NEPAD: drawing lessons from theories of foreign direct investment.
Kebonang, Zein
Abstract
The New Partnership for Africa's Development (NEPAD) contends
that increased levels of foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows are
crucial if Africa is to achieve sustainable development and poverty
reduction. Consistent with this view, NEPAL) calls African countries to
create and adopt enabling environments within which FDI can flourish.
Although reliance on FDI as a source of growth may be a pragmatic one,
drawing on a review of the theories of FDI, this paper argues that
whilst FDI can indeed be a source of good, it can equally be a source of
economic harm. Consequently, in embracing FDI, NEPAD must have a
regulatory mechanism in place to ensure that only FDI that meets the
developmental objectives of the hosts state is welcomed.
INTRODUCTION
In its base document, the New Partnership for Africa's
Development (NEPAD) emphasizes the importance of Foreign Direct
Investment (FDI) to Africa's long-term development. To fill its
identified resource gap of 12 percent of its GDP (or US$64 billion),
NEPAD contends that African economies must grow by at least seven
percent annually. Although this growth is to be achieved through more
international aid, debt cancellation, increased domestic savings, and
improved public collection systems, FDI is deemed to be a more viable
strategy. However, despite the centrality of FDI to NEPAD, there is no
general agreement about the desirability or impact of FDI on host
economies. In exploring and evaluating NEPAD's position in respect
of this matter, this paper kicks the debate by giving a brief review of
the different theories of FDI. It looks in particular at the classical,
dependency and middle path theories of FDI and the lessons that NEPAD
can draw from them.
THEORIES OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT
The Classical Theory of FDI
Reduced to its basic form, the classical theory marks a shift from
earlier doctrinal objections held by many developing countries on the
role played by multinational corporations (MNCs) in their economies.
MNCs were viewed as inimical to the economic development of the
developing countries. Based on this assertion, MNCs were either
discriminated against or their role in the host economy severely
restricted or limited (Seid 2002:15; Markusen and Venables 1999:336;
Lall 1996; Muchlinski 1995:8; Kennedy 1992:67, OECD 1990). This
assertion also provided a justification for the expropriation of foreign
companies or assets. As illustrated in Table 1.1 below, the 1950s, 1960s
and 1970s represented a period of uncertainty for foreign investors.
Many of their assets or investments were either expropriated or
nationalized by host states.
The expropriation of MNCs by many developing countries particularly
during the early days of their independence symbolized a rejection by
these countries of being externally dependent upon
"foreigners" (Kennnedy 1992:74). As Kobrin (1984) observes:
The end of the colonial era and the rise of Third World
assertiveness and independence during the late 1960s and early
1970s influenced the preference for expropriation as opposed to
regulatory control of behavior ... There was a tendency on the part
of many countries to use foreign investment as a symbol of Western
industrialization and Western colonialism; expropriation
represented a rejection of the general context as well as of the
specific enterprise (quoted in Kennedy 1992:74).
However, the hostility directed at MNCs in the 1950s and 1970s has
largely waned. Rather than strangle the development of FDI on the basis
that it is a source of foreign domination and control, many countries
have now come to recognize that positive economic gains can be achieved
from the presence of FDI (Kobrin 2005:3; Gao 2005:158; Markusen and
Venables 1999:336; UNCTAD 1999:4; Lall 1996:44; Muchlinski 1995:9). This
change in attitude can be attributed to, inter alia, the slowdown of
growth in the world economy in the mid-1970s, change in political
leadership and the scarcity of financial capital in the wake of the debt
crisis of the early 1980s (UNCTAD 1999:29; Muchlinski 1995:10). Since
the 1990s, following the disappearance of commercial bank lending for
most countries, FDI has become the largest single source of finance for
developing countries (Kobrin 2005:3; Aitken and Harrison 1999:605;
Rodriguez-Clare 1996:852). Just about every government is involved in
trying to attract more FDI by promulgating laws and regulations that are
investor friendly. Despite, for instance, the likelihood of harmful tax
competition resulting from tax concessions given to MNCs, the 1991
UNCTAD report reveals that between 1977 and 1987 both developed and
developing countries changed their respective tax subsidy policies in an
attempt to entice MNCs (UNCTAD 1991; OECD 1998; see, also, Kebonang
2001). These changes in tax policy, although wasteful (as they simply
confer a windfall on MNCs), demonstrate clearly the importance countries
now attach to FDI.
