A middle ground on insider trading: allowing price-decreasing insider trading could signal when equities are overvalued.
Lambert, Thomas A.
For more than four decades, corporate law scholars have debated
whether government should prohibit insider trading, commonly defined as
stock trading on the basis of material, nonpublic information.
Participants in this long-running debate have generally assumed that
trading that decreases a stock's price should be treated the same
as trading that causes the price to rise: either both forms of trading
should be regulated or neither should. I argue for a middle-ground
position in which "price-decreasing insider trading" (sales,
short sales, and purchases of put options on the basis of negative
information) is deregulated, while "price-increasing insider
trading" (purchases of stock and call options on the basis of
positive information) remains restricted.
The reason for the proposed asymmetric treatment is that
price-decreasing insider trading provides significantly more value to
investors than price-increasing insider trading. Price-decreasing
insider trading provides an effective means of combating the problem of
overvalued equity--i.e., a stock price so high that it cannot be
justified by expected future earnings. As Harvard's Michael Jensen
has argued, overvalued equity increases the probability that corporate
managers will engage in value-destroying actions. Deregulation of
price-decreasing insider trading would allow corporate insiders--those
in the best position to know when a stock is overvalued--to signal the
market that the price is too high. Deregulation of price-increasing
insider trading could similarly remedy undervalued equity, but
undervaluation causes fewer problems than overvaluation and there are
numerous other mechanisms for addressing that sort of mispricing.
Moreover, the potential investor losses resulting from price-increasing
insider trading are higher than those caused by price-decreasing
trading.
THE INSIDER TRADING DEBATE
Ever since Henry Manne published his classic book Insider Trading
and the Stock Market, scholars have debated whether insider trading has
net benefits. Critics of insider trading attribute to it both
distributional and efficiency costs. The main distributional claim is
that there is something fundamentally wrong with traders using an
informational advantage to profit at the expense of other traders,
particularly when the advantaged traders are corporate insiders who are
supposed to be acting as agents for those who lack the informational
advantage. As for efficiency costs, the critics make several claims:
* Insider trading discourages equity investment by uninformed
outsiders because they fear trading with informed insiders, which
reduces the liquidity of capital markets.
* Insider trading encourages insiders to delay disclosures and to
make management decisions that increase share price volatility but do
not maximize firm value.
* Insider trading increases the "bid-ask" spread of stock
specialists, who systematically lose on trades with insiders (whom they
cannot identify ex ante) and who will thus tend to "insure"
against such losses by charging a small premium on each trade.
* Banning insider trading protects the corporation's property
rights over valuable information regarding firm prospects.
Proponents of deregulating insider trading discount those
arguments. Regarding the normative claim that insider trading is simply
wrong, they argue that insider trading cannot be "unfair" to
investors because they trade with full knowledge of the possibility of
insider trading. The proponents dismiss the efficiency criticisms with a
mixture of empirical evidence and theory. With respect to concerns that
insider trading increases bid-ask spreads, empirical evidence suggests
that any increases are small. While in theory the ability to engage in
insider trading might encourage managers to delay disclosures or make
management decisions aimed solely at increasing share price volatility,
deregulation advocates contend such mismanagement is unlikely. They
observe that managers generally work in teams and the theoretical
mismanagement described by ban proponents would require the explicit
unethical collusion of many managers, which is unlikely. Finally,
deregulation proponents assert that a corporate "property
right" to material nonpublic information need not be a
nontransferable interest granted to the corporation; efficiency
considerations may call for the right to be transferable and/or
initially allocated to a different party (e.g., to insiders).
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
In addition to rebutting the arguments for regulation, proponents
of deregulation have offered affirmative arguments for liberalizing
insider trading. First, they maintain that insider trading should
generally be permitted because it increases stock market efficiency
(i.e., the degree to which stock prices reflect fundamental value),
which promotes efficient resource allocation. Corporate insiders, after
all, generally know more about their company's prospects than
anyone else. When they purchase or sell their company's stock,
thereby betting their own money that the stock is mispriced, they convey
valuable information to the marketplace. Assuming their trades somehow
become public, other rational investors will likely follow their lead,
which will cause stock prices to reflect more accurately the underlying
value of the firm. More efficient stock prices will then lead to a more
efficient allocation of productive resources throughout the economy.
