Does a concern for lowering national Gini coefficients justify redistributionist policies?
Stringham, Edward ; Gonzalez, Rodolfo ; Krishnan, Aanand 等
We address whether a concern for lowering national Gini
coefficients justifies implementing redistributionist policies. We
explore the simple point that national Gini coefficients are largely
determined by political demarcation and calculate the Gini coefficient for two hypothetical countries. First we show that even if U.S. states
had perfect equality in each state, current differences in average
income between states lead to a countrywide Gini coefficient greater
than zero. Next we estimate the Gini coefficient for Europe as a whole
by looking at income per quintile in 29 nations. Even though individual
European countries typically have low Gini coefficients, the Gini
coefficient for Europe as a whole is actually higher than that of the
United States. If lowering national Gini coefficients is the ultimate
goal, the simplest way to achieve this would be to split countries into
numerous small nations with less intrastate inequality.
Jel Codes: D31, 132, H80
Keywords: Gini, redistribution, Tiebout
INTRODUCTION
Numerous authors hold income equality as a policy ideal (Clayton
and Williams, (2000); Kawachi and Kennedy, (2002)). One of the most
common measures of equality is the Gini coefficient, which enables
comparisons of income distribution between countries. A Gini of zero
signifies perfect equality; a Gini of one signifies that all income is
in the pockets of one person. Although the Gini coefficient is a
positive concept, most people discuss it for normative reasons and
advocate judging policies based on whether they lower a country's
Gini coefficient. One of the more common calls is for redistributionist
policies in countries such as the U.S., which has a higher Gini
coefficient than almost every country in Europe. For example, Buss,
Peterson, and Nantz (1989:13-4) write, "Income is distributed less
fairly in the United States," and they conclude, "Income must
be reallocated to individuals at the lowest rungs of the
distribution."
Other authors judge policies such as immigration laws based on
whether they lead to lower Gini coefficients. Borjas (1999) favors
restrictions on immigration because open borders have the potential to
increase inequality in a nation. Note that these arguments are concerned
with national Gini coefficients rather than the Gini coefficient for the
entire globe. As Tullock (1997) argues, most first world residents do
not favor policies that decrease global inequality because it would
entail massive redistribution out of their country. Although some
authors, including Firebaugh (1999), Goesling (2001), and Milanovic
(2002), are concerned with the global Gini, many others are concerned
only with the Gini within nations (Glaeser, Scheinkman and Shleifer,
2003).
This paper addresses the scholars concerned with lowering national
Gini coefficients. Their policy prescriptions vary, but most tend to
argue against classical liberal policies, which are hands off on the
issue of income distribution. In this article we address whether a
concern for lowering national Gini coefficients justifies implementing
redistributionist policies. Whereas authors such as Tullock (1997)
question the desirability of equality altogether, we take that goal as
given. We argue, however, that even if one accepts low national Gini
coefficients as the ideal, redistributionist policies remain
unjustified; Gini coefficients can be lowered by other means. We explore
the simple point that Gini coefficients are largely determined by
political demarcation and they can be lowered by changes in the same.
In countries with many regions or states, such as the US and
Brazil, national inequality is determined by interstate inequality in
addition to intrastate inequality. Ceteris paribus, when political
boundaries are defined across large areas with significant regional
differences, the Gini will increase. If lowering national Gini
coefficients is the ultimate goal, the simplest way to achieve this
would be to split countries into numerous small nations with less
intrastate inequality. Nozick proposed a world where people are free to
leave and join political units with people similar to them. Such a
system would be approximated by Tiebout competition. If people chose to
be in jurisdictions whose members have similar incomes, Gini
coefficients would instantly decrease. Such a policy of political
decentralization does not affect global inequality, only national
inequality. One might conclude that policies should not be judged on
whether they change individual national Gini coefficients (because the
global Gini coefficient may remain unchanged). If one takes this
position, however, one must abandon the use of national Gini
coefficients to judge policy. If, on the other hand, one wishes to hold
onto national Gini coefficients as a normative goal, then one might as
well advocate radical decentralization.
