A hidden gift to manufacturing: cities should stop zoning land exclusively for industrial use.
Hills, Roderick M., Jr. ; Schleicher, David
We both now live or have lived in Brooklyn, in a neighborhood that
real estate brokers call "Cobble Hill," just a few blocks from
the East River. The location allows you simultaneously to get some
exercise and study land use regulation by taking a run along the South
Brooklyn waterfront. If you run south along Columbia Heights and Van
Brunt, you enjoy one of the city's best views of the Upper Bay and
Manhattan. Just by turning your head, you can see a stretch of river
from the Brooklyn Bridge to the Verrazano Bridge, encompassing the
towers of the Financial District, the Statue of Liberty, Governor's
Island, and Staten Island. It is not far from the popular restaurants
and cafes of Cobble Hill and Carroll Gardens, and the area received some
press when MTV's The Real World filmed a season from a building
nearby. The land seems like a prime spot for a condo with a view.
But the buildings enjoying this magnificent vista are often
abandoned or underused, frequently consisting of apparently empty
warehouses, some usually idle container cranes, and crumbling concrete
lots surrounded by chain-link fence. The waterfront still has a couple
of significant industrial employers. On Piers 7 through 11, for
instance, American Stevedoring leases land from the Brooklyn Port
Authority, although the rent is apparently paid from funds supplied by
the state, and the cocoa beans that the company unloads are barged over
to Port Newark, NJ. The Golten Marine Company operates a maritime repair
facility next door to American Stevedoring. But heavy maritime industry
has mostly left the area: the two most conspicuous businesses are the
Fairway Grocery and the new IKEA, both commercial retailers in Red Hook
that cater to city residents. These retailers are surrounded by the
skeletons of crumbling warehouses and defunct cranes, the relics of
Brooklyn's manufacturing past.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The absence of housing along New York's waterfront is, in
large part, the result of zoning. Since 1961, the city's zoning
resolution has barred residential uses from manufacturing zones, and 30
percent of the city's shoreline is presently zoned for industrial
use. Such "noncumulative" manufacturing zones (that is, zones
that do not allow the "cumulation" of uses less noxious than
industry in manufacturing zones) bar housing in a considerable part of
New York City. According to a 2005 Manhattan Institute study by Regina
Armstrong, the city zoned 22,500 acres for industrial development to the
exclusion of residential uses in 2005. Cities around the country have
adopted similar policies, fencing off valuable real estate in tight
markets from residential and often from commercial development.
Why not allow residential uses in these manufacturing zones?
Advocates of noncumulative zoning typically offer two explanations for
how residential users could threaten industrial uses. First, residential
users are said to burden industry with complaints and nuisance lawsuits.
Keeping residences out of industrial zones is a regulatory analogue to a
"coming to the nuisance" defense in tort law, preserving
industrial investments from encroachments by sensitive users. Second,
residential users outbid industrial users for land, driving industry out
of the city in search of cheaper real estate. By excluding residential
uses, noncumulative zoning protects urban industry from the threat of
escalating real estate prices.
Neither of these arguments provides a compelling reason to exclude
residential or commercial uses from manufacturing zones. Industry could
be protected from nuisance litigation by giving industrial users a
defense of regulatory compliance. Further, noncumulative zoning is an
indiscriminate, inflexible, and politically invisible form of subsidy
for manufacturers. It cannot be targeted at firms that provide
agglomerative spillover benefits for the city, it provides far less
benefits to firms than would cash subsidies of equal value, and it
generates costs that are not included in a city's public budget and
hence are hidden from ordinary group competition for scarce public
resources. Noncumulative zoning is an idea whose time has passed.
BRIEF HISTORY OF NONCUMULATIVE ZONING
Prior to World War II, most zoning ordinances followed the model of
the Village of Euclid v Ambler Realty (1926) by providing for
"cumulative" or "inclusive" zoning districts defined
by a hierarchy of uses. The highest use was the single-family home, and
land zoned for such homes excluded most other uses, including
multifamily residential uses. Land zoned for uses deemed to be more
noxious than the single-family use would permit single-family homes as
well as other less noxious uses. Thus, commercial, multifamily, and
single-family uses would all be permitted in industrial zones, and
landowners could freely convert industrial uses into other uses within
those zones as the market dictated.