Deregulation advocates further maintain that corporations ought to
be allowed to adopt liberal insider trading policies because competition
in the labor and capital markets will lead corporations to adopt
efficient insider trading policies. The market for managerial labor may
reward corporations with liberal insider trading policies because the
right to make money through insider trading is valuable to potential
managers. But capital market pressures will prevent corporations from
adopting insider trading policies that are, on balance, harmful to
investors. Thus, deregulation advocates maintain, the interaction of the
labor and capital markets will incentivize firms to adopt insider
trading policies that are, on the whole, value-maximizing.
Not surprisingly, the affirmative case for liberalizing insider
trading has not gone unchallenged. Ban defenders retort that trading by
insiders conveys information only to the extent it is revealed, and even
then the message it conveys is "noisy" or ambiguous. Insiders
may trade for a variety of reasons, many of which are unrelated to their
possession of inside information. Ban defenders further maintain that
insider trading is an inefficient, clumsy, and possibly perverse
compensation mechanism.
One of the most striking aspects of the well-worn insider trading
debate is its starkness. Assuming that insider trading must be treated
as a whole, ban defenders and opponents have argued over liberalization
in all-or-nothing terms; they have not considered whether some species
of insider trading should be treated differently than others.
This article attempts to demonstrate that price-decreasing insider
trading, which consists of trading by insiders on the basis of negative
nonpublic information, provides greater net benefits to investors than
price-increasing insider trading, which consists of trading by insiders
on the basis of positive nonpublic information. Accordingly, the law
should treat price-decreasing insider trading less harshly than
price-increasing insider trading.
PERSISTENCE OF OVERVALUATION
Stock overvaluation is more likely to persist than undervaluation
and tends to cause greater harm to investors when it occurs.
Accordingly, insider trading that reduces the price of overvalued equity
toward fundamental value will provide greater investor benefits than
will insider trading that increases stock prices.
Empirical evidence suggests that the bulk of securities mispricing
occurs in the direction of overvaluation rather than undervaluation.
This should not be surprising because the two groups of individuals most
likely to provide the information that would correct stock
mispricing--corporate managers and professional stock analysts--are more
likely to emphasize positive than negative information about future
corporate profits. Let us consider these two groups, to see why this
would be.
CORPORATE MANAGERS Scholars have argued that corporate managers,
seeking to protect their reputations for trustworthiness, have a
tendency toward candor. But there are numerous reasons to believe that
managers tend to be systematically optimistic in their portrayals of
their corporations' prospects and thus are less likely to correct
overpricing than underpricing.
First, corporate managers may fail to be forthcoming with stock
price-correcting bad news because they face "last period" and
"multiple audience" problems. The last period problem exists
when the undisclosed news is so bad that it might cause insolvency or
some kind of managerial shake-up. If senior managers think the
undisclosed bad news will result in company insolvency or employment
demotion or termination, they may rationally decide that the costs to
them of misleading disclosures (or omissions) are less than the costs to
them of candor. The multiple audience problem results from the fact that
corporate managers cannot make targeted disclosures of negative
information only to shareholders. When managers make a corporate
disclosure, they inform not only shareholders, but also such corporate
constituencies as consumers, employees, and suppliers. Managers may wish
to conceal price-decreasing information in order to protect
relationships with those constituencies, despite the managers'
interest in maintaining a reputation for candor.
Well-documented cognitive biases may also lead managers to
overemphasize good news. Individuals unconsciously construe information
and events in a manner that confirms their prior beliefs, attitudes, and
impressions. Corporate managers may strongly resist evidence that
previously selected courses of action were ill-chosen. In addition,
managers may be falsely optimistic because they officially
"control" corporate endeavors. Psychologists have concluded
that individuals systematically overrate their own abilities and
achievements. Thus, corporate managers overestimate the chances of
success of the businesses under their control.