WHY GINI COEFFICIENTS ARE AFFECTED BY POLITICAL DEMARCATION
Let us consider how political demarcation of boundaries affects
Gini coefficients. Notably, most European countries have lower Gini
coefficients than the U.S. One cause is that countries in Europe tend to
have more redistribution than the U.S. (Gwartney, Lawson, and Block
1996), but another possible cause is the relatively small size of
nations. Europe is comprised of numerous countries that have fewer
regional differences than the U.S. does. Depending on one's
definition of Europe, it has 29 nations for 588 million residents; the
U.S. has one country for 294 million residents. The average European
country contains only 20 million residents, which is about three times
the population of the average U.S. state. If a country's residents
are more alike and few regional differences exist, ceteris paribus their
Gini will be lower.
In contrast to smaller European countries, the U.S. has large
regional differences within its borders, and income varies significantly
between states. Even if each state had perfect equality within its
borders, as long as regional differences exist, the national Gini
coefficient cannot be zero. Let us consider a sample calculation.
Imagine a nation with 50 equally sized states, each with a Gini
coefficient of zero but with average income by state as varied as in the
current U.S. Table 1 shows the per capita income by state; the
unweighted average is $20,767 with per capita income ranging from
$15,853 in Mississippi to $28,766 in Connecticut.
We can calculate the Gini coefficient for a country with the
following formula:
G [approximately equal to] 1/[square root of 3]
[[sigma].sub.y]/[bar.y] [rho] (y, [r.sub.y])
where s is the standard deviation of the income; y is the income
point for each individual; [bar.y] is the average income for the
country; [r.sub.y] is the rank corresponding to the income (1); and r is
the correlation coefficient between the rank and income distributions of
the population.
Knowing income and population for each hypothetical state, we can
map the cumulative population and income curves. The Gini coefficient
can then be calculated by comparing the cumulative earnings to the
equality diagonal. Figure 1 shows the Lorenz curve for this hypothetical
country; its Gini coefficient is 0.08. This is much lower than the Gini
coefficient of the current U.S., which is 0.408 (Central Intelligence
Agency, 1997), but this hypothetical coefficient is still not zero.
Supposing that lowering national Gini coefficients is the ultimate
goal, one policy would be redistribution between the states. A much
simpler way to decrease the Gini coefficients, however, would be to
split this hypothetical country into fifty separate nations. Although
this situation does not exactly mirror the U.S., we want to emphasize
that Gini coefficients are the result of numerous factors, one of which
is demarcation of political boundaries. If regional differences are
important, a region's Gini coefficient may be lower than the Gini
coefficient of the larger political unit to which it belongs.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
We believe that this situation may exist in Europe. Although
individual countries in Europe typically have high equality, (2) the
Gini coefficient for the continent as a whole may be significantly less
equalitarian.
Calculating the Gini coefficient for Europe is imprecise, but we
believe that we can obtain a fairly good estimate. Even though we do not
have income data for every person in Europe, one can estimate the Gini
by looking at average income per quintile for each country. If one knew
the average income per quintile in two countries, one would have ten
points to map the cumulative population and cumulative income curves. As
one knows more points, the curves become more accurate. Because we have
average income per quintile data for 29 countries, we have 145 points
for our calculations. We have no commitment to any particular
geographical definition of Europe, but we excluded smaller counties with
missing data (3) as well as Russia (and three former Soviet Republics)
because Russia is large, mostly in Asia, and often not considered part
of Europe. (4) Table 2 shows population, average income, and percentage
share of national income per quintile for each of the countries on our
list.
We obtained the number of people in each country's quintiles by dividing the country's population by five. We then arranged the
145 data points by income and calculated the cumulative population and
income at each point. For example, if the lowest income category in
Europe was in a country with 8 million people, the lowest point has 1.6
million people; if the next lowest income category in Europe was in a
country with 22 million, the next lowest point would have 4.4 million,
and so on. By looking at total income and total population of Europe, we
can calculate the amount of cumulative income at each point if income
distribution were equal. By comparing this to actual cumulative income,
we can calculate the Gini. Figure 2 shows the Lorenz curve for Europe as
a whole; its Gini coefficient is 0.472.