After World War II, municipalities began experimenting with
noncumulative zones that excluded residential uses from industrial
zones. During the 1950s, state courts were typically skeptical of such
ordinances, regarding them as inconsistent with the anti-nuisance
rationale for zoning that had been proffered in Village of Euclid as
zoning's primary justification.
This focus on protecting residences from industrial uses began to
change in New York City when Robert Wagner began a campaign to revise
New York's zoning resolution between 1947 and 1961. Unlike the
state court opinions that justified such exclusion largely in terms of
protecting residential uses from the fumes and noise of industry, the
studies commissioned by Wagner and his appointees argued that industrial
uses were threatened by housing and that the city needed to safeguard
its industrial future by reserving land exclusively for the former.
After a decade of protracted political struggle, Wagner got his wish
when the City Council enacted the 1961 Zoning Resolution that provided,
for the first time, noncumulative manufacturing zones in New York City.
What had changed by the early 1960s that would make more compelling
these calls to protect industry from residential uses? Between 1955 and
1965, New York's industry had been devastated by a revolution in
transportation that deprived cities of their comparative advantage in
attracting and retaining manufacturing. At the center of this revolution
was the creation of an interstate highway system and the "container
revolution" integrating the shipment of goods in a single metal box
across rail, trucking, and shipping. Radically reducing shipping costs,
this transportation revolution eliminated most of the advantage of
locating factories in immediate proximity to Brooklyn's piers. By
1965, New York City had lost much of its maritime shipping business to
New Jersey and factories had deserted Bay Ridge and Sunset Park in
droves. New York's waterfront had been reduced to derelict shambles
and the city's industrial job base had suffered staggering losses.
Responding to pressure from manufacturers and unions, politicians
in New York and other big cities pressed for incentives to keep
manufacturing enterprises in the city. New York's 1961 move to
noncumulative zoning has been matched by other large cities'
efforts to attract or retain industry. The names and details of these
zoning schemes differ (Chicago calls them "planned manufacturing
districts," San Francisco calls them "industrial protection
zones," and Los Angeles, "industrial business zones"),
but the basic concept remains the same: the city seals off some area
from residential and often commercial development in order to provide
benefits to urban manufacturers.
Two arguments dominate this defense of noncumulative industrial
zoning. First, both planners and industrial users of urban land complain
that intruding residential uses threaten industrial uses with complaints
about noise, smell, or traffic. As Robert J. Hughes, the owner of Erie
Basin Bargeport, the city's largest barge operator, stated in
explaining his opposition to luxury waterfront condos in Red Hook,
Brooklyn, "The first thing luxury condo owners will do is sue
us." This anti-lawsuit justification is the exclusive reason for
non-cumulative zoning offered by the New York City Planning
Department's website.
Second, manufacturers and unions worry that residential users will
bid up the price of land, causing landowners to hike rents on industrial
users, who will respond by fleeing to the suburbs. The transportation
revolution increased the elasticity of demand for industrial land so
much that cities can no longer hope to retain manufacturing enterprises
simply by offering proximity to customers or suppliers. By excluding
residential (and, less frequently, even office and commercial uses), the
central city can provide an in-kind subsidy of cheaper land to
manufacturers as a bribe to get them to locate or expand in the city.
Such exclusively industrial zoning has potentially large costs.
Land zoned for nonresidential uses could be an important source of
residential housing. In 2005, the City of New York zoned 22,500 acres of
land exclusively for manufacturing uses; developed at even a small
fraction of Brooklyn's average density of 55 dwelling units per
acre, this land could provide thousands of units of housing in a city
with a notorious shortage of residential units. Of course, there is no
way to easily calculate how much of this land would actually be used for
residential uses if zoning were cumulative, but there is anecdotal
evidence of high demand for industrially zoned land among residential
users. In the 1930s, fully half of all New Yorkers lived in
non-residential zones, and, even under the post-1961 regime of
noncumulative zoning, manufacturing zones accommodate a large number of
residential units--so many, in fact, that the city's crackdown on
illegal conversions of manufacturing units to residential use was
impeded by the threat of leaving hundreds of tenants stranded.
THE CASE AGAINST THE CASE FOR NON-CUMULATIVE ZONING
It is not self-evident that keeping manufacturers within cities is
a good idea. If transportation and real estate costs are lower in less
densely populated areas, then the de-industrialization of cities might
be a boon rather than a bane. But there may be some justification for
these policies. In what follows, we adopt what economist Timothy Bartik
has called the "market failure" perspective on the problem of
urban industrial uses: we try to define the circumstances under which
markets in land might fail to reflect the socially optimal amount of
industry in urban areas. We argue that noncumulative zoning is likely to
be too inflexible and indiscriminate to identify specific industrial and
commercial uses that will create increasing returns, and we suggest that
a "regulatory compliance" defense and tax or grant subsidies
would be better mechanisms for industrial retention if, in fact, such
retention is advisable.
