 1.2% 1.0%
Penetration, 2000
Lifeline 2.0% 3.5%
Penetration, 2009
Percentage 2000-2009 0.8% 2.5%
FIGURE 8
Trends in Wireless Substitution 2007-2010
Average Average
All Jurisdictions Liberalized Jurisdictions
Wireless 14.1% 15.2%
Substitution, 2007
Wireless Substitution, 24.5% 26.3%
7/2009-6/2010
Percentage Point 10.5% 11.1%
Change, 2007-2009/2010
Average Price Average ROR
Cap Jurisdictions Jurisdictions
Wireless 13.9% 12.4%
Substitution, 2007
Wireless Substitution, 24.0% 23.4%
7/2009-6/2010
Percentage Point 10.1% 11.0%
Change, 2007-2009/2010