The incentives faced by lower-level managers and workers exacerbate
the good-news bias of senior executives. Each information-provider will
be tempted to tweak his message to conform to his self-interest. By the
time the price-affecting information reaches the senior managers in
charge of corporate disclosure, it is likely to have been
"massaged" so as to make underlings look good.
Finally, even if corporate managers were as likely to perceive
overvaluation as undervaluation and were equally motivated to correct
both forms of mispricing, they would be more likely to correct
undervaluation than overvaluation because they can do so more easily.
Consider a manager confronted with evidence that her company is
undervalued. She might issue a press release explaining why the market
was undervaluing her firm, or she could initiate a stock repurchase,
thereby signaling management's strong belief that the stock is
undervalued. Managers finding undervalued equity to be a chronic problem
could adopt equity-based compensation schemes for executives (e.g.,
payment in stock or stock options).
A manager confronting overvalued equity, by contrast, has few
effective options. As a practical matter, managerial candor is not an
option because a manager who directly announces to the market that his
corporation's stock is overpriced probably would not remain
employed for very long. Nor could the manager correct the mispricing by
engaging in a sale transaction that would send the reverse signal of a
stock repurchase. The signal sent by a stock buy-back is relatively
unambiguous. In contrast, a sale transaction designed to signal
overvaluation (e.g., an equity offering or a sale of treasury shares the
corporation previously purchased) is much noisier. It could easily be
interpreted as a means of raising capital for some sort of corporate
undertaking. And, of course, equity-based compensation, which helps
prevent undervaluation, exacerbates overvaluation by inducing managers
to drive the share price higher even when they know the company is
overvalued. There is thus an asymmetry in the degree to which managers
and market forces are able to correct the different species of
mispricing: the primary options available to correct negative mispricing
are not practically available when the mispricing is in the positive
direction.
STOCK ANALYSTS Stock analysts, the other individuals who are
well-positioned to identify and correct stock mispricing, also are less
likely to correct overvaluation than undervaluation. Consider the
optimism bias exhibited in the Enron debacle. In the autumn of 2001,
just weeks before Enron's December 2, 2001 bankruptcy, each of the
15 largest Wall Street firms covering Enron's stock had buy
recommendations in place. And as late as October 26, 2001--after
Enron's chief financial officer had been forced to resign, the SEC
had initiated an investigation, and the Wall Street Journal had run
several stories about Enron's earnings management problems--10 of
the 15 largest Wall Street firms covering Enron maintained buy
recommendations, as did 15 of 17 top Wall Street analysts surveyed by
Thompson Financial/First Call. Sadly, Enron was no outlier. The ratio of
buy to sell recommendations has recently been as high as 100-to-1, and
in the period immediately preceding a 60 percent drop in the NASDAQ,
only 0.8 percent of analysts' recommendations were sell or strong
sell. Thus, the evidence suggests that analysts, quick to report
undervaluation by issuing buy recommendations, are less responsive to
mispricing in the positive direction.
Empirical evidence suggests that analysts' employers have
structured their promotion and compensation schemes to favor
overvaluation. Harrison Hong and Jeffrey Kubik, for example, analyzed
the earnings forecasts and employment histories of 12,000 analysts
working for 600 brokerage houses between 1983 and 2000. They found that
analysts were systematically rewarded for being optimistic as long as
the optimism was within a range of accuracy that maintained the
credibility of the analysts. Hong and Kubik also found that relatively
optimistic analysts were much less likely to be fired or to leave a top
brokerage house, were much more likely to be hired by a better house,
and were given better assignments than their more pessimistic
(realistic?) colleagues. Thus, analysts face personal incentives to
issue enthusiastic and optimistic recommendations, and are not likely to
provide investors with the "bad news" necessary to correct
instances of overvalued equity.