Stopping Nuisance Complaints The least controversial "market
failure" for which exclusive industrial zones might be a plausible
remedy is the problem of nuisance. On this view, residential users will
inefficiently drive out industrial neighbors by complaining about
nuisance costs such as noise, fumes, or traffic. Iran industrial
landowner could somehow purchase, lease, or buy easements for all of the
land within earshot of their industrial facility, they could protect
themselves from nuisance lawsuits. But transaction costs predictably
foil the effort to buy out a multitude of ill-identified potential
plaintiffs in a densely populated urban area.
The problem of lawsuits, however, does not require total exclusion
of housing. Why not allow residential users to occupy land in
manufacturing zones, but give industrial users a defense of regulatory
compliance against any nuisance or analogous lawsuits that might
otherwise be applicable? If residential users prefer the grit and noise
of industrial neighbors to other residential alternatives, then
excluding those users from manufacturing zones entirely would seem to be
excessive paternalism. Why not let the urban pioneers make their own
choice on the tradeoff between low price and low clamor?
There is plenty of precedent for such a regulatory compliance
defense to protect active users from quiet enjoyers. In particular, many
states have passed "right-to-farm" laws that give existing
farms a right to continue defined farming activities against nuisance
complaints about the obnoxious side effects. "Right-to-stink"
laws could serve an analogous function for industry.
One difficulty with right-to-farm legislation is that such statutes
typically protect only existing uses from nuisance complaints. It is a
common lament of industrial users that the presence of residences
prevents their expansion as well as continuation. To the extent that one
wanted to protect prospective industrial uses from existing residential
users' complaints, then one would need a full defense of regulatory
compliance, under which current or future uses consistent with the
manufacturing zone's use schedule would be exempt from liability
even if they arose after the plaintiff or complainant purchased within
the zone.
Such a strong defense of regulatory compliance, in which a lot that
is vacant or residential could be converted into a smoke-spewing
smelter, places a heavy burden on potential residential users to
research and insure against changes in the use of nearby land, either
through on-site precautions (for example, triple-pane windows) or simply
taking a short-term lease rather than a fee simple interest.
Manufacturing zones that form the basis for a regulatory compliance
defense, therefore, might need more detailed specifications of
permissible uses, including emissions and decibel levels to serve as
notification for housing consumers.
Subsidizing Manufacturing The major justification for exclusion of
residential uses from manufacturing zones is less concerned with
prevention of nuisance litigation than with stabilization of land
prices. In purpose and effect, noncumulative zoning is a subsidy to draw
manufacturing enterprises to the city. Zoning reduces the cost of
manufacturing land in the city and, thereby, is a subsidy to new
manufacturing entrants.
Does it ever make sense to influence the location of industry with
such subsidies? Maybe--but the subsidies have to be targeted to the
precise uses that generate spillover benefits that are not reflected in
the market value of land. Noncumulative zones do not seem well suited
for delivering such subsidies when compared to outright grants or tax
subsidies. In particular, noncumulative zones are so indiscriminate,
inflexible, and politically invisible that the deadweight costs imposed
on residential users are likely to outweigh the benefits to the
city's economy.
How might a subsidy rationally support the development of a city?
In their efforts to explain why cities develop, economists have produced
a voluminous literature usually called "agglomeration
economics" or the "New Economic Geography." This
literature argues that individuals and firms locate near others because
of the external benefits of physical proximity. Specifically, they have
identified three major reasons why firms and individuals cluster in
cities:
* to reduce shipping costs for goods;
* to access deep markets (particularly labor markets, but also
consumption and social markets), which provide more specialized services
and employers, insurance against firm- or industry-specific risk, and
quick matching; and
* for information spillovers between firms and individuals, either
inside an industry or between industries, that promote both increased
production and the development of human capital over time.
