Roles of literacy and life expectancy in promoting economic well-being across developing countries.
Rahman, Matiur ; Khan, M. Moosa
Abstract
This paper studies the roles of literacy and life expectancy in
promoting economic well-being (real GDP per capita) using panel data
across 99 developing countries over 1990-2008. The panel unit root tests
reveal nonstationarity of each variable with I(l) behavior. The Pedroni
panel cointegration tests confirm the presence of a long-run equilibrium
relationship among the above variables. The estimates of the
error-correction model unveil long-run unidirectional causal flows from
literacy and life expectancy to real GDP per capita with strong
short-run interactive bidirectional feedbacks underscoring the
importance of investment in education and healthcare services in
promoting economic well-being across the above developing countries.
Keywords: Literacy, Life Expectancy, Well-Being, Panel
Cointegration
I. INTRODUCTION
The traditional neoclassical economic growth models followed by
Solow (1956) incorporate capital and labor as variable inputs in the
production of output subject to the law of diminishing returns to scale.
They ignored the roles of non-economic variables such as human capital
and human health variables in economic growth. To keep the economy
growing, they depended on infusions of exogenous technological progress.
Yet the reality is quite contrary that there are other factors outside
the realm of neoclassical growth models that are accountable for
maintaining high growth performance in selected developing countries.
They are addressed in a new paradigm known as endogenous growth models
as developed in the mid-1980s (Romer, 1986). They have enhanced the
understanding of the mysteries of high growth performance of East Asian
economies.
The growth in real GDP per capita is broadly used as a proxy for
economic well-being. This emphasizes only the quantity aspect of
prosperity without paying due attention to quality of life proxied by
life expectancy while that should also be an important component of
economic development. Gaining literacy through schooling helps formation
of human capital and improving the quality of workforce augmenting
productivity. Productivity increases are expected to be correlated with
higher wages. Quality of life is reflected through improvement in life
expectancy as a result of enhanced access to adequate nutrition intakes
and improved healthcare services. Improvement in human capital and
longer longevity of people are conjectured to contribute to larger
output.
The growth in real GDP per capita is conditional on the initial
level of human capital in addition to the initial level of real GDP per
capita (Mankiw, Romer, and Well, 1992). Using the World Bank typology,
countries are blocked into four, namely, "High Income",
"Upper Middle Income", "Lower Middle Income", and
"Low Income". Such classifications are used to study the
convergence issue (Barro and Sala-iMartin, 1992). The primary focus of
this paper is to explore the influences of literacy and life expectancy
on real GDP per capita. Most of the studies on this issue utilized time
series data. The use of panel cointegration in this paper provides new
perspectives. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. The
next section provides a brief survey of the related literature.
Individual section thereafter outlines the empirical methodology,
reports results, and offers conclusions in sequence.
II. BRIEF SURVEY OF THE RELATED LITERATURE
Social indicators have been used informally for a long time in
economics to assess the state of the nation and programs towards
national objectives. Measuring people's quality of life emphasizes
human well-being and particularly issues of equity, poverty and gender.
Social development indicators are a major challenge for policies aiming
to foster sustainable human development that involves improving the
social, economic, cultural, political and environmental conditions of a
nation to develop the present quality of human life without compromising
future generations (Medina, 1996).
The conceptualization of human development and the strategies to
foster it have varied through history. During the 1960s, the main
concern was the economic growth having interest in the productive value
of investment in training and education (Colclough, 1993). The
assessment of human development was principally concentrated in the
value of human capital (Becker, 1964; Schultz, 1961). In the 1970s, the
international concern focused upon poverty alleviation and income
distribution (Colclough, 1993). International programs of healthcare and
primary schooling targeted the poorest segments of the society. By the
end of the 1970s, the focus shifted towards growth concerns and social
developments as an interdisciplinary approach (Taylor and Jodine, 1983).
The developmental approach, in general, replaced the efforts of
human development of the 1970s with an encouragement for privatization
and commitment in support of basic educational and health goals.
