How the supreme court doomed the ACA to failure the Roberts "tax" ruling undermines the new health care law.
Lambert, Thomas A.
Pundits, policy wonks, and law professors (including this author)
were surprised by the U.S. Supreme Court's June 28, 2012 ruling on
the constitutionality of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act
(ACA). Most observers expected either a 5-4 vote striking down the
ACA's so-called "individual mandate" as an overbroad
attempt to regulate interstate commerce, or a 5-4 or 6-3 vote upholding
the mandate as a valid exercise of Commerce Clause power. Instead, five
justices, including Chief Justice John Roberts, agreed that a mandate to
purchase health insurance from a private company would exceed
Congress's authority under the Commerce Clause, but a different
five-justice majority, again including the Chief Justice, read the
statute not to impose a strict mandate to purchase health insurance, but
instead to levy a constitutionally valid tax for failure to do so.
The Court also surprised observers by ruling 7-2 that the ACA
unconstitutionally coerces the states by threatening to deny all federal
Medicaid funding-not just expansion funding-to states that do not expand
their Medicaid rolls as the statute prescribes. While prior Supreme
Court precedents had recognized the theoretical possibility that
Spending Clause legislation could unconstitutionally commandeer recipient states, no spending legislation had actually been struck down
on coercion grounds. Few observers expected the state challengers to
succeed on their coercion argument, particularly by a 7-2 vote.
Now that the dust has settled somewhat, we may assess the likely
consequences of the decision in National Federation of Independent
Business v. Sebelius. This article briefly summarizes the reasoning
underlying the decision's individual mandate ruling. It then
considers what lies ahead for health insurance and medical care in the
United States if the ACA, as modified by NFIB, is not repealed. Be
warned: the picture isn't pretty.
The Roberts Court's Decision
As both Justice Roberts' opinion for the Court and the joint
dissent of Justices Antonin Scalia, Anthony Kennedy, Clarence Thomas,
and Samuel Alito emphasized, our federal government is one of limited
powers. The Bill of Rights precludes the government from imposing rules
and taking actions that violate certain fundamental rights like the
freedoms of speech, association, and religion. In addition, Article I of
the Constitution limits congressional power by exhaustively cataloging
the things Congress is authorized to do; congressional action that is
not authorized is forbidden. Accordingly, for an act of Congress to pass
constitutional muster, it must be both authorized by the empowering
provisions of Article I and not forbidden by the constraints in the Bill
of Rights.
The primary issue in NFIB was whether the so-called individual
mandate-the provision of the ACA requiring most individuals to purchase
health insurance or pay a penalty to the government--was authorized by
Article I. The government contended that the mandate was authorized by
Congress's express power under the article's Section 8, Clause
3 to "regulate Commerce ... among the several States." The
state challengers, by contrast, maintained that individuals who had
elected not to purchase health insurance had not thereby engaged in
commerce, so forcing them to do something commercial--to enter
commerce--was not itself a regulation of commerce. Five members of the
Court (Chief Justice Roberts and Justices Scalia, Kennedy, Thomas, and
Alito) agreed and held that the Commerce Clause does not authorize
Congress to order individuals to purchase insurance from a private
company. They further agreed that the mandate was not authorized by the
Article I provision empowering Congress to "make all Laws which
shall be necessary and proper" for carrying out its Commerce Clause
authority. The mandate was not "proper," the five justices
concluded, because it would compel-not regulate--commerce, and any power
conferred by the Necessary and Proper Clause must be incidental to, not
greater than, the expressly enumerated powers.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
But all this was not enough to undermine the individual
mandate's constitutionality. Having concluded that the mandate is
not a valid exercise of Congress's authority under the Commerce and
Necessary and Proper Clauses, Justice Roberts invoked a longstanding
interpretive canon that calls for the Court, if possible, to interpret
statutes in a way that preserves their constitutionality. Because he had
determined that the mandate could not be upheld on the aforementioned
grounds, Justice Roberts was willing to adopt what he characterized as a
"fairly possible," though not the "most
straightforward," reading of the ACA--namely, that the statute does
not make it illegal not to buy health insurance, but instead merely
imposes a tax, labeled a "penalty," on the failure to do so.