The Classical Theory in Context
In broad terms, classical theorists advance the claim that FDI and
multinational corporations (MNCs) contribute to the economic development
of host countries through a number of channels. These include the
transfer of capital, advanced technological equipment and skills (Gao
2005:158; Mody 2004:195; Asheghian 2004; Girma, Kneller and Pisu 2003;
Kohpaiboon 2003:55; Hermes and Lensink 2003; Seid 2002:30; Keller 2001;
Shihata 1991:487; Balasubramanyam, Salisu and Sapsford 1996:95; Hymer
1970:443), the improvement in the balance of payments, the expansion of
the tax base and foreign exchange earnings, the creation of employment,
infrastructural development and the integration of the host economy into
international markets (Li and Liu 2005:404; Janeba 2004:367; Amiti and
Wakelin 2003:102; Sornarajah 1994:39; Muchlinksi 1995: 91). These claims
about FDI have been amplified by the phenomenal economic growth of the
newly industrialized countries, Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore and South
Korea, especially in the 1980s and early 1990s (Muchlinski 1995:99;
Ulmer 1980:458) and more recently by China's impressive economic
growth (Cheung and Lin 2004:30; UCTAD 2003:40; World Bank 2003:151).
With its emphases on the importance of FDI and limited state role,
the classical doctrine has been propagated in recent years by
international institutions and organizations like the United Nations
(UN), the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the
International Labor Organization (ILO). The United Nations for instance,
endorsed FDI at its 2002 Monterrey Conference held in Mexico, as an
important and vital complement to national and international development
efforts.
FDI and the Spillover Channels
According to proponents of the classical theory, the benefits from
FDI are derived through positive spillovers (see, for instance, Cheung
and Lin 2004; Girma, Kneller and Pisu 2003; Gorg and Strobl 2002;
Lensink and Morrissey 2001; Markusen and Venables 1999; Aiten, Hanson
and Harrison 1997). In this matrix, MNCs are an important source of
these spillovers. They provide information relating to new technologies,
new markets, new customers and management techniques from which domestic
firms benefit (Greenaway, Sousa and Wakelin 2001; Sousa, Greenaway and
Wakelin 2000). This information spillover from MNCs occurs through
imitation, competition, linkages and/or training (Cheung and Lin 2004;
Hermes; Gorg and Greenaway 2001; Lensink and Morrissey 2001; Gorg and
Strobl 2002; Markusen and Venables 1999). By imitating the more advanced
technologies and managerial skills of MNCs, and through the movement of
highly skilled staff from MNCs to domestic firms, local firms are forced
to catch up and become more productive (Gorg and Strobl 2002; Lensink
and Morrissey 2001:3; Aitken and Harrison 1999:605).
In addition, the entry of MNCs in local markets increases the level
of competition in the domestic market and encourages domestic firms to
become more efficient (Lensink and Morrissey 2001:3). Exposure to best
practices and to greater competition leads to improvements in
productivity (Girma, Kneller and Pisu 2003:3). In instances where the
MNC is export-oriented, domestic firms may likewise be encouraged to be
export oriented (Greenaway, Sousa and Wakelin 2001; Aiten, Hanson and
Harrison 1997:128). Furthermore, through linkages with indigenous
suppliers MNCs sustain domestic firms by creating demand for
domestically produced intermediate goods (Gorg and Strobl 2002; Lensink
and Morrissey 2001:3).
Positive spillovers from MNCs also arise from the training provided
to locals. These benefits are in the form of improved human resource
development, better managerial abilities and improved industrial
discipline and administrative organization (Lensink and Morrissey
2001:3). The introduction of new technology may require that training be
given to employees. For employers, be they MNCs or domestic firms,
self-interest simply dictates that they provide such training (Lensink
and Morrissey 2001:4).