Meanwhile, the United Nations Development Program (UNDP) was emphasizing
the need for placing people at the center of development because
"people are the real wealth of nations". The policies of the
1990s focused on poverty alleviation by proving the basic services to
the poor. Primary education, health care, family planning, and nutrition
and self-employment programs were among the most important services.
Unfortunately, a sound measure of human development is not yet
available. The "Human Development Index - HDI" developed by
the UNDP has significant conceptual limitations which misjudge the
measurement of social development. A new social indicator "Literate
Life Expectancy" as developed in Lutz is innovative, simple, and
accounts for only two essential elements of social development: literacy
and life expectancy (Lutz, 1995). Education and healthcare are the
leading factors for social development. Basic education and health are
simple measured by the number of people who are literate and by the
number of years of personal survival, respectively.
Traditionally, nations strive to achieve a higher real GDP per
capita and it erroneously considered the single and most important
element to measure their national prosperity. The use of real GDP per
capita as an indicator of social development fails to capture the
distribution of economic progress. This might produce a misleading
picture of a country's social development, insofar as it does not
reflect important elements of social prosperity such as education and
health. The use of literate life expectancy would be a better proxy for
social development.
The accumulation of human capital has gained a central role in the
recent growth literature. Lucas (1988) has postulated that human capital
is an input in the production process like any other; its accumulation
implies capital deepening with an associated period of accelerated
growth towards a new steady state growth path of output. Moreover, human
capital is necessary for the discovery of new technologies and thus its
stock is permanently related to the growth rate of output (Aghion and
Howitt, 1998; Nelson and Phelps, 1966; Romer, 1990). Bassanini and
Scarpetta (2001) find a significant impact of human capital accumulation
on output per capita growth. Although there is strong theoretical
support for a key role of human capital in the growth process, empirical
evidence is not crystal clear. Card (1999) and Psacharopoulos (1994)
find that one additional year of schooling is associated with between 5
and 15 percent higher earning across countries. Also, Jorgenson et al.
(1987), and Young (1994, 1997) provide some additional support to a
significant growth impact of human capital accumulation. In contrast,
Benhabib and Spiegel (1994), Pritchett (1997), and Topel (1999) find
that the evolution of human capital over time is not statistically
related to output growth.
III. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY
Panel data, which has both a cross sectional as well as a
longitudinal (time series) component provide a convenient way to study
phenomena, where a statistically adequate number of cross-sectional
observations may not be obtainable at a given point in time. Thus, the
combination of a time series and cross-sections can enhance the quality
and quantity of data in ways that would be impossible using only one of
these two dimensions (Gujarati, 2003). Our study provides an example of
such a situation where incorporating observations on the variables over
successive time periods allows us to expand the informational content of
the data. Furthermore, since the length of the time series is small
compared to the number of cross-sections, the effects of autocorrelation
are small if not negligible. Panel data estimation models include the
constant coefficient (pooled), the fixed effects and the random effects
regression models.
In order to test for the existence of a long-run equilibrium
relationship among real GDP per capita (y), life expectancy (x) and
literacy rate (z) in a heterogeneous panel consisting of 99 developing
countries (Appendix I) over the period 1990-2008, the following model is
specified:
[y.sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.i] + [[beta].sub.i] [x.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.j] [z.sub.it] + [[gamma].sub.i][D.sub.it] + [e.sub.it] (1)
where i = 1,..., N and t = 1,..., T
In model (1), [[alpha].sub.i] shows the possibility of
country-specific fixed effects and [[beta].sub.i] as well as
[[beta].sub.j] allow for heterogeneous cointegrating vectors. And,
[[gamma].sub.t] represents time dependent common shocks, captured by
common-time dummies ([D.sub.it]), that might simultaneously affect all
the 99 developing countries included in the study. Model (1) is
estimated by the recently proposed Pedroni (2000, 2001) panel
Fully-Modified Ordinary Least Squares cointegration technique
(hereafter, Panel FM-OLS), which adjusts for the presence of endogeneity
between literacy and life expectancy, and serial correlation in the
data. This method is an appropriate technique, especially when there are
endogeneous macroeconomic factors that can cause co-movements between
the above variables.