The result is that Europe has a higher Gini coefficient than the
U.S. Individual countries in Europe have lower Gini coefficients and
more equality than the U.S, but that does not mean that Europe as a
whole has more equality than in the U.S. One might rightfully respond
that the final Gini coefficient for Europe depends on how one defines
Europe. If we exclude all of Eastern Europe from the sample, the Gini
coefficient of Europe is lower than the U.S. As one limits the analysis
to more homogenous groups of countries, such as those in Western Europe,
the Gini coefficient decreases. We agree, but that proves our point:
Gini coefficients are partially determined by how one defines political
units. If Europe were one large nation, its Gini coefficient would be
higher than that of the U.S.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
CONCLUSION
Calculating the Gini coefficients for two hypothetical countries
shows that the coefficients depend on demarcation of national
boundaries. A desire to lower national Gini coefficients does not
justify income redistribution. The simplest way to lower national Gini
coefficients is to redefine political jurisdictions to eliminate
regional and population differences. One might conclude that large
nations should not be split into many small states, but if one does, the
use of national Gini coefficients as a normative benchmark must be
abandoned. If, on the other hand, one wants to continue using national
Gini coefficients for normative reasons, one should embrace a policy of
radical decentralization. Rather than justifying various policies at
odds with classical liberalism, a concern for lowering Gini coefficients
justifies the policy prescription in Nozick's third section of
Anarchy, State, and Utopia (1974). A policy of political
decentralization would lower Gini coefficients instantly. (5)
REFERENCES
Buss, J., Peterson, G.P., and Nantz, K. (1989), "A Comparison
of Distributive Justice in OECD Countries" Review of Social
Economy, Vol. 47, 1-13.
Central Intelligence Agency (1997), CIA World Factbook. Washington,
DC: Central Intelligence Agency.
Central Intelligence Agency (2003), CIA World Factbook. Washington,
DC: Central Intelhgence Agency.
Clayton, Matthew and Williams, Andrew (eds.) (2002), The Ideal of
Equality. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Firebaugh, G. (1999), "Empirics of world income
inequality" American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 104, 1597-1630.
Glaeser, E., Scheinkman, J., and Shleifer, A. (2003), "The
Injustice of Inequality" Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50,
199-222.
Goesling, Brian (2001), "Changing Income Inequalities within
and between Nations: New Evidence" American Sociological Review,
Vol. 66, 745-761.
Gwartney, James, Lawson, Robert and Block, Walter (1996), Economic
Freedom of the World: 1975-1995. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.
Kawachi, Ichiro and Kennedy, Bruce (2002), The Health of Nations:
Why Inequality is Harmful to Your Health. New York: New Press.
Milanovic, Branko (1997), "A simple way to calculate Gini
coefficient and some implications ." Economics Letters, Vol. 56,
45-49.
Milanovic, Branko (2002), "True World Income Distribution,
1988 and 1993: First Calculations Based on Household Surveys Alone"
Economic Journal, Vol. 112, 51-92.
Nozick, Robert (1974), Anarchy, State, and Utopia. New York: Basic
Books.
Tullock, Gordon (1997), Economics of Income Redistribution, 2nd ed.
Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
NOTES
(1.) For example, the lowest income would have a rank of 1 and the
highest income would have a rank of 'N,' where N is the
population of the region.
(2.) The Gini coefficient in almost every European country is lower
than that of the U.S. Countries such as Italy, Norway, Finland, Sweden,
and Denmark have Gini coefficients under 0.3 (Central Intelligence
Agency, 2003).
(3.) We did not have data for Albania, Andorra, Bosnia and
Herzegovina, Gibraltar, Iceland, Liechtenstein, Malta, Monaco, San
Marino, Serbia, and Vatican City.
(4.) University of Edinburgh Professors Jamieson and Grundy
(2002:11) report, "The majority of Edinburgh residents rated all
the countries [in Eastern and Western Europe] as part of Europe except
Russia."
(5.) In fact, a Gini coefficient of 0 for every country could be
achieved if the world were split up into 6 billion countries.