FDI and the Uncertainty of Spillovers
Although the classical theory seems to paint an overwhelmingly
positive picture about the benefits that can be derived from FDI,
empirical evidence on the subject is mixed. Some studies have found a
positive spillover effect, some no effect and others a negative
spillover effect (see, for instance, Gorg and Strobl 2002; Gorg and
Greenaway 2001; Markusen and Venables 1999; Aitken and Harrison 1999;
Aiten, Hanson and Harrison 1997; Killick 1973). What in fact emerges
from a reading of the literature is that for every argument in favor or
against FDI, there is also a counter argument. For instance, whilst
Todaro (1989:475) finds that FDI helps in accumulating foreign exchange
and hence contributes to the country's balance of payment, Sharan
(1978) observed that between the period 1964-1971, FDI had a negative
impact on India's balance of payment.
A study carried out by the Research and Information System (RIS)
for the non-aligned and other developing countries based in India has
found the evidence of the effect of FDI on domestic investments to be
mixed (OECD 2002: 4). Taking a sample of 98 Asian countries covering
1980-98, the study found that in India, Fiji, Papua New Guinea,
Philippines and Singapore, FDI crowded out domestic investment. But in
Pakistan, China, Indonesia, Malaysia and Turkey FDI flows appeared not
to have any effect on domestic investment. In Bangladesh, Korea, Nepal,
Sri Lanka and Thailand, FDI was noted to have a positive effect by
bringing in domestic investment (OECD 2002:4).
Despite the general contribution to employment, MNCs, particularly
when they are capital rather than labor intensive, can aggravate the
problem of unemployment. Such MNCs increase demand for skilled labor and
drive up wage rates. In the process they crowd out domestic firms which
cannot afford to compete for such skilled labor (Lipsey and Sjoholm
2004:422; Gorg and Greenaway 2001). Feenstra and Hanson (1997:391) note,
for instance, that between 1975 and 1988, the entry of FDI in Mexico led
to a wage increase and demand for skilled labor and a decline in the
employment of unskilled labor. Similarly, a study by Ohiorhenuan
(1983:164) found that in Nigeria, not only did MNCs import inappropriate
technology but they also exacerbated the problem of unemployment because
unlike the relatively labor intensive local firms, they were more
technology driven and therefore required less labor.
A number of scholars, among them Li and Liu 2005; Le 2004;
Nunnenkamp 2004; Alfaro 2003; Seid 2002; Borensztein, De Gregorio and
Lee 1998; Balasubramanyam, Salisu and Sapsford 1996; Khan and Reinhart
1990 and Hirschman 1958, in acknowledging the importance of FDI and its
welfare contribution to the host economy, share the view that the
benefits derived from FDI depend on the existence of a number of
factors. These factors range from the economic policies pursued by the
host state, the sectors in which investment is made, the political risks
present, availability of effective institutions and the presence of
developed financial markets, to the stock of human capital availability.
These factors constitute what is called the "absorptive
capacity" of a host country.
Borensztein, De Gregorio and Lee (1998:117) argue, for instance,
that whilst FDI contributes to economic growth in larger measure than
domestic investment, the absence of or low levels of human capital may
undermine that contribution. They maintain that FDI contribution to
economic growth is greatly enhanced by its interaction with the level of
human capital in the host country. This is because the application of
advanced technology requires the presence of a sufficient level of human
capital, without which the absorptive capability of the host country is
greatly reduced. They conclude that FDI enhances growth only in
countries with a sufficiently qualified labor force (see, also, Xu 2000;
Li and Liu 2005).
Meanwhile, Le (2004:589) finds that private investment leads to
economic growth and prosperity provided that there are stable
socio-political institutions, certainty in macroeconomic policies and
flexibility in the financial market. He identifies three types of
political risks that may adversely impact private investment, namely
socio-political instability, regime change instability and policy
uncertainty. He argues that in order to provide a sound environment to
attract and maintain a stable flow of private investment in the economy,
governments should be able to design and implement consistent policies
that deal with these types of political risks.