The market for land theoretically might lead to too little
clustering of firms in cities because individual firms will fail to take
into account the positive effect they have on other firms and
individuals. The core case for industrial subsidies follows ordinary
Pigouvian principles (see p. 2) for subsidizing beneficial spillovers:
cities that derive special spillover benefits from particular firms or
industries should subsidize those firms or industries until private
costs are reduced to the point where they make the socially optimal
decision. As long as cities differ in their ability to capture these
externalities, competition among them should lead to optimal location
decisions, as the city best placed to capture the externalities will bid
the most to capture the firm.
However, to justify a subsidy, a firm must provide a greater
externality than the various deadweight costs imposed by taxation.
Taxation at the local governmental level produces two distinct sorts of
deadweight losses. Aside from the ordinary excess burden caused by
taxation's distorting effect on consumption or production, local
taxes also influence residential choices. Unless the tax is effectively
a benefits charge paid exclusively by those who receive the external
benefit of the subsidy, increases in taxation may (on the margin) cause
some residents to exit to other locations. And individual residents can
create agglomeration spillovers just as readily as industry. If artists,
actors, financial wizards, writers, or other creative types are driven
out of the city because of high tax burdens, then the agglomeration
economies that they generate by hanging out at cafes and exchanging
ideas will be lost.
Thus, for a subsidy to be justified for a given city, the external
benefits provided by the subsidized firm must be greater than (a) the
sum of the cost to existing residents of local taxation (in, say,
changing their consumption patterns or labor market participation in
inefficient ways), and (b) the loss of external benefits generated by
those who are priced out of the city by taxation. This formula implies
that industrial subsidies are justified from the city's perspective
only if the industrial tenant thus gained or retained will be a far
better generator of beneficial spillovers than whomever they displace.
Such a formula suggests that the mechanism for providing industrial
subsidies should not be indiscriminate or inflexible. Policies that
provide subsidies to crudely defined categories of industry are unlikely
to distinguish between industries that generate net benefits after the
cost of the subsidies is taken into account. Take, for example,
intellectual spillovers, which are commonly cited as the most prominent
agglomeration benefit of dense industrial concentration. Cities are said
to foster a "creative class" precisely because their density
allows persons who benefit from intellectual spillovers to interact
frequently and informally. It is, however, difficult to determine which
mix of firms--whether diverse or homogenous--or which type of firms
generates intellectual spillovers. There is no reason to think that it
will be beneficial to subsidize manufacturing in general rather than
industries with particular characteristics, such as firms with high
levels of human capital and/or firms that are known to provide and rely
on a high degree of intellectual ferment (e.g., filmmaking, education,
medicine, software design).
The same argument can be made for increasing the labor market size.
There are spillover benefits from labor market depth, but manufacturing
industries do not indiscriminately generate such benefits more than
other types of industries. Deep labor markets provide gains from
specialization and insurance. Deep labor markets also provide labor with
insurance against firm- or industry-specific risk. If a single firm or
field in a big city does badly, an individual who works there can get
another job without relocating. Further, deep labor markets have lower
search costs for both firms and individuals, as it is easier to find the
proper labor (or firm) if there are many choices. This has dynamic
effects as well. Increased localization creates incentives for labor to
invest in human capital, as they can be sure these investments will not
be wasted.
To the extent that labor is not fungible across industries, labor
market depth might provide an argument for subsidizing industries that
are already large in any given urban area. By having more firms in these
industries, there will be more labor demanded, more specialization, and
greater insurance against firm-specific risk (although less against
industry-specific risk). But this argument does not support
indiscriminate manufacturing subsidies. Instead, the argument for
labor-market depth provides an argument for subsidizing certain classes
of industry in which cities are already strong, thereby retaining labor
market depth and preserving the market's quality and
specialization. Cities certainly engage in this type of subsidy policy.
For instance, New York City granted Broadway theater companies a subsidy
by allowing them to sell the air rights above their theaters to
developers. Spraying dollars indiscriminately at the manufacturing
sector, however, seems intuitively an implausible way to preserve labor
market depth. One might as well deepen the labor market by simply
attracting all sorts of businesses through generally lower taxes.
Finally, the traditional argument for concentrating industry in
urban areas--reduction in transportation costs seems increasingly
implausible as a justification for manufacturing subsidies. The
importance of this as a force for agglomeration has declined as
intercity transport costs have fallen dramatically in the last 50 years.
It barely costs anything to ship, say, lug nuts, and so the value to
other firms of having locally sourced lug nuts is now very low. As a
result, it is hard to imagine a justification for urban industrial
subsidies on the basis of reducing shipping costs.