OVERVALUATION AND INVESTOR HARM
Not only is overvaluation more likely than undervaluation to occur
and persist, it also tends to cause greater harm to investors. Perhaps
most importantly, overvaluation creates much larger agency costs than
undervaluation. Agency costs are the sum of the contracting, monitoring,
and bonding costs incurred to reduce the conflicts of interest between
principals and agents, plus the residual loss that occurs because it is
generally impossible to perfectly harmonize the behavior of agents with
the interests of their principals. While capital markets generally
operate as a powerful tool for minimizing agency costs (because firms
that have developed effective mechanisms for lowering such costs will be
most attractive to investors), recent economic developments suggest
that, when equity becomes overvalued, securities markets tend to
exacerbate agency costs.
Before examining why overvaluation creates substantial agency
costs, consider why undervaluation does not do so. When a firm's
equity is undervalued, the incentives of shareholders and managers are
likely to be closely aligned: both groups will usually want to increase
the stock price toward fundamental value. Shareholders prefer that
result because price appreciation increases their long-term wealth and
enhances the corporation's overall health (and thus its value) by
making it easier for the firm to raise funds in the capital markets.
Managers also prefer to increase share price because a higher stock
price enhances their job prestige and (most likely) their compensation,
and enables the corporation to be more flexible (because it can use its
high-priced stock as currency or raise more money for expansion in the
capital markets). Given the overlap in shareholders' and
managers' interests, it is unlikely that undervaluation results in
managerial behavior that diverges from shareholder interests.
In contrast, when a firm's stock is overvalued, the interests
of shareholders and managers are likely to diverge substantially.
Managers are unlikely to prefer that the stock price fall to fundamental
value because they receive benefits from a high stock price. While most
managers realize that overvaluation cannot last forever and that price
correction is likely to occur eventually, they are unlikely to take
steps to reduce price to fundamental value. Their tendencies toward
optimism push them to believe either that they can eventually cause the
firm to generate cash flows that will justify the currently inflated
price or that they will be able to exit the corporation (by resigning
their positions and selling their stock) prior to the inevitable price
correction.
On first glance, one might suppose that shareholders would
similarly prefer that equity overvaluation persist; after all, the
higher the stock price, the greater a shareholder's wealth. Because
overvaluation tends to be corrected eventually, however, medium- to
long-term shareholders generally cannot capture the transitory wealth
increase stemming from overvaluation and thus will not care to extend
periods of overvaluation. While short-term shareholders may be able to
profit from transitory periods of overvaluation, they can do so only if
they sell their stock prior to the inevitable price correction. Such a
"bail before correction" strategy is much riskier for
shareholders than for managers because shareholders know little about
corporate events that may reveal overvaluation and are thus more likely
to delay too long before selling their stock. Moreover, shareholders
possess neither actual nor apparent control over the events likely to
reveal overvaluation and will thus tend to be less optimistic than
managers about their ability to sell their stock before the inevitable
price correction. Accordingly, even short-term stockholders will value
periods of overvaluation less than managers will.
in addition, any upside experienced by shareholders during periods
of overvaluation is likely to be offset by a significant downside:
managers who seek to maintain stock prices at artificially high levels
tend to engage in value-destroying actions. In order to protect their
jobs and reputations, managers of overvalued firms often need to
"buy time"--i.e., to trick the market into maintaining the
high stock price until they can exit the firm (both as shareholders and
as managers) or can produce the corporate performance required to
justify the stock price. Consider, for example, this account of
Enron's collapse from Bethany McLean and Peter Elkind's 2003
book The Smartest Guys in the Room:
Enron's accounting games were never meant to last
forever.... The goal was to maintain the impression
that Enron was humming until [CEO Jeff] Skilling's
next big idea kicked in and started raking in real profits....
In Skilling's mind, though, there was no way he
was going to fail. He had always succeeded before, and
his successes had transformed the company. Why
would it be any different [this time]?
Such continued trickery requires beating analysts'
expectations because the capital markets routinely punish firms that
fail to meet such expectations.
