Not the time to cap and trade.
Lipford, Jody ; Yandle, Bruce
We were not surprised in late September 2009 when China's
president Hu Jintao announced to the United Nations Assembly that his
country would not be a party to a global greenhouse gas reduction
commitment. Instead of locking China into a promise that it would not
keep, President Hu indicated that he would go forward with forest carbon
sequestration and expanded "clean energy" production. Without
apologizing, Mr. Hu indicated that China would not promote greenhouse
gas reductions at the expense of GDP growth and that China's carbon
emissions will continue to increase in the future, though at a reduced
rate. That was exactly what our research suggested he would do.
It is also exactly what the United States should do.
The United States and other developed nations have apparently
decided that some international emissions reduction agreement must be
reached, but no one has said how much it will cost to achieve those
reductions. To some, this may not matter very much; whatever the cost,
the expected benefits make the effort worthwhile, as we may face doom
otherwise. However, our research suggests that costs matter a lot. And
differences in cost across countries limit the prospects of gaining a
global agreement to reduce carbon by dramatic amounts.
We have just completed a study that looks at the relationship
between per capita real GDP and total carbon emissions--1950 through
2004--for each of the G8 countries (Canada, France, Germany, Italy,
Japan, Russia, the United Kingdom, and the United States) as well as the
emerging economic powers Brazil, China, India, Mexico, and South Africa.
Our work shows that, in the past, each G8 country, except Russia, and
China experienced a period of reduced emissions per unit of per capita
GDP, but those emissions are now increasing. For Russia, Brazil, India,
Mexico, and South Africa, there was no recent period of decline in
emissions per unit of per capita GDP.
Indur Goklany's research on the history of U.S. air pollution
control tells us that when faced with the possibility of real harm from
a pollutant, the American people have always taken action to mitigate
that harm. As incomes rise, Americans and other people in higher income
countries reduce emissions that pose less certain threats. But if costs
rise for dealing with those less harmful emissions, people back away,
even as incomes continue to rise. The retreat will be even faster when
incomes fall during periods of extended recession.
As suggested by the behavior we observed in our work, the control
of carbon emissions is a case where the costs imposed by not taking
action are apparently less than the cost of doing something now. Couple
that with the current economic woes, and it seems unlikely that the
United States or any other nation would undertake serious emissions
controls that would threaten GDP growth.
But what would happen if the United States were to push ahead with
carbon control anyway? Our estimates show that China emits 2,173,000
metric tons of carbon to yield a $1 increase in per capita income. The
United States emits 204,000 metric tons to get a dollar, and France
emits just 2,470 metric tons to accomplish the same end. In other words,
significant and costly reductions in carbon emissions from the United
States or France will quickly be offset by expanding GDP in China.
Mr. Hu has promised that China will continue to grow per capita
GDP. So should the United States.
The 1,400-page Waxman-Markey climate change bill containing a
costly cap-and-trade program and a rich barrel of pork for favored
constituents has passed the U.S. House and is now being debated in the
Senate. If adopted, the cost of the proposed program, according to U.S.
Treasury and other estimates, would equal a tax that generates revenues
ranging from $100 billion to $200 billion annually. This turns out be an
annual tax on each U.S. household of between $880 and $1,761--or as much
as a 15 percent tax increase. If the proposal becomes law, American
households will be paying for carbon reductions that will easily be
offset by emission growth in China and elsewhere. This, of course, is
the prisoner's dilemma faced by all who seek to do something about
climate change.
A more sensible and less costly policy option would be for the
United States to focus on improving incentives for discovering new,
cleaner technologies. Chief among these is elimination of the capital
gains tax. Instead of spending billions annually on carbon permits,
millions might be spent to support carbon mitigation experiments that
will reduce control costs for the developed and the developing world.
These experiments could include the application of new technologies that
mitigate carbon emissions once in the atmosphere as suggested recently
by Bjorn Lomborg in a September 1, 2009 Wall Street Journal column. And
then, as suggested by China, there is the option to expand the use of
proven technologies such as nuclear-generated power, carbon
sequestration, and ocean injection.
Our research suggests that Copenhagen will not see acceptance of
binding agreements to make meaningful reductions in carbon emissions.
This is not the time to cap and trade. But it is the time to get serious
about applying our scarce resources to actions that are known to improve
human well being.
BY JODY LIPFORD, Presbyterian College AND BRUCE YANDLE, Clemson
University
Jody Lipford is professor of economics at Presbyterian College.
Bruce Yandle is Alumni Distinguished Professor of Economics
Emeritus at Clemson University, Distinguished Adjunct Professor of
Economics at the Mercatus Center at George Mason University, and senior
fellow at PERC.