Before estimating model (1), it is required that the order of
integration of the variables be determined by using panel unit root
tests. If all variables are found to be I(1), then by using the Pedroni
panel cointegration tests (Pedroni, 1999, 2000, 2001), it will be
investigated whether they are cointegrated. These above-mentioned tests
and techniques are warranted to make sure that no spurious regression
phenomenon exists in the estimation of [[beta].sub.i] and
[[beta].sub.j]. In order to test for the presence of a unit root in the
panel data series under study, recent panel unit root tests proposed by
Im, Pesaran and Shin (1997, 2003), Maddala-Wu (1999), and the Breitung
(2000) test are employed. In all these tests, the null hypothesis is
non-stationarity (for details, see Breitung, 2000). Im, Pesaran and Shin
(1997, 2003) have proposed the following panel unit root test statistic,
[t.sub.IPS], which is applicable to heterogeneous cross-sectional
panels:
[t.sub.IPS] = [square root of N]([bar.t] - E
[[t.sub.i]|[[rho].sub.i] = 0]) / [square root of Var]
[t.sub.i]|[[rho].sub.i] = 0] (2)
where, N is the number of countries, [bar.t] is the mean of the
computed Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) statistics for individual
countries included in the panel, [[rho].sub.i] is the autoregressive
root, E[[t.sub.i]|[[rho].sub.i] = 0] and Var [[t.sub.i] | [[rho].sub.i]
= 0] denote respectively, the moments of mean and variance tabulated
obtained from Monte Carlo simulation and tabulated by Im, Pesaran, and
Shin (1997, 2003). The statistic [t.sub.IPS] approaches in probability a
standard normal distribution as N and T tend to infinity. The Maddala-Wu
panel data unit root test is a much more flexible test and is applicable
even to unbalanced panels and it is valid for individual ADF tests with
different lag-lengths. The Maddala-Wu test statistic [lambda], which has
a chi-square distribution with 2N degrees of freedom under the null
hypothesis is expressed as:
[lambda] = -2 [N.summation over (i=1)] [l.sub.n] [P.sub.i] (3)
where, [P.sub.i] refers to the probability values from individual
ADF unit root tests for each country in the panel. Breitung (2000)
formulates a panel unit root test statistic which corrects for the
dramatic loss of power associated with the IPS (Im, Pesaran and Shin)
test when individual ADF tests include a trend in the specification.
Breitung panel unit root test has greater power than that of IPS test.
In order to determine whether in the panel under study, the series
[y.sub.it], [x.sub.it] and [z.sub.it] are cointegrated, Pedroni's
panel cointegration tests are conducted (see Pedroni (1999). Following
Pedroni (1999, 2001), the null hypothesis of no cointegration against
the alternative of cointegration is tested using the seven test
statistics, proposed by Pedroni, which consist of four panel and three
group test statistics. Each of these panel test statistics under
appropriate standardization is distributed asymptotically as a normal
distribution and expressed as follows:
[[theta].sub.NT] - [mu][square root of N]/[square root of v] [right
arrow] N(0,1) (4)
where, [mu] and v are the mean and variance respectively of the
underlying individual series. The values [mu] and v are simulated and
provided by Pedroni (2000, 2001) and their numerical values depend upon
the presence of a constant, time trend, and the number of regressors in
the cointegration regression. The rejection of the null hypothesis of no
cointegration requires that the absolute value of the calculated test
statistics exceed the critical value using four panel cointegration
tests in this paper.