The problem is that managers of overvalued firms cannot perpetually
meet analysts' expectations by exploiting legitimate value-creating
opportunities. Once those options have been exhausted, managers will
eventually turn to gimmicks that are designed to produce numbers that
appease the market but actually reduce long-term firm value.
ACQUISITIONS Because corporate acquisitions create the appearance
of growth (and thus may fool the market for at least a while), corporate
managers who have exhausted other growth options may find such
acquisitions attractive, even if they are ultimately value-reducing.
Consider, for example, recent findings by Sara Moeller, Frederick
Schlingemann, and Rent Stulz, who compared the effect of merger
announcements on the stock prices of acquiring firms during the
1998-2001 period, a period of significant equity overvaluation, with the
acquiring-firm price effects of merger announcements in the 1980s. The
authors discovered that, for the 1998-2001 period, the value of
acquiring firms declined by a total of $240 billion in the three-day
periods surrounding announcements of acquisitions. During all of the
1980s, by contrast, the loss in value of acquiring firms during the
three-day period surrounding merger announcements was only $4.2 billion.
While the acquirers' losses in the 1980s were offset by gains to
acquirees for a net synergy gain of $11.6 billion, such an offset did
not occur in the 1998-2001 period; instead the losses to acquirers
exceeded acquirees' gains for a net synergy loss of $134 billion.
Equity overvaluation seems to have influenced this value
destruction. Most of the value losses were attributable to 87
"large loss" transactions in which the loss to each acquiring
firm exceeded $1 billion. "Wealth destruction on a massive
scale" appears to have occurred because overvalued bidders used
their high-priced stock to finance deals that, from an investor's
perspective, should not have been pursued.
INVESTMENTS Equity overvaluation also tends to destroy firm value
by leading managers to pursue certain greenfield investments that have a
negative net present value (NPV) and to avoid other investments that
have a positive NPV. When equity is overvalued, firm managers
effectively have more capital to invest. Most obviously, they may pay
for expenses using their firm's inflated stock as currency. In
addition, they can raise more cash by issuing new equity at prices
reflecting their firm's overvaluation. Empirical data indicate that
managers do, in fact, take advantage of periods of overvaluation by
issuing equity. Equity overvaluation thus increases the resources with
which managers may pursue firm expansion, creating a version of what
Jensen has termed the "agency costs of free cash flow."
Because firm expansion often provides managers with private benefits
that are not available to shareholders (e.g., greater job prestige,
perhaps higher compensation), managers have an incentive to pursue
expansion beyond the value-maximizing point--the point at which the
corporation's marginal benefit created equals its marginal cost of
expansion. Overvalued equity exacerbates those agency costs by expanding
the resources with which managers may pursue firm expansion.
In addition to causing active value destruction through imprudent
acquisitions and unwise greenfield investments, overvaluation may cause
passive value destruction by encouraging managers to forgo positive NPV
projects. Because the dominant strategy of managers of overvalued firms
is, in Jensen's words, to "postpone the day of reckoning until
[they] are gone or [they] figure out how to resolve the issue,"
they will look for opportunities to conceal their firm's
overvaluation from the market. One way to do so is to delay
value-enhancing investment expenditures in order to meet quarterly
earnings expectations and avoid the value reassessment that accompanies
missing such an expectation. Research suggests that this sort of
value-sacrificing behavior is widespread. In a recent survey, 80 percent
of corporate CFOs stated that they would be willing to delay
discretionary expenditures on research and development, advertising, and
maintenance in order to meet earnings expectations, and over 55 percent
stated that they would "delay starting a new project even if this
entails a small sacrifice in value" in order to meet a target.
PRICE-DECREASING INSIDER TRADING
In addition to providing greater investor benefits than
price-increasing insider trading, price-decreasing insider trading is
also likely to impose lower investor costs. To see why this is so,
consider how insider trading may cause harm to the corporation and how
the law affords asymmetric treatment to the use of different types of
secret information.