Congress's calling the payment a penalty rather than a tax, Justice
Roberts reasoned, was enough to preclude application of the
Anti-Injunction Act, which limits courts' jurisdiction to hear
challenges to tax laws but, as a mere statute, may be overridden by
congressional action. But, according to the Chief Justice and Justices
Ruth Bader Ginsburg, Stephen Breyer, Sonia Sotomayor, and Elena Kagan,
congressional labeling alone is not enough to keep a penalty from
amounting to a tax for constitutional purposes. The penalty for not
buying insurance is constitutionally a tax, the majority reasoned,
because it is relatively small in size, has no "scienter"
requirement (i.e., does not require an intentional
failure to purchase insurance), and is to be collected by the
Internal Revenue Service. Accordingly, the penalty for failure to
purchase insurance is constitutionally authorized as long as it meets
the Constitution's restrictions on Congress's taxing power.
The majority concluded that it does.
Constitutional law scholars will spend years dissecting the
reasoning and exploring the broad implications of NFIB's individual
mandate ruling, and an exhaustive constitutional analysis of the
decision is beyond the purview of this article. Instead, the remainder
of this article focuses on the narrower and more immediate issue of how
the modified ACA will alter health insurance and medical care in the
United States.
Implications
In June 2009, at the outset of the health care reform debate,
President Obama's Council of Economic Advisers identified "two
key components of successful health care reform: (1) a genuine
containment of the growth rate of health care costs, and (2) the
expansion of insurance coverage." When the ACA was finally enacted,
it became apparent that proponents had deemphasized the former component
and focused almost exclusively on the latter. As interpreted and
modified by the NFIB Court, however, the ACA is likely to provide
neither. Instead, we can expect health insurance premiums to rise, the
underlying cost of medical care--the primary driver of insurance
premiums-to continue to grow at pre-ACA (or perhaps higher) rates, and
insurance coverage to expand less than ACA proponents predicted.
Health insurance premiums | As the government repeatedly stressed
in the NFIB argument, the individual mandate was necessary because of
two constraints the ACA places on insurance companies. The first,
"guaranteed issue," precludes insurance companies from denying
or dropping coverage because of preexisting conditions. The second,
"community rating," requires insurers to set premiums solely
on the basis of age, smoker status, and geographic area, without
charging higher premiums to sick people or those susceptible to
sickness. Taken together, these two constraints on insurance pricing
create a perverse incentive for young, healthy people to refrain from
purchasing health insurance until they need medical care. After all,
they can always obtain coverage immediately upon becoming ill or injured
(thanks to guaranteed issue), and (thanks to community rating) the
insurer is forbidden to charge them a higher price reflective of the
virtual certainty that they will make large claims. The penalty-backed
individual mandate was designed to prevent young, healthy people from
dropping or declining to purchase insurance, thereby leaving only the
older and infirm in the covered population.
If young, healthy people do exit the pool of premium-paying
insureds, insurance premiums will skyrocket. That is because health
insurance premiums are based on the likely health care expenditures of
the covered population. The greater the percentage of young and healthy
(low expenditure) individuals in the group, the lower the resulting
premiums. Conversely, when the young and healthy drop out so that the
pool of insureds is, on average, older and more infirm, premiums will
rise. And, of course, the higher insurance premiums rise, the more
sensible it becomes for the relatively healthy to drop their insurance,
pay the small "tax," and wait to get sick before signing up
for increasingly costly coverage. Efficacious penalties for failure to
purchase insurance, then, are required to prevent "adverse
selection" and ensure that insurance policies, as regulated by the
ACA, remain affordable.
But penalties do not deter if they are set too low. Say, for
example, that a parking meter costs a dollar, but the penalty for not
feeding the meter is only a quarter. Who would feed the meter? Unless
the expected penalty for an expired meter (the fine times the likelihood
of detection) exceeds a dollar, feeding the meter is irrational.
The ACA creates a similar situation because the statutory penalty
for not carrying health insurance is quite low, much lower than the cost
of insurance. As Justice Roberts observed:
[I]ndividuals making $35,000 a year are expected to owe the IRS
about $60 for any month in which they do not have health insurance.