Subsequently, the following error-correction model Engle and
Granger (1987) is estimated on the evidence of a cointegrating
relationship:
[DELTA][[gamma].sub.it] = [alpha] + [k.summation over
(t=1)][beta][DELTA][[gamma].sub.it-i1] + [1.summation over (t=1)] [phi]
[DELTA][x.sub.it-1] + [m.summation over (t=1)] [psi][DELTA] [z.sub.it-1]
+ [pi][[??].sub.t-1] + [u.sub.it] (5)
For long-run convergence and causal relationship, the estimated
coefficient ([??]) of the error-correction term ([[??].sub.t-1]) is
expected to be negative and statistically significant. The estimated
[beta], [phi], and [psi] reveal short-run interactive bidirectional
feedback relationships.
The appropriate lag-lengths are determined by the Akaike
information criterion (Akaike, 1969). Annual data from 1990 through 2008
are obtained from various issues of the World Development Indicators
(CD-ROM). The 99 countries studied in this paper are listed in the
Appendix.
IV. RESULTS
The panel unit root test results are reported as follows:
Table 1
Unit Root Tests
Variables [t.sub.IPS] Maddala-Wu [lambda] Breitung
y -1.185 38.281 0.096
(0.125) (0.312) (0.538)
x -0.912 35.061 -0.805
(0.186) (0.451) (0.210)
z -0.814 37.146 -0.912
(0.206) (0.462) (0.201)
Order of Integration
[DELTA]y -4.179 52.061 -4.51
(0.001) * (0.025) * (0.000) *
[DELTA]y -8.163 110.322 -8.56
(0.001) * (0.000) * (0.000) *
[DELTA]y -5.145 115.041 -6.36
(0.001) * (0.000) * (0.000) *
Note: Probability values are reported in parentheses. The critical
IPS value at 5% level or significance is 1.64. The critical value of
[x.sup.2] is 34.
Table 1 shows that each variable is nonstationary in levels and
reveals I(1) behavior providing justification for the application of the
methodology as outlined in the preceding section. The Pedroni panel
cointegration test results are reported as follows:
Table 2
Pedroni Panel Cointegration Tests @
Test Statistic Value
V-Statistic 0.881 *
6-Statistic -6.619 *
pp-Statistic -7.591 *
ADF-Statistic -4.274 *
* Denotes significance at 1% level.
@ Only four tests are reported in lieu of seven.
As the above computed test statistics in Table 2 are significant at
1% level, the null hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected. This
inference supports the fact that the variables under study depict
long-run equilibrium relationship. Thus, the estimation of the
error-correction model is in order.
Finally, the estimates of the error-correction model (5) are
reported as follows:
Table 3
Estimates of Error-Correction Model (5)
Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob.
C 80.40116 6.762649 0.0000
[[??]i.sub.t-1] -0.101800 -4.415521 0.0000
[DELTA][y.sub.it.-1] 0.452172 11.88963 0.0000
[DELTA][y.sub.it.-2] -0.017927 -0.470894 0.6379
[DELTA][y.sub.it.-3] 0.174127 4.430123 0.0000
[DELTA][z.sub.it] 7.185365 0.548620 0.5834
[DELTA][z.sub.it-1] 4.073940 0.298219 0.7656
[DELTA][z.sub.it-2] -4.967048 -0.371377 0.7105
[DELTA][z.sub.it-3] 3.166438 0.245369 0.8062
[DELTA][x.sub.it] -1.359010 -0.145981 0.8840
[DELTA][x.sub.it-1] 79.72767 -1.082573 0.2794
[DELTA][x.sub.it-2] 223.8529 2.807383 0.0051
[DELTA][x.sub.it-3] -207.5076 2.726456 0.0066
[[bar.R].sup.2] = 0.288, F=24.362, DW=1.862.
In Table 3, the coefficient of the error-correction term
([[??].sub.t-1]) and the associated t-value confirm a strong long-run
casual flow from changes in life expectancy at birth and adult literacy
rate to changes in real GDP per capita. The sum of the coefficients of
the subsequent variables and the F-statistic at 24.362 indicate
interactive bidirectional positive feedbacks among the variables in the
short run. In other words, the above variables positively reinforce each
other in the short run for stronger influences on real GDP per capita in
the long run. The numerical value of at 0.288 is quite modest and the
DW-value at 1.862 indicates near-absence of serial correlation.