SQUANDERING OPPORTUNITIES The most plausible negative effect of
insider trading is the thwarting of valuable corporate transactions that
could otherwise be accomplished. Suppose, for example, that a mining
corporation discovers a valuable ore deposit and wishes to purchase
surrounding land. It will want to keep the ore discovery secret so as to
procure a favorable price on the surrounding land. If insiders aware of
the discovery begin buying the corporation's stock, thereby causing
a precipitous price increase, landowners may become suspicious and raise
their price demands. Price-increasing insider trading could thereby
squander a corporate opportunity.
Price-decreasing insider trading could also thwart value-creating
corporate transactions. The relevant situation would be one in which the
corporation had an interest in keeping its stock's inflated price
above its true value in order to accomplish some transaction. For
example, the corporation might desire to use its overvalued stock as
consideration for a purchase, to issue new equity at an inflated price,
or to secure credit on favorable terms. Price-decreasing insider trading
could squander such corporate opportunities.
VALUE VS. DEFECTS If both price-increasing and price-decreasing
insider trading have the potential to undermine worthwhile corporate
projects, why ban only the price-increasing variety? The answer lies in
the more general treatment of secret information by the law.
When it comes to a contracting party's use of secret
information in executing a deal, the law generally distinguishes between
secret "good news" (e.g., inside information about hidden
value) and secret "bad news" (e.g., inside information about
hidden defects). In order to encourage people to search out hidden
value, the law permits the use of the former type of inside information,
but it generally allows counter-parties to void transactions that
involve the use of the latter sort of information. Thus, transactions
involving the suppression of information about overvaluation (hidden
defects) are not typically available to the corporation, but
transactions involving suppression of information suggesting
undervaluation (hidden value) are.
The upshot is that price-decreasing insider trading, unlike the
price-increasing variety, generally cannot thwart otherwise available
corporate opportunities. Price-decreasing insider trading thus imposes
lower costs on investors.
CONCLUSION
Undervaluation is more likely to be self-correcting than
overvaluation. In the long run, undervaluation is unlikely to impose
significant costs on investors, while overvaluation is likely to do so.
Insider trading that pushes a stock's price upward toward actual
value may cause harm to the corporation and its investors. Insider
trading that pushes an inflated price downward toward value is unlikely
to do so.
Taken together, these observations suggest that an asymmetric
insider trading policy that permits some form of price-decreasing
insider trading, while generally banning price-increasing insider
trading, is the policy that investors and managers would likely bargain
for were they able (practically and legally) to do so. Accordingly, the
law should liberalize price-decreasing insider trading (subject only to
contractual restraints imposed by corporations themselves), while
continuing to regulate price-increasing insider trading.
Readings
* "Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and
Takeovers," by Michael C. Jensen. American Economics Review, Vol.
76 (Papers and Proceedings) (1986).
* "Agency Costs of Overvalued Equity," by Michael C.
Jensen. Financial Management, Vol. 34 (2005).
* "Analyst Forecasting Errors and Their Implications for
Security Analysis," by David N. Dreman and Michael A. Berry.
Financial Analyst Journal, Vol. 51 (1995).
* "Analyzing the Analysts: Career Concerns and Biased Earnings
Forecasts," by Harrison Hong and Jeffrey D. Kubik. Journal of
Finance, Vol. 58 (2003).
* "Bid, Ask and Transaction Prices in a Specialist Market with
Heterogeneously Informed Traders," by Lawrence R. Glosten and Paul
R. Milgrom. Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 14 (1985).
* Corporation Law and Economics, by Stephen M. Bainbridge.
Foundation Press, 2002.
* "Earnings Surprises, Growth Expectations, and Stock Returns,
or Don't Let an Earnings Torpedo Sink Your Portfolio," by
Douglas J. Skinner and Richard G. Sloan. Review of Accounting Studies,
Vol. 7 (2002).
* "Enron, Fraud and Securities Reform: An Enron
Prosecutor's Perspective," by John R. Kroger. University of
Colorado Law Review, Vol. 76 (2005).
* "Equity Mispricing: It's Mostly on the Short
Side," by Mark T. Finn et al. Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 55
(1999).