The view that the growth impact of FDI depends on the
characteristics of the country in which FDI takes place is now
widespread. According to Nunnenkamp (2004:673), benefits derived from
FDI depend on whether the host country environment is conducive to the
overall investment, economic spillovers and income growth. Unless there
are developed local markets and institutions, investment-friendly
policies and administrative framework, as well as complementary factors
of production, there will be modest gains derived from FDI (Nunnenkamp
2004:673; see, also, Khan and Reinhart 1990:25).
In parity, Balasubramanyam, Salisu and Sapsford (1996:95) argue
that the usefulness of FDI in promoting economic growth depends on the
economic policies being pursued by the host country. Balasubramanyam et
al. (1996) take the view that openness to trade is central in harnessing
the positive growth effect of FDI. They identify two types of trade
policies that have a bearing on the effectiveness of FDI in promoting
economic growth. These are the Import Substitution (IS) and the Export
Promotion (EP) policies. According to Balasubramanayam et al, an IS
policy is unlikely to promote FDI or provide an economic climate
conducive to the efficient operations of foreign firms, as such policies
restrict competition from both domestic and foreign sources. However, EP
policies, with their emphasis on the neutrality of policy, the free play
of market forces and competition, provide an ideal climate for the
exploitation of the potential of FDI to promote growth (Balasubramanayam
et al 1996:96; see, also, Gorg and Greeanway 2001; Miller and Upadhyay
2000).
Hermes and Lensink (2003:142) on the other hand suggest that the
impact of FDI on the economic growth of the host state depends on the
existence of a viable financial system. They see a developed financial
system as a prerequisite for FDI to have positive spillovers. According
to them, a developed financial system not only enhances the efficient
allocation of resources but also improves the absorptive capacity of the
host country with respect to FDI inflows (Hermes and Lensink 2003:143;
see, also, Alfaro, Chanda, Ozcan and Sayek 2004).
Equally, the sector in which investment is made influences the
types of gains obtained from FDI. The oft-cited benefits of FDI such as
technology and managerial skill transfer are usually more pronounced in
the manufacturing rather than in primary sectors of the economy such as
agriculture and mining (Alfaro 2003). The absence of linkages in the
primary sectors with the rest of the economy limits the contribution
that FDI can make to economic growth. According to Hirschman (1958:110;
see, also Alfaro 2003), 'the grudge against what has become known
as the 'enclave' type of development is due to this ability of
primary products from mines, wells, and plantations to slip out of a
country without leaving much of a trace in the rest of the
economy'.
Finally, the type of FDI made also determines what benefits are
derived from it. Maswood (2000: 217) makes a distinction between two
types of FDI: speculative and productive foreign investment. He asserts
that speculative FDI, which is often accompanied by short-term capital
flows, can undermine national monetary and economic objectives and be
harmful to the economy as a whole. Productive FDI is different in that
it normally represents a long-term commitment to the host economy
(Maswood 2000: 217; see also Ulmer 1980: 462). Between these two types
of FDI, speculative investment needs to be subjected to more regulation
if potential harm to the economy is to be avoided. Likewise, Seid (2002:
125-27) argues that FDI, being by its very nature profit-driven, may pay
a scant regard to labor, consumer or environment concerns in the host
country. For this reason, he contends that FDI must be regulated if
optimum results are to be obtained from it. According to Seid (2002:
116), unrestricted FDI entry into the host market is not desirable as it
restricts the host country's ability to determine the level and
type of FDI suitable for it.
The Dependency Theory
Despite the centrality of FDI to NEPAD, enthusiasm about FDI is not
widespread. Some commentators such as Bond (2002) and Tandon (2002)
among others have either impliedly or expressly questioned the need for
FDI. Bond (2001; 2002) sees for instance, multinational corporations as
agents of 'global apartheid' responsible for Africa's
worsening economic state, whilst Tandon (2002) argues that what Africa
needs is 'self-reliance and not FDI reliance'.