V. CONCLUSIONS
Each variable is nonstationary with I(1) behavior. The Pedroni
panel cointegration tests depict cointegration among real GDP per
capita, life expectancy and literacy rate. The estimates of the
error-correction model confirm a long-run equilibrium relationship among
the above variables and a unidirectional causal flow from the
explanatory variables to the dependent variable. Furthermore, there are
evidences of strong short-run interactive and positive bidirectional
feedback effects among the above variables. Thus, the evolving economic
growth dynamics should include life expectancy and literacy in
explaining the growth process more comprehensively.
For policy implications, all developing countries should increase
investment in education and healthcare services to enhance economic
well-being even further in the long run. Moreover, inclusions of these
two variables in the neoclassical growth models would augment their
ability to explain economic growth more precisely. Education would also
improve the quality of labor force that plays a major role in the modern
economic growth process. In brief, social progress and economic
well-being ought to advance in tandem as one feeds into the other.
APPENDIX
(List of Countries)
1) Albania
2) Algeria
3) Argentina
4) Armenia
5) Bahrain
6) Bangladesh
7) Barbados
8) Belize
9) Benin
10) Bolivia
11) Botswana
12) Brazil
13) Bulgaria
14) Burundi
15) Cameroon
16) Cape Verde
17) Central African Republic
18) Chad
19) Chile
20) China
21) Colombia
22) Comoros
23) Congo, Rep.
24) Costa Rica
25) Cote d'Ivoire
26) Cyprus
27) Dominican Republic
28) Ecuador
29) El Salvador
30) Estonia
31) Ethiopia
32) Ghana
33) Greece
34) Guatemala
35) Haiti
36) Honduras
37) Hungary
38) India
39) Indonesia
40) Iran, Islamic Rep.
41) Israel
42) Italy
43) Jamaica
44) Jordan
45) Kenya
46) Lao PDR
47) Latvia
48) Lesotho
49) Liberia
50) Lithuania
51) Macao, China
52) Malawi
53) Malaysia
54) Mali
55) Malta
56) Mauritanian
57) Mauritius
58) Mexico
59) Moldova
60) Mongolia
61) Morocco
62) Mozambique
63) Namibia
64) Nicaragua
65) Niger
66) Nigeria
67) Oman
68) Panama
69) Paraguay
70) Peru
71) Philippines
72) Portugal
73) Puerto Rico
74) Romania
75) Russian Federation
76) Rwanda
77) Senegal
78) Singapore
79) South Africa
80) Spain
81) Sri Lanka
82) Sudan
83) Syrian Arab Rep.
84) Tajikistan
85) Tanzania
86) Thailand
87) Togo
88) Trinidad and Tobago
89) Tunisia
90) Turkey
91) Uganda
92) Ukraine
93) United Arab Emirates
94) Uruguay
95) Uzbekistan
96) Venezuela, RB
97) Yemen, Rep.
98) Zambia
99) Zimbabwe
References
Aghion, P. and P. Howitt. (1998), Endogenous Growth Theory.
Cambridge, Mass: The MIT Press.
Akaike, H. (1969), Fitting Autoregression for Prediction. Annals of
the Istitute of Statistical Mathematics. 21, 243-47.
Barro, R. J. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1992), Convergence. Journal of
Political Economy. 100, 223251.
Bassanini, A. and S. Scarpetta (2001), Does Human Capital Matter
for Growth in OECD Countries? Evidence from Pooled mean-group Estimates.
Working Paper No. 282, Economics Department, OECD.
Becker, G. S. (1964), Human Capital. New York: Columbia University
Press.
Benhabib, J. and M. Spiegel (1994), The Role of Human Capital in
Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-country Data.
Journal of Monetary Economics. 43, 143-174.