* "From Fairness to Contract: The New Direction of the Rules
Against Insider Trading," by Jonathan R. Macey. Hofstra Law Review,
Vol. 13 (1984).
* "Gatekeeper Failure and Reform: The Challenge of Fashioning
Relevant Reforms," by John C. Coffee, Jr. Boston University Law
Review, Vol. 84 (2004).
* "Information Effects on the Bid-Ask Spread," by Thomas
E. Copeland and Dan Galai. Journal of Finance, Vol. 38 (1983).
* "Insider Trading in a Rational Expectations Economy,"
by Lawrence M. Asubel. American Economic Review, Vol. 80 (1990).
* "Insider Trading and the Bid-Ask Spread: A Critical
Evaluation of Adverse Selection in Market Making," by Stanislav
Dolgopolov. Capital University Law Review, Vol. 33 (2004).
* Insider Trading and the Stock Market, by Henry G. Manne. Free
Press, 1966.
* "Insider Trading: Rule 10b-5, Disclosure and Corporate
Privacy," by Kenneth E. Scott. Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 9
(1980).
* Judgment in Managerial Decision Making, 3rd ed., by Max H.
Bazerman. Wiley, 1994.
* "Mandatory Disclosure and the Protection of Investors,"
by Frank H. Easterbrook and Daniel R. Fischel. Virginia Law Review, Vol.
70 (1984).
* "Market Timing and Capital Structure," by Malcolm Baker
and Jeffrey Wurgler. Journal of Finance, Vol. 57 (2002).
* "Organized Illusions: A Behavioral Theory of Why
Corporations Mislead Stock Market Investors (and Cause Other Social
Harms)," by Donald C. Langevoort. University of Pennsylvania Law
Review, Vol. 146 (1997).
* "Predicting Individual Analyst Earnings Forecasts," by
Scott E. Stickel. Journal of Accounting Research, Vol. 28 (1990).
* "Securities and Secrets: Insider Trading and the Law of
Contracts," by Saul Levmore. Virginia Law Review, Vol. 68 (1982).
* "Technology, Information Production, and Market
Efficiency," by Gene D'Avolio et al. Harvard Institute for
Economic Research, discussion paper 1929, 2001.
* "The Economic Implications of Corporate Financial
Reporting," by John R. Graham, Campbell R. Harvey, and Shivaram
Rajgopal. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 10550,
2005.
* "The Effect of Insider Trading Rules on the Internal
Efficiency of the Large Corporation," by Robert J. Haft. Michigan
Law Review, Vol. 80 (1982).
* "The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency," by Ronald J.
Gilson and Reinier H. Kraakman. Virginia Law Review, Vol. 70 (1984).
* "The Regulation of Insider Trading," by Dennis W.
Carlton and Daniel R. Fischel. Stanford Law Review, Vol. 35 (1983).
* "The Theory and Practice of Corporate Finance: Evidence from
the Field," by John R. Graham and Campbell R. Harvey. Journal of
Financial Economics, Vol. 60 (2001).
* "Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and
Ownership Structure," by Michael C. Jensen and William H. Meckling.
Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3 (1976).
* "Unsafe at Any Price: A Reply to Manne, Insider Trading and
the Stock Market," by Roy A. Schotland. Virginia Law Review, Vol.
53 (1967).
* "Vicarious Liability for Fraud on Securities Markets: Theory
and Evidence," by Jennifer H. Arlen and William J. Carney.
University of Illinois Law Review, 1992.
* "Wealth Destruction on a Massive Scale? A Study of
Acquiring-Firm Returns in the Recent Merger Wave," by Sara B.
Moeller, Frederik P. Schlingemann, and Rene M. Stulz. Journal of
Finance, Vol. 60 (2005).
BY THOMAS A. LAMBERT
University of Missouri
Thomas A. Lambert is associate professor of law at the University
of Missouri.
This article draws on the author's paper "Overvalued
Equity and the Case for an Asymmetric insider Trading Regime," Wake
Forest Law Review, Vol. 41 (2006).