NON-CUMULATIVE ZONING'S THREE FATAL FLAWS
Judged by the standards set forth above, noncumulative zoning is a
poor way of subsidizing retention of industry in urban areas. Such
in-kind land subsidies tend to be too indiscriminate, inflexible, and
invisible to be reliably worth the deadweight costs that they are likely
to impose.
Indiscriminant Subsidy The most obvious flaw with noncumulative
zones is that they provide an indiscriminate subsidy to every business
falling within the zoning district's schedule of uses. These uses
tend to be broadly defined, often including (to the consternation of
lobbyists for industrial land) not only industry but also commercial
retailing. Even if retailers were excluded, however, manufacturing
districts do not make fine distinctions between manufacturing uses based
on the quantity and quality of the jobs they produce. New York City, for
instance, has only three manufacturing use districts (light, medium, and
heavy) defined by the intensity of noise or pollution produced by the
permitted uses. Although these three categories are subdivided into use
groups that variously permit specific commercial uses, the
resolution--like other cities' zoning ordinances provides no way to
distinguish (for instance) between a high-wage manufacturer using a
highly skilled workforce and a low-wage manufacturer employing very few
workers or unskilled nonresidents who commute from the suburbs.
Zoning categories are far too crude to discriminate between
businesses worth subsidizing and businesses that produce no net gain for
local residents. The result is that manufacturing districts contain
those underused warehouses, parking lots, and even abandoned buildings
on New York's waterfront. Even when such zones produce economically
viable uses, there is no guarantee that they will produce the high-wage
jobs that their boosters urge as their justification. One study of
Chicago's planned manufacturing districts found that they did not
do much to preserve high-paying manufacturing jobs even when they were
occupied by successful commercial businesses.
The indiscriminate nature of manufacturing zones could be solved by
narrowing the number of permissible uses. This, indeed, is the solution
urged by New York's Industrial Retention Network, which has urged
the creation of industrial zones from which profitable retail uses are
excluded. But it is unlikely that the city could confidently select
specific types of enterprises likely to produce, say, human capital
spillovers and promote those enterprises by excluding all other uses
from a parcel. Unlike a cash subsidy, the zoning subsidy risks leaving a
lot vacant for an extended period of time while the city awaits a buyer
who would actually put the land to the zoned use.
Inflexible Subsidy If landowners could easily obtain map amendments
or use variances whenever the existing manufacturing use is, in the
judgment of the city, less valuable than a proposed residential use,
then the indiscriminate character of zoning districts would not inflict
any deadweight cost on housing consumers. Landowners with manufacturing
tenants that produce few spillover benefits would simply seek to have
their parcel rezoned for residential uses, citing the low-value nature
of its current use.
But land use changes, whether administrative or legislative, are
costly to obtain. Unlike outright grants of revenue that are regularly
reviewed through the budget process, zoning districts remain in place
until the planning commission, city council, or private parties propose
an amendment or variance. Landowners seeking to change zoning
designations face opposition from neighbors who typically oppose any
rezoning that increases density or bulk of the existing use, as well as
from the tenants of the landowner and their employees and potential
rival purchasers of the land. To say that it is difficult to get a
variance understates the case significantly.
Of course, well connected and experienced developers can and will
pay the freight to alter the zoning where the gap between the value of
the existing use and the proposed residential use is extraordinarily
high. By greasing the skids with community benefit agreements or
providing parks and playgrounds, developers can buy allies on the city
council and buy off opposition groups. But this is inefficient, unfair
to those with fewer political connections, and time consuming.
The inflexibility of noncumulative zoning comes with an added cost.
Because the only way to use noncumulative zoning as a subsidy is by
procuring land, it generates inefficient substitution among
manufacturers toward the use of more land rather than, say, more
efficient machines. Not only does this provide less benefit to
manufacturers than would a direct subsidy, it increases the cost to the
city economy. The cost of the noncumulative zoning "tax" will
be borne by other potential users of the property--that is, commercial
users and residents. As these residents generate external returns too,
the costs of noncumulative zoning are magnified.