The above views, which implicitly suggest that FDI is exploitative,
find sympathy in the depedency theory of FDI. Drawing from the
experience of Latin American countries, proponents of this theory argue
that relations of free trade and foreign investment with the
industrialized countries are the main causes of underdevelopment and
exploitation of developing economies (Wilhelms and Witter 1998:8; Dos
Santos 1970). This theory focuses largely on the relationship between
the center and periphery. Well-developed and industrialized countries
are deemed to constitute the center and the least developed countries
the periphery. In this regard, FDI is seen as a conduit through which
the center exploits the periphery and perpetuates the latter's
state of underdevelopment and dependence.
Instead of promoting economic development, the argument goes,
foreign investment strangulates such development and perpetuates the
domination of the weaker states by keeping them in a position of
permanent and constant dependence on the economies of the developed
states (Sornarajah 1994:43). MNCs are accused of being "imperialist
predators' that exploit developing countries and exacerbate their
underdevelopment (Alfaro 2003). These views are largely informed by the
fact that multinationals
have often been involved in the exploitation of natural resources with no corresponding benefits for host economies (UNCTAD 1999). The
depedency theory is therefore very much a reaction against this
"extractive nature" of FDI.
Under the dependency theory, FDI is considered to promote
dependence and underdevelopment through its promotion of specialization
in production and exports of primary products; increased reliance by
least developed countries (LDCs) on foreign products and capital
intensive technology; diffusion of western values and elite consumption;
acute growth inequality in income distribution and rising unemployment
and destruction of indigenous production capacity (Gorg and Strobl 2002;
Girma and Wakelin 2000; Markusen and Venable 1999; Aitken and Harrison
1999; Biersteker 1987; Lall 1975). The crowding-out or displacement of
indigenous production necessarily eliminates the development of the
national entrepreneurial class and hence "excludes the possibility
of self-sustained national development" (Biersteker 1978:7). This
dependency is also worsened by the remittance or repatriation of profit,
royalties, interest payments, declining reinvestment and lack of local
economic spin-off, which taken together lead to a
'decapitalization' of the host economy (Dos Santos 1970: 233;
Rojas 2002; Biersteker 1978).
These surplus transfers reduce funds available for domestic
investment in the less developed countries (Rojas 2002). As a result
developing countries are compelled to seek new forms of foreign
financing--be it in the form of aid or loans to finance their
development or cover existing deficits, in the process they create a
perpetual state of dependency (Dos Santos 1970: 233). Accordingly to
address this problem, the dependency theorists contend that the solution
to underdevelopment requires closing developing countries to
international investment and trade (Wilhelm and Witter 1998: 8). Because
of the perceived exploitative nature of FDI, the dependency and
underdevelopment it engenders, proponents of the dependency theory are
in unison in calling for the adoption of state policies that are
deliberately discriminative of FDI in order to foster the development of
local industries and promote self-reliance (see, Tandon 2002; Wilhelms
and Witter 1998: 8; Blumenfeld 1991: 63). Only by this means, so they
contend, can developing countries or governments acquire the autonomy
and freedom to achieve structural changes and economic diversification
free from constraints on their development (Blumenfeld 1991: 63).
The Decline of the Dependency Theory
Despite its near reverence especially in the 1960s and 70s, the
theoretical dominance of the dependency theory over state policies has
become limited. More countries are now competing for FDI to stimulate
economic growth and development. Governments which were once hostile to
foreign investors are now actively seeking and competing for them
(Girma, Kneller and Pisu 2003; Blomstrom and Kokko 2003). Laws and
regulations that are investor friendly have proliferated. Between 1991
and 2001, for instance, a total of 1,393 regulatory changes were
introduced in national FDI regimes, of which 1,315 (or 95 percent) were
in the direction of creating a more favorable environment for FDI (World
Bank 2003:122). Countries, such as Ghana, that once experimented with
the dependency theory have achieved neither prosperity or greater
economic independence. Rather they have experienced much poverty, misery
and greater dependence on international aid and charity (Ahiakpor
1985:546).
The Intervention/Integration/Middle Path Theory
The intervention or integrative school attempts to analyze FDI from
the perspective of the host country as well as that of the investor. It
incorporates arguments from both the classical and dependency theorists.