EDWARD STRINGHAM, RODOLFO GONZALEZ, and AANAND KRISHNAN
San Jose State University, San Jose
Table 1
Per Capita Income in the United States by State
Alabama 18,189
Alaska 22,660
Arizona 20,275
Arkansas 16,904
California 22,711
Colorado 24,049
Connecticut 28,766
Delaware 23,305
Florida 21,557
Georgia 21,154
Hawaii 21,525
Idaho 17,841
Illinois 23,104
Indiana 20,397
Iowa 19,674
Kansas 20,506
Kentucky 18,093
Louisiana 16,912
Maine 19,533
Maryland 25,614
Massachusetts 25,952
Michigan 22,168
Minnesota 23,198
Mississippi 15,853
Missouri 19,936
Montana 17,151
Nebraska 19,613
Nevada 21,989
New Hampshire 23,844
New Jersey 27,006
New Mexico 17,261
New York 23,389
North Carolina 20,307
North Dakota 17,769
Ohio 21,003
Oklahoma 17,646
Oregon 20,940
Pennsylvania 20,880
Rhode Island 21,688
South Carolina 18,795
South Dakota 17,562
Tennessee 19,393
Texas 19,617
Utah 18,185
Vermont 20,625
Virginia 23,975
Washington 22,973
West Virginia 16,477
Wisconsin 21,271
Wyoming 19,134
Source: US Bureau of the Census, 2000 Summary File 3.
Table 2
European Population, Income, and Percentage share of Income
per Quintile
Population Average
(Mid-Year) income 1st 2nd
Austria 8,069,876 28,170 6.90 13.20
Belgium 10,199,787 26,870 8.30 13.90
Bulgaria 8,066,057 1,180 10.10 13.90
Croatia 4,319,632 4,750 8.80 13.30
Czech Republic 10,300,707 5,280 10.30 14.50
Denmark 5,283,663 34,280 9.60 14.90
Estonia 1,458,065 3,400 7.00 11.00
Finland 5,134,406 25,620 10.00 14.20
France 58,623,428 25,850 7.20 12.60
Germany 82,011,073 28,580 8.20 13.20
Greece 10,502,372 12,280 7.50 12.40
Hungary 10,244,684 4,510 10.00 14.70
Ireland 3,667,233 19,780 6.70 11.60
Italy 57,479,469 22,000 8.70 14.00
Latvia 2,470,454 2,300 7.60 12.90
Lithuania 3,651,923 2,220 7.80 12.60
Luxembourg 421,014 46,460 9.40 13.80
Netherlands 15,604,464 27,250 7.30 12.70
Norway 4,405,672 36,380 9.70 14.30
Poland 38,655,842 3,810 7.80 12.80
Portugal 9,994,921 11,260 7.30 11.60
Romania 22,562,458 1,520 8.00 13.10
Slovakia 5,383,010 3,860 11.90 15.80
Slovenia 1,917,851 9,870 9.10 13.40
Spain 39,855,442 15,380 7.50 12.60
Sweden 8,897,619 27,950 9.60 14.50
Switzerland 7,193,761 43,840 6.90 12.70
Turkey 63,047,647 3,180 5.80 10.20
United Kingdom 58,808,266 21,510 6.10 11.60
3rd 4th 5th
Austria 18.10 23.90 38.00
Belgium 18.00 22.60 37.30
Bulgaria 17.40 21.90 36.80
Croatia 17.40 22.60 38.00
Czech Republic 17.70 21.70 35.90
Denmark 18.30 22.70 34.50
Estonia 15.30 21.60 45.10
Finland 17.60 22.30 35.80
France 17.20 22.80 40.20
Germany 17.50 22.70 38.50
Greece 16.90 22.80 40.30
Hungary 18.30 22.70 34.40
Ireland 16.40 22.40 42.90
Italy 18.10 22.90 36.30
Latvia 17.10 22.10 40.30
Lithuania 16.80 22.40 40.30
Luxembourg 17.70 22.60 36.50
Netherlands 17.20 22.80 40.10
Norway 17.90 22.20 35.80
Poland 17.10 22.60 39.70
Portugal 15.90 21.80 43.40
Romania 17.20 22.30 39.50
Slovakia 18.80 22.20 31.40
Slovenia 17.30 22.50 37.70
Spain 17.00 22.60 40.30
Sweden 18.10 23.20 34.50
Switzerland 17.30 22.90 40.30
Turkey 14.80 21.60 47.70
United Kingdom 16.40 22.70 43.20
Sources: World Bank 2002World Development Indicators; U.S. Census
Bureau, 1997 Population Division, International Programs Center.