Forty years on the regulatory commons.
Yandle, Bruce
On January 18, with much fanfare that included a Wall Street
Journal op-ed (a rare act for a sitting president), President Obama
announced Executive Order 13563. The order set in motion yet another
presidential effort to exert control over the federal government's
regulatory Leviathan, an estate with 280,000 workers and a $60 billion
budget that turns out 3,000 new rules annually.
With noteworthy innovations, the order contains some of the same
logic for improving regulation found in President Richard Nixon's
October 1971 order that established in the Office of Management and
Budget a Quality of Life review for major federal regulations. From
Nixon forward, there has always been an executive order requiring some
kind of White House review of new regulations. And over the years,
regulatory review orders have evolved in an apparent effort to free up
the economy by reducing regulatory burdens.
With 40 years of accumulated executive order wisdom to draw on and
knowledge tapped from turning out some 2.5 million pages of Federal
Register rules since 1970, President Obama looked the Leviathan in the
eye and called for a review that will "root out regulations that
conflict, that are not worth the cost, or that are just plain
dumb." His order calls for renewed efforts for agencies to conduct
benefit-cost analysis of new rules, asks agencies to identify and
eliminate regulations that serve no meaningful purpose, and instructs
regulators to conduct retrospective reviews of rules and make beneficial
modifications. The president also initiated an expanded web-based
process that opens windows for those who wish to see what is going on
inside the regulatory process. While emphasizing that strenuous
benefit-cost analysis must be applied where possible to justify
regulations, the order also allows for softer considerations that
include "equity, human dignity, fairness, and distributive
impacts."
But in spite of the complex administrative machinery described in
the Obama order, human incentives still matter most, and incentives for
regulators and the regulated have changed over the past four decades.
There is nothing in EO 13563 that recognizes that the U.S. economy in
the 21st century is very different from Nixon's 1971 economy.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Regulatory commons
In a world where everything can be regulated, requiring agencies to
act on better benefit-cost analysis is a wonderfully important idea and
requiring retrospective reviews of mossy rules is to be celebrated. But
as good as they are, those ideas and others in EO 13563 do not take
account of our regulation-driven capitalism and the incentives playing
throughout it.
Ours is a regulatory capitalism where regulators and the regulated
are intertwined in symbiotic cartel-forming ways that often make working
the halls of Congress and regulator offices far more profitable for
firms and organizations than struggling in labs, stores, and service
organizations to earn consumer patronage. EO 13563 gives commands to an
army of regulators who operate as if they are external to the economy
they seek to fix, while in fact they are a part of it.
The transformation of the U.S. economy into regulatory capitalism
began around 1970, which was the start of the modern regulatory era. It
was then that regulation became highly centralized at the federal level,
that newly formed social regulators such as the Environmental Protection
Agency, Occupational Safety and Health Administration, and Consumer
Product Safety Commission joined older economic regulators like the
Federal Communications Commission, Securities and Exchange Commission,
and Federal Trade Commission to form a new legal environment that
ultimately transformed the United States from a common-law to a code-law
country.
Inspired by statutes directing action, our 60-plus federal
regulatory agencies are somewhat like sheep with legislative guiding
shepherds grazing on a regulatory commons, a resource space where there
are no systematic limits on the number of rules that can be produced,
the time required to read and abide by them, or the economic resources
consumed in meeting the rules. Fed by growing budgets and expanded
duties, the regulators write more rules. While budgets, congressional
directives, executive orders, and benevolent forbearance partially
constrain the commons, there is always room for one more bite by the
sheep, one more regulation.
The regulatory commons parallels its brother, the fiscal commons.
Deficits are the inevitable tendency on one; excessive regulation on the
other. In fact, across the years 1970 to 2010, regulatory agency budgets
were fed by deficit dollars; they grew faster than federal revenue.
What is it like on the regulatory commons? When one puts on a pair
of externality-visualizing glasses, one sees endless opportunities to
internalize external costs and maybe even render the world Pareto safe.
Whether it be dealing with lead paint, mandatory inspection of catfish,
energy efficiency for refrigerators and furnaces, minimum standards for
drivers licenses, diesel engine emissions, advertising over-the-counter
drugs, marketing practices of funeral homes, or ridding the market of
noisy Hickory Dickory Dock pounding toys, the world is full of unhappy
and dangerous situations that need fixing.
But with externality glasses, it is much easier to see the flaws
than to determine if all people taken together are made better off after
the regulatory repairs are in place. And who has time to check? As a
result, in the post-1970 period, regulations affecting
processes--product design, marketing, personnel, purchasing, finance,
manufacturing, and waste disposal--began to affect each and every
industrial sector. In a chaotic sense, industries such as autos, food,
steel, construction, paper, chemicals, banking, insurance, health care,
and higher education were transformed to a new kind of public utility,
but without the usual regulatory commission to look after them--and be
captured.
On rare occasions over the last 40 years, government analysts made
a back-breaking, overall-industry assessment to describe and analyze the
cumulative effects of all federal regulations imposed on a single
industry. But most of the time, no one has kept score. And even more
rarely, regulators would conduct retrospective analyses to determine if
indeed the regulations that appeared to be so strongly net-beneficial
when imposed really turned out that way. As all of us who have been part
of the regulatory establishment understand, there is seldom enough
agency time to deal with business in the pipeline, let alone enjoy the
luxury of self-examination. All of the incentives go the other way. The
next Federal Register press run is waiting. In a way, the nature of our
work as regulators made it far more important to turn out more
regulation than to inquire about outcomes. It was as if no one really
cared about outcomes; regulation was the only outcome that mattered. And
if there are to be retroactive assessments, does it really make sense to
let the regulators pick the ones to assess?