Invisible Subsidy Noncumulative zoning has political as well as
practical drawbacks. In comparison with the obvious alternatives of
direct subsidies or tax breaks for firms, it is much less visible even
to an attentive public. The reason for this invisibility is that the
baseline of "neutral" treatment is much harder to perceive in
zoning than in taxation. When a manufacturer or developer receives tax
abatement, then it is obvious to minimally informed observers that they
are receiving an unusual benefit for which they should be held
accountable, because the layperson's baseline of expectations is
that one normally pays taxes. Thus, New York City's 421-a tax
abatement program, which provides tax relief to developers and owners of
newly built condominium apartments that have certain characteristics,
generated enormous controversy in the popular press because of the
perception that people like Calvin Klein and Derek Jeter ought not to
receive "special" tax relief. By contrast, when a manufacturer
gets a cheap lot because competing bidders have been zoned out of
existence, there is no intuitive baseline of expectations by which to
identify or measure the benefit. No one can tell why residential users
have never bid on a lot (which might not have been developed as
residential housing even if rezoned), let alone the magnitude of the
price reduction that the manufacturer received as a result of the zoning
restriction.
Subsidy programs or tax abatements have to compete with other
possible uses of local resources from schools to roads. Industrial
retention does not have to go through this political crucible. As long
as noncumulative zoning makes the costs invisible to the public, there
is little political check to ensure that the costs of industrial
retention do not massively outweigh the benefits.
CONCLUSION
The simplest solution to the problem of noncumulative zoning is to
make such zones cumulative by permitting within them all uses less
noxious than industry. Land markets are hardly perfect mechanisms for
allocating parcels among competing uses for land. Noncumulative zones,
however, are highly unlikely to outperform even imperfect markets. As
methods for abating nuisance lawsuits, such zones go far beyond what is
necessary to preserve the rational expectations of industrial users. As
mechanisms for subsidizing the industrial users' costs of acquiring
land, such zoning imposes extraordinary deadweight losses--primarily
elimination of housing opportunities--while making no effort to target
the cost reduction to those very specific industries that are likely to
generate spillover benefits for the city or region.
Rather than rely on this indiscriminate and inflexible device for
subsidizing industry, we suggest that the city rely on subsidies that
actually are earmarked for businesses that produce the touted benefits.
Ideally, businesses would apply for grants based on their capacity to
generate intellectual or labor market spillovers, ensuring a program
that is maximally discriminating and subject to regular legislative
review.
One might respond that such a subsidy-based system generates
deadweight losses of its own in the form of higher taxation needed to
generate the necessary revenue. Ideally, the city's system of
taxation would be able to tap the extra value created by cumulative
zones by using the increase in property assessments generated by the
looser zoning restrictions to generate more revenue for (among other
things) carefully targeted industrial subsidies. In such an ideal tax
system, landowners could convert their land as of right to whatever use
generated the highest returns, and cities would tax the land based on
the market value of a vacant parcel without respect to its actual use.
Such a system would impose little deadweight loss because the
landowners' actions would not change their tax liability.
Unfortunately, most states' systems of property taxation deter such
a rational system of revenue by limiting the ability of a local
government to tax certain types of property, either by underassessing
residential uses or by subjecting nonresidential uses to additional
taxes from which residential users are exempt.
The best justification for noncumulative zones, in short, might be
that they provide a second-best solution to an artificially constrained
system of local government finance. By imposing conditions on the
rezoning of noncumulatively zoned land, a city can generate various
in-kind benefits (e.g., the parks that cities get from developers who
are greasing the wheels in an effort to avoid the strictures of the
zoning regime) that would be denied to the city if it allowed land to
convert as of right. Put differently, the only way to justify
noncumulative zoning--and even this would kindly be described as a
stretch--is as a response to extreme pathologies of the laws governing
local taxation. The energy invested in its defense by urban planners and
city politicians would be more wisely devoted to improving the municipal
system of taxation so that cities would have revenue to do precisely
what noncumulative zones do so crudely--retain industry that actually
generates benefits worth subsidizing.
BY RODERICK M. HILLS JR.
New York" University Law School
AND DAVID SCHLEICHER
George Mason University Law School
Roderick M. Hills Jr. is the William T. Comfort III Professor of
Law at New York University Law School.
David Schleicher is assistant professor of law at George Mason
University Law School.
The authors gratefully acknowledge the research of Jonathan
Herczeg, NYU Law School Class of 2008, whose unpublished paper on the
history of New York City's 1961 zoning resolution provided valuable
background on the politics of the city's zoning. This paper is
adapted from the authors' paper "The Steep Costs of Using
Non-Cumulative Zoning to Preserve Land for Urban Manufacturing,"
which will be published in Vol. 77 of the University of Chicago Law
Review.