Someone with an annual income of $100,000 a year would likely owe
about $200. The price of a qualifying insurance policy is projected
to be around $400 per month.
It makes little sense for a young, healthy person in this situation
to pay $400 a month for health insurance when she can instead opt to pay
a penalty of $60 a month until she needs health care, at which point she
can contact a health insurer and be assured of coverage (because of
guaranteed issue) at rates not reflecting her impaired health (because
of community rating).
Now, this analysis does not account for subsidies the ACA provides
to purchase health insurance. Families earning up to four times the
federal poverty level (FPL) may qualify for a subsidy on health
insurance purchased on a state exchange that complies with the ACA. But
there are two reasons to believe that, even with these subsidies, many
young and healthy people will refrain from purchasing health insurance.
First, the subsidies are too small. For subsidy-eligible families of
four (those earning up to 400 percent of FPL), the annual penalty for
failure to purchase insurance will never exceed $2,085 (adjusted for
inflation from 2016 dollars). Out-of-pocket costs for subsidized
insurance, by contrast, will be significantly more than that amount for
all but the poorest families. Table 1 catalogs, for different
family-income levels, the maximum income percentage and out-of-pocket
dollars the family will have to pay for subsidized insurance in 2016,
the percentage difference in outlays for the family's two options
(buy insurance or pay the penalty), and the family's likely
decision.
As the table reveals, at all but the lowest income levels it makes
more sense for healthy families to refrain from purchasing insurance and
pay the penalty until insurance coverage is needed. In fact, until 2016,
even families with the lowest two income levels on the table would be
better off foregoing insurance purchases. Because the no-insurance
penalties are phased in between 2014 and 2016 (they are only $285 in
2014 and $975 in 2015), they are initially less than the out-of-pocket
cost of a qualifying insurance policy. It is likely, then, that even
low-income healthy families will drop out of the insurance pool in 2014
and 2015, driving up insurance premiums for those remaining in the pool.
In addition to being too small, the subsidies for purchasing
insurance may not be available in many states. The text of the ACA
provides for the subsidies only on purchases made through exchanges that
the states voluntarily establish. While proponents of the ACA presumably assumed that all states would establish such exchanges so as to make
subsidies available to their citizens, a great many states (36 as of the
time this article was drafted) either have declared an intention not to
set up a state exchange or have made little movement in the direction of
doing so. The IRS has taken the position that the subsidies should also
be available through federal exchanges set up as a "fallback"
in states that do not establish their own. It insists that expanding the
subsidies is consistent with the purpose of the statute. That is not
altogether clear, for legislative history suggests that Congress
deliberately provided subsidies only through state-established exchanges
in order to encourage states to set up and manage such exchanges. In any
event, the statutory language limiting subsidies to state exchanges is
quite clear and courts are generally loathe to exalt a statute's
purported purpose over its clear text, particularly when congressional
intent is ambiguous.
In the end, then, the ACA sets penalties that are too low to induce
young and healthy people to purchase insurance, even when their
purchases are subsidized as the statute provides. Proponents of the ACA,
who certainly understood the perverse incentives created by mandating
guaranteed issue and community rating, must have recognized that the
penalties were too low to prevent widespread adverse selection. They
likely assumed, though, that the deficient penalties for failure to
carry insurance were a "bug" that Congress would eventually
fix once the act was put in place and became operative. During debate
over the ACA, proponents needed for the penalties to be low so that they
could maneuver the statute through the political process; they figured
they could fix the deficiencies later.
The NFIB decision, however, limits Congress's ability to
increase the penalty for not carrying health insurance. The small size
of the penalty was one of three factors that, according to Chief Justice
Roberts, transformed the penalty into a tax for constitutional purposes.
He explained:
[T]he shared responsibility payment may for constitutional purposes
be considered a tax, not a penalty: First, for most Americans the
amount due will be far less than the price of insurance, and, by
statute, it can never be more. It may often be a reasonable
financial decision to make the payment rather than purchase
insurance, unlike the "prohibitory" financial punishment in Drexel
Furniture. Second, the individual mandate contains no scienter
requirement. Third, the payment is collected solely by the IRS
through the normal means of taxation-except that the Service is not
allowed to use those means most suggestive of a punitive sanction,
such as criminal prosecution.