Changing political economy
Years ago, when regulation was young, before we had published those
2.5 million pages of rules, economists spoke knowingly in tones of
certainty about market failure and intervention to correct difficulties
from such problems as market power, information asymmetries, failed
institutions, and unspecified property rights. We spoke as though
government and regulation were exogenous to the market process, that on
occasions regulators would open a window, examine features of the
economy, make some efficiency-enhancing adjustments, and then quickly
close the window to leave the economy to operate in a more glorious way.
Indeed, we used the word "intervention" and we referred
sometimes to Michael Lantz's 1937 FTC statuary metaphor where a
powerful flee market horse is being bridled by a benevolent plowman who
presumably serves the public interest.
But as regulatory windows opened and closed daily and agencies
pumped out more rules, firms and industries became intertwined with
government. Government was no longer exogenous to the behavior of firms
in the marketplace; government became endogenous. While major
regulations may have reduced some perceived market failure, they also
cartelized industries and reduced competition. The strong horses and
other special interests came seeking the plowman.
As the political economy has changed, so the words we use to
describe and explain what we are doing have become obsolete. When banks
become tantamount to regulated public utilities with rules at every
margin, can we accurately refer to problems in the industry as evidence
of market failure? Would we better say government failure? Or regulatory
failure?
Our theories of regulation suffer as well. Long ago, we referred to
public interest theory to describe what regulators sought to do when
they opened and closed the regulatory windows. We then talked about
capture--that happens when the window is open too long. Then came
special interest theory that recognizes the competitive battles at play
when multiple interest groups seek regulation to obtain well-packaged
gains. And yes, there is bootleggers-and-Baptists theory that offers to
explain how apparently opposing groups may struggle on the regulatory
commons to obtain the same set of rules. But we must enrich our
behavioral theories. We must focus on the process itself and how the
regulatory process has affected the U.S. economy.
Final thoughts
Ours is an intertwined political economy where economic
agents--public and private, always connected--interact on the commons.
Cutting through the entanglement will be difficult. Each rule worth
revising or repealing maintains wealth for members of the regulatory
cartel.
While critically important, as EO 13563 makes clear, it is no
longer enough to do benefit-cost analysis on a rule-by-rule basis in the
belief that regulation is exogenous to the market process. In terms of
improving the new rule, the following should be incorporated:
* Agencies should be required to conduct potential cartel analysis
for every major industry rule. They should also identify industry
winners and losers under proposed rules, account for the gains and
losses that may result in a rule-induced regulatory cartel, and estimate
deadweight losses imposed on consumers.
* The Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice and the
Federal Trade Commission should be required to review major rules in
cooperation with the White House's Office of Information and
Regulatory Affairs, and should intervene as appropriate in regulatory
proceedings that may have inefficient outcomes.
* In conjunction with the required retrospective assessments and
industry reviews, Congress should hold annual hearings to review those
reports, with an eye toward improving the competitiveness of the U.S.
economy and identifying the economic gains obtained through regulatory
review by OIRA.
Going beyond executive orders and OIRA review, Congress should
exercise its sovereign responsibility on behalf of the people. This
requires it to close the circle of accountability so that all regulatory
agencies--executive branch and independent--meet the same accountability
standard. To accomplish this, Congress must pass legislation that
requires the Congressional Budget Office to:
* become a government-wide scorekeeper on regulatory burdens
imposed by legislative mandates, and
* assess pending legislation that includes regulatory mandates and
recommend cost-effective alternatives.
Congress must then hold annual hearings on the state of regulation
in the economy and how regulation is affecting competitiveness in the
U.S. economy. On the basis of those hearings, Congress should take
action to set constraints on the amount of regulatory cost that can be
imposed annually on the U.S. economy.
Two and a half million pages of rules and 40 years later, it is
time to enclose the regulatory commons and sharply revise the way we
regulate.
READINGS
* "A Theory of Entangled Political Economy, with Application
to TARP and NRA," by Adam Smith, Richard E. Wagner, and Bruce
Yandle. Public Choice, Vol. 148, Nos. 1-2 (2011).
* "Bootleggers and Baptists: The Education of a Regulatory
Economist," by Bruce Yandle. Regulation, Vol. 22 (1983).
* Public Choice and Regulation: A View from Inside the Federal
Trade Commission, edited by James C. Miller III, Robert Mackay, and
Bruce Yandle. Hoover Institution Press, 1987.
* Regulating Business by Independent Commissions, by Marver H.
Bernstein. Princeton University Press, 1985.
* Regulation by Litigation, by Andrew P. Morriss, Bruce Yandle, and
Andrew Dorchak. Yale University Press, 2009.
* "Regulatory Process Reform," by Murray Weidenbaum.
Regulation, Vol. 20 (1997).
* "The Theory of Economic Regulation," by George J.
Stigler. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 3
(1971).
BY BRUCE YANDLE
Clemson University
BRUCE YANDLE is professor of economics emeritus at Clemson
University, distinguished adjunct professor of-economics at the Mercatus
Center at George Mason University, and PERC senior fellow.