Breitung, J. (2000), The Local Power of Some Unit Root Tests for
Panel Data, in B. Baltagi (ed.), Nonstationary Panels, Panel
Cointegration and Dynamic Panels. Advances in Econometrics. 15, 161-178.
Card, D. (1999), The Causal Effects of Schooling on Earnings. in O.
Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.) Handbook of Labor Economics. Amsterdam,
North Holland.
Colclough, C. (1993), Human Development: Towards a more Integrated
Framework for Planning in the 1990s. Discussion Paper 323. Brighton,
England: Institute of Development Studies.
Engle, R. and Granger, C. W. J. (1987), Co-integration and
Error-correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing. Econometrica.
35, 315-329.
Gujarati, D. (2003), Basic Econometrics. Fourth Edition.
McGraw-Hill.
Im, K. S., M. H. Pesaran, and Y. Shin (1997), Testing for Unit Root
in Heterogeneous Panels. DAE Working Paper No. 9526. University of
Cambridge.
Im, K. S., M. H. Pesaran, and Y. Shin (2003), Testing for Unit
Roots in Heterogeneous Panels. Journal of Econometrics. 115, 53-74.
Jorgenson, D. W., F. M. Gollop and B. M. Fraumeni (1987),
Productivity and U.S. Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Lucas, R. E. (1988), On the Mechanics of Economic Development.
Journal of Monetary Economics. 22.
Lutz, W. (1995), Literate Life Expectancy. POPNET 26 (Winter), pp.
1-5, Luxemburg, Austria. International Institute for Applied Systems
Analysis.
Maddala, G. and S. Wu (1999), A Comparative Study of Unit Root
Tests and a New Simple Test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics. 61, 631-652.
Mankiw, G. N., D. Romer and D. N. Well (1992), A Contribution to
the Empirics of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 107,
407-37.
Medina, S. (1996), Implementing a New Indicator of Social
Development in Mexico: Literate Life Expectancy (LLE). WP-96-103.
International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenberg,
Austria.
Nelson, R. and E. Phelps (1966), Investment in Humans,
Technological Diffusion and Economic Growth. American Economic Review.
56, 69-75.
Pedroni, P. (1999), Critical Values of Cointegration Tests in
Heterogeneous Panels with Multiple Regressors. Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics. 61, 653-670.
Pedroni, P. (2000), Fully Modified OLS for Heterogeneous
Cointegrated Panels, in Baltagi, B. and C.D. Kao (Eds.), Advances in
Econometrics, Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration and Dynamic
Panels. New York: Elsevier Science. pp. 93-130.
Pedroni, P. (2001), Purchasing Power Parity Tests in Cointegrated
Panels. Review of Economics and Statistics. 83, 727-731.
Pritchett, L. (1997), Where has all the Education Gone? Policy
Research Working Paper No. 1581. The World Bank. Washington D.C.
Psacharopoulos, G. (1994), Returns to Investment in Education: A
Global Update. World Development. 22, 1325-1343.
Romer, P. M. (1986), Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth.
Journal of Political Economy. 94, 1002-1037.
Romer, P. M. (1990), Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of
Political Economy. 98, 70-102.
Solow, R. M. (1956), A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 70, 65-94.
Schultz, T. W. (1961), Investment in Human Capital. American
Economic Review. 51, 1-17.
Taylor, C. L., and D. A. Jodine (1983), World Handbook of Political
and Social Indicators. Third Edition. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Topel, R. (1999), Labor Markets and Economic Growth in O.
Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics. Amsterdam,
North Holland.
Young, A. (1994), Lessons from the East Asia NIC's: A
Contrarian View. European Economic Review. 38, 964-973.
Young, M. E. (1997), Social Indicators: A Bibliography with
Annotations. Springfield, VA: NTIS.
MATIUR RAHMAN, MBA Director and JP Morgan Chase Endowed Professor
of Finance, McNeese State University, Lake Charles, LA, USA
M. MOOSA KHAN, Associate Professor of Finance, Prairie View A&M
University, Prairie View, TX, USA