This reasoning suggests that the penalty for failure to carry
health insurance can count as a tax for constitutional purposes only if
it is kept so small as to be largely ineffective. NFIB thus transformed
what was effectively a "bug" in the ACA into a
"feature" of the statute-one that is required for the act to
constitute a valid exercise of congressional power. Absent the power to
increase penalties substantially, the only means Congress has for
inducing young, healthy people to buy insurance is to increase premium
subsidies to bring out-of-pocket expenses into line with expected
penalties. Given the nation's dire fiscal situation, the political
will to take that tack may prove lacking. Somewhat ironically, then, the
NFIB decision may have damned the ACA to failure in the process of
saving it from constitutional challenge.
Underlying medical costs I The toxic combination of guaranteed
issue, community rating, and constitutionally limited low penalties for
failure to purchase health insurance would not doom the ACA if the act
significantly reduced medical costs across the board. While adverse
selection would generate a somewhat riskier pool of insureds, the
reduced costs per claim might offset the increased number of claims per
insured, driving total medical costs (and thus insurance premiums)
downward. Unfortunately, the ACA does precious little to reduce the
costs of medical care itself, as opposed to health insurance. In fact,
it will likely cause underlying medical costs to rise.
The ACA's primary measures aimed at constraining the costs of
medical care are:
* increased funding for ferreting out "waste, fraud, and
abuse"
* price controls (administered by the Independent Payment Advisory
Board, commonly known as IPAB) on Medicare charges
* comparative effectiveness research aimed at determining which
medical procedures are most cost-effective
* measures to encourage preventive care
* authorization for "Accountable Care Organizations"
(ACOs), which are collaborations among medical care providers who are
offered a modest financial incentive to coordinate care so as to reduce
redundancy, unnecessary testing, etc.
* an excise tax to discourage extremely generous employer-provided
health care plans that lead consumers to ignore medical prices and
overconsume health care services
Unfortunately, none of these measures will likely have much
cost-reducing effect. An attempt to reduce waste, fraud, and abuse may
be a cost-effective effort, but officials have been attempting to reduce
waste, fraud, and abuse for decades and there is little reason to
believe this particular attempt will be anomalously successful. IPAB
recommendations will affect Medicare expenditures only, and will likely
lead to either reduced services for Medicare beneficiaries or price
discrimination against non-Medicare consumers of the services at issue,
who will be charged higher prices to make up for the Medicare cuts.
Comparative effectiveness research is probably a good initiative
(information, after all, has characteristics of a public good and is
thus frequently underproduced), but such research will reduce costs only
if health care providers actually use it in making treatment decisions.
Given that doctors tend to think their patients are unique and should
not be confined to "off the rack" treatments, and insured
patients have little or no incentive to pressure their physicians to
follow the most cost-effective treatment regimens, it is difficult to
believe that comparative effectiveness research will reduce overall
health care costs by a significant percentage. The same goes for the
ACA's preventive care efforts, which amount mainly to grants for
demonstration projects, etc., or to mandates that insurers provide
preventive measures free of charge. (For reasons detailed below,
mandating insurance coverage for all preventive measures will likely
increase the cost of those measures in the long run.) As for ACOs, any
cost-savings from collaborations among competing providers must be
reduced by the amount of price-enhancing collusion such collaborations
facilitate. Given that the payoff for ACO members who successfully
collude to raise prices would dwarf any likely "shared
savings" from coordination, the coordination among competitors that
the statute's ACO provisions encourage is more likely to increase
than to reduce providers' prices. That leaves the excise tax for
particularly-generous insurance policies. For reasons explained next,
that tax is a good, but far too limited, initiative.
When it comes to the medical costs that underlie insurance
premiums, the glaring omission in the ACA is its failure to address what
is perhaps the primary driver of health care inflation: the lack of
price competition among providers of medical services. In competitive
markets, price is driven down to the level of the producer's
incremental cost (which usually falls with technological development and
increased specialization) as competing producers vie for customers. But
producers will lower their prices only if doing so brings them more
business, and lower prices will enhance sales only if customers (at
least "marginal" customers-those most price-sensitive)
actually shop on price. When a third party pays for the consumer's
purchase, the consumer has little incentive to consider price when
determining from whom to purchase. Thus, health insurance tends to make
consumers price-insensitive, thereby destroying providers'
incentive to compete on price.
As health insurance has transitioned from covering only
unpredictable and catastrophic expenses (like emergency surgeries and
unexpected hospitalizations) to covering even expected, low-cost
services (like office visits and vaccinations), and as co-payments have
been reduced or eliminated, consumers' incentives to take price
into consideration when selecting medical service providers have
virtually disappeared. It is not surprising, then, that a 2005 Harris
Interactive Poll of 2,000 insured adults found that the average survey
participant could predict the price of a Honda Accord within $300, but
was off by a whopping $8,100 when it came to estimating the price of a
four-day hospital stay. Why research prices (or refuse low-value
services) when someone else is paying? And why would providers lower
their prices (or refrain from recommending services of little value)
when consumers routinely ignore price in making purchase decisions?
Things change drastically when consumers have to foot the direct
bill for medical treatment. Consider, for example, the price of LASIK eye surgery, which insurance generally does not cover. In 1999, prices
for the procedure averaged $2,106 per eye. By 2010, the average price in
real (1999) dollars had fallen 21 percent, to $1,658 per eye, despite
significant improvements in the technology. Similarly, prices for
cosmetic surgery have consistently fallen over time despite both
technology improvements and increased demand. In the three years
preceding 2009, purchases of laser skin resurfacing increased by 456
percent among men and 215 percent among women, but prices fell even in
nominal terms. Before this surge in demand, the average procedure cost
$2,317; by 2010 it had declined to $2,232 in nominal dollars (an 18.5
percent decline in real terms). Prices for medical services overall, by
contrast, have risen sharply over time. From 1999 to 2010, when LASIK
prices fell 21 percent in real terms, real prices for medical services
rose by 22 percent. What accounts for this difference in price trends?
In large part, the vigorous price competition results from the fact that
consumers of LASIK and cosmetic surgery take price into account because
they must pay out of pocket.
The lesson for health care reformers is that if we want to stop the
upward spiral of health care costs--the real source of America's
purported health care crisis--we need to find ways to motivate providers
to compete on price. Expanding insurance coverage does not help here;
such expansion results in even less price comparison among consumers and
tends to encourage providers to raise prices and to oversell unnecessary
or marginally useful medical services.
A better policy would encourage consumers to pay directly (out of
pocket) for a more significant portion of their health care consumption
so that providers have an incentive to compete on value. Increasing
deductibles and copayments, while encouraging consumers to prepare for
higher out-of-pocket costs by maintaining tax-advantaged Health Savings
Accounts, would help on this front. Current policy, though, discourages
high-deductible, high-copayment insurance policies. Right now, employer
contributions to health insurance, but not individuals' own
expenditures on such insurance, are not taxed. This creates an incentive
for employers to replace salary, upon which their employees are taxed,
with more generous health insurance benefits (i.e., low deductibles, low
copayments, lots of costly coverages), which are tax-advantaged. Those
generous benefits, in turn, discourage both price competition and
thoughtful decisions about health care consumption.
Proponents of the ACA understood this reasoning, as evidenced by
the comment of Christina Romer (then-chair of President Obama's
Council of Economic Advisers and an architect of the ACA) that overly
generous insurance plans "lead families to be less vigilant
consumers of health care." The act's excise tax on the most
generous employer-provided plans is a step in the right direction. ACA
proponents missed a crucial opportunity, though, in failing to correct
the inequitable tax treatment that encourages employers to compensate
their workers with more generous benefits rather than increased salary.
Moreover, the act exacerbated the problem of anemic price competition by
mandating that insurance plans fully cover, with no copayment, all
preventive services. If consumers pay nothing for a preventive service regardless of its price, they have little incentive to select relatively
cost-effective services, and providers therefore have little incentive
to compete on price. Automobile insurers understand this principle. They
do not raise premiums slightly and cover routine oil changes, even
though regular oil changes prevent higher costs down the road, because
they know that insurance coverage would destroy price competition among
mechanics and drive up the price of oil changes. By the same token, the
ACA's mandate that insurers fully cover all preventive health
services is sure to increase the price of those services in the future.
Insurance coverage | As mentioned above, the ACA's framers
chose to pursue increased insurance coverage over reduced medical costs.
As implemented in light of NFIB, however, it is unlikely that the act
will expand coverage as much as its proponents hoped and promised.
First, a number of stares, including some very populous ones, are
likely not to expand Medicaid as the statute prescribes. Recall that one
of the holdings of NFIB was that Congress could not cut off all federal
Medicaid funding to states that did not expand their Medicaid rolls to
cover all individuals and families earning up to 133 percent of FPL
(because doing so would impermissibly "commandeer" the
states). Instead, Congress could merely withhold federal expansion
funding from noncompliant states. The "carrot" of expansion
funding is far less significant than the "stick" of cutting
off all federal Medicaid funding, and a number of governors--Democrats
and Republicans alike-have expressed reservations about expanding their
Medicaid rolls. Given the generous federal subsidies available to states
that expand their rolls (100 percent of expansion funding initially,
falling to 90 percent by 2020), most state governments will likely
comply with the expansion request. After all, the federal taxes paid by
a state's residents ultimately help finance the expansion funding,
and resident voters are thus likely to demand some share of that
funding. On the other hand, officials in many cash-strapped states have
worried that Congress will, in the future, reduce the amount of federal
subsidies for the expanded rolls, leaving the states on the hook for the
expanded entitlement benefits. Those officials may decide not to expand
their states' Medicaid rolls, leaving uninsured many citizens who
are not eligible for traditional Medicaid. Those earning less than 133
percent of FPL would also not be eligible for premium subsidies, which
are available only for individuals and families earning 133 percent to
400 percent of FPL.
Coverage levels may also disappoint because the ACA encourages
employers to drop health plans for lower-income employees, many of whom
will not be motivated to purchase insurance on their own. As noted, the
federal tax code currently exempts employer-provided health insurance
benefits from taxation. That exemption amounts to an implicit subsidy
percentage equal to the payroll tax rate plus the recipient
employee's marginal income tax rate. Because high-income workers
are subject to higher marginal tax rates than are lower-income workers,
this implicit subsidy is greatest for them. Moreover, workers earning
more than 400 percent of FPL will get no subsidy to buy insurance if
their employer stops providing it. Lower-income workers, by contrast,
get less of an implicit subsidy for employer-provided health insurance,
are eligible for more generous subsidies on state exchanges if their
employer does not provide health insurance benefits, and would therefore
prefer to work for employers that do not offer such benefits. Employers
competing for workers will respond to these preferences.
Consider, for example, a previously uninsured 4S-year-old who earns
$35,000 and wants to acquire a family insurance policy that, in a
high-cost area, will cost around $15,000 in 2016. If the employer
provides the policy, the cash component of the employee's
compensation will fall to $20,000 (benefits generally being a
dollar-for-dollar substitute for wages). The employee, however, will not
have to pay the approximately $3,400 in federal income, Social Security,
and Medicare taxes that would otherwise be due on the $15,000 received
as insurance rather than cash. On the other hand, if the employer does
not provide health insurance and the employee purchases it on a state
exchange, the employee will be eligible for a federal subsidy worth
around $13,600. Given the choice between a $3,400 implicit tax subsidy
and a $13,600 subsidy on the exchange, the employee would prefer the
latter. If the employer employs more than 50 workers and fails to
provide coverage, then the employer would be charged a penalty of $2,000
for each worker (after the first 30 workers). It would likely choose to
pay that penalty, however. The employer could finance the payment by
reducing the employee's salary by $2,000, and the employee would
gladly agree to that arrangement. Even after having his salary
diminished by $2,000, the employee would be better off gaining access to
the larger government subsidy available only to individuals without
employer-provided coverage.
But this analysis shows merely that the ACA encourages employers to
drop coverage for lower-income workers. Won't those workers then
purchase subsidized policies on the state exchanges? Perhaps not. For
many of those workers, it will make more sense to pay the penalty and
wait until health care is needed before purchasing insurance. A
one-income family of four headed by a 40-year-old earning $50,000, for
example, would have to pay $3,385 for qualifying insurance or incur a
no-insurance penalty of $2,085. And the family could always purchase
insurance on a state exchange-with a $9,900 subsidy-the moment coverage
became necessary. Such a family's income level is low enough that
the family is better off without employer coverage, yet high enough that
the family's out-of-pocket insurance expenses will exceed the
no-insurance penalty. Families in this situation can be expected to both
lose employer coverage and refrain from purchasing insurance On a state
exchange.
Of course, all this assumes that premium subsidies are indeed
available. For reasons set forth above, the ACA seems not to authorize
such subsidies in states that fail to establish exchanges and instead
rely on the federal government to do so. Employers in such states would
have less incentive to drop coverage for low-income employees, but
lower-income citizens who do not have employer-provided health insurance
would not be likely to purchase insurance in such states, where the
difference between the non-coverage penalty and the out-of-pocket cost
of insurance (without subsidies) would be tremendous.
For all these reasons, the ACA, as constrained by NFIB, is unlikely
to expand health insurance coverage to anywhere near the level its
proponents predicted.
Conclusion
While the NFIB decision averted a constitutional ruling that would
have eviscerated the constraints government faces as a result of the
Constitution's enumeration of congressional powers, the decision
left the ACA largely intact. The limitations it did impose, though, are
likely to impair further the effectiveness of the already misguided
statute. As modified and constrained by NFIB, the ACA is likely to drive
up both the cost of health insurance premiums and the underlying cost of
medical care without increasing insurance coverage by nearly as much as
the act's proponents promised.
Of course, this grim picture of the future assumes that the ACA is
not repealed or significantly amended. Given the act's continued
unpopularity, repeal is a genuine possibility. Congress and the
president would do well to replace this ill-conceived statute with a law
focused primarily on the most fundamental problem plaguing the American
medical system: the lack of vigorous price competition among health care
providers. Correcting the tax code provisions that encourage overly
generous health insurance policies and thereby assure that consumers of
health care pay little or nothing out of pocket would be an excellent
first step toward tackling the biggest problem facing the American
health care system.
READINGS
* "How the Free Market Can Cure Health Care," by Matt
Palumbo. American Thinker, December 17, 2011.
* "Punitive Damages: An Economic Analysis," by A.
Mitchell Polinsky and Steven Shavell. Harvard Law Review, Vol. 111
(1998).
* "Taxation without Representation: The Illegal IRS Rule to
Expand Tax Credits under the PPACA," by Jonathan Adler and Michael
F. Cannon. Health Matrix: Journal of Law-Medicine, forthcoming.
* "The Proposed Accountable Care Organization Antitrust
Guidance: A First Look," by Joe Miller. Health Affairs Blog, April
4, 2011.
* "The Real Trouble with the Birth Control Mandate," by
John H. Cochrane. Wall Street Journal, February 9, 2012.
* "Why States Have a Huge Financial Incentive to Opt Out of
Obamacare's Medicaid Expansion," by Avik Roy. Apothecary, July
13, 2012.
* "Yes, the Federal Exchange Can Offer Premium Tax
Credits," by Timothy S. Jost. Health Reform Watch, September 11,
2011.
THOMAS A. LAMBERT is the Judge C.A. Leedy Professor of Law at the
University of Missouri Law School.
TABLE 1
Penalty vs. Insurance Decision for Different Incomes
For 2016 and beyond
Family Maximum per- Dollars to Insurance Likely
Income cent of income be spent on cost as decision
to be spent on insurance percent of
insurance penalty
$35,000 3.97% $1,388 67% Buy
$40,000 4.96% $1,982 95% Buy
$45,000 5.94% $2,672 128% Don't buy
$50,000 6.77% $3,385 162% Don't buy
$55,000 7.52% $4,135 198% Don't buy
$60,000 8.23% $4,937 236% Don't buy
$65,000 8.85% $5,751 276% Don't buy
$70,000 9.47% $6,626 318% Don't buy
$75,000 9.50% $7,125 342% Don't buy
$80,000 9.50% $7,600 365% Don't buy
$85,000 9.50% $8,075 387% Don't buy
$90,000 9.50% $8,550 410% Don't buy
$95,000 No maximum Full cost 400+% Don't buy
$100,000 No maximum Full cost 400+% Don't buy