The theory posits that foreign investment must be protected but only to
the extent of the benefits it brings the host state and the extent to
which foreign investors have behaved as good corporate citizens in
promoting the economic and social objectives of the host country
(Sornarajah 1994:49). The theory calls for a mixture of intervention
(regulation) and openness in dealing with foreign investment and
cautions against too much openness and too much regulation or
intervention (Seid 2002: 23). The theory recognizes that there are
instances where the market is better placed to act and other instances
where government intervention is necessary. What is needed therefore is
a balancing act between those activities that can best be handled by the
market and those that can be done by the government.
In many ways, the middle path/integration theory represents a
convergence between Adam Smith's case in favor of a laissez-faire
approach and Keynes' argument in favor of government intervention
in the market. Whilst Adam Smith in his Wealth of the Nations believed
that except for intervention in providing public works and institutions,
the role of the state in the market must be minimized (Hollander
1972:256; Ginzberg 1934:22; Viner 1928:138), Keynes, who was greatly
influenced by the effects of the US Great Depression of the 1930s,
strongly believed that government participation in the market was
crucial to stimulate the economy.
The notion that governments and markets are complements and not
substitutes stands in stark contrast to earlier views which held the
position that the existence of one required the diminution of the other.
In the 1950s and 1960s, the state in many developing countries was the
primary player in economic matters (Rodrik 1997:412). Following the debt
crisis of the 1980s, major reforms were introduced which sought to limit
and confine the role of government to the provision of public goods such
as securing property rights, maintaining macroeconomic stability and
providing education and the necessary infrastructure (Rodrik 1997:412;
Whiteley 1986:175). This idea of a limited government role in the
market, often dubbed the "Washington Consensus", was and has
been actively promoted by the World Bank and IMF.
The term 'Washington Consensus', coined originally in
1990 by John Williamson to describe a set of market reforms that Latin
American economies could adopt to attract private capital following the
debt crisis of the 1980s, called for reforms in at least ten key areas
(Clift 2003:9; Williamson 2000:251). These areas were fiscal discipline,
tax reform, interest rate liberalization, a competitive exchange rate,
trade liberalization, a reduction of public expenditure, liberalization
of inflows of foreign direct investment, privatization, deregulation and
secure property rights (Maxwell 2005; Williamson 2000:252-53; Clift
2003:9). In essence, these reforms require the state, beyond its
provision of the necessary market institutions, to play a minimal role
in the market. Although initially targeted at Latin American countries,
these reforms have become a common prescription that is advanced by the
World Bank/IMF for developing countries.
Ironically, even as it acknowledged the complementary roles between
the state and markets in promoting economic growth, the World Bank
maintained in its 1991 Development Report that state interventions even
when market-friendly should be reluctantly pursued. Markets were to be
allowed to work unless it was demonstrably better for government to step
in (World Bank 1991:5). Although important, the state's role in
economic development in this 'market-friendly' approach is to
be limited to providing social, legal and economic infrastructure and to
creating a suitable climate for private enterprise (Singh 1994:1812).
This "market-friendly" approach, which requires a limited
government role has been found wanting following the East Asian economic
success or miracle.
In its 1993 Report, the World Bank acknowledged that the economic
success of East Asian countries, particularly Hong Kong, South Korea,
Singapore and Taiwan, came not simply because these countries had the
basics right (stable macroeconomic policy, high savings rates and
investment rates, physical and human capital, economies that were export
oriented, and the use of incentives and application of selective import
barriers) but because in most of these economies the government
intervened systematically and through many channels to foster
development and in some cases to develop specific industries (World Bank
1993; Rodrik 1997:413; Singh 1994:1811; Harris and Schmitt 2001:294;
Rueschemeyer and Putterman 1992: 253; Selden 1992: 171).
The East Asian miracle has led Haggard and Kaufman (1992:222) to
argue that what the Asian success demonstrates is that market
institutions and state power are not inversely related: "the
expansion of the first does not require a diminution of the
second". In more recent studies, Liew (2005: 332) shows that
China's rapid economic growth has resulted not from less state
control or rapid or "big-bang" liberalization approaches often
prescribed by the IMF/World Bank but from intense state intervention and
ownership of enterprises.
It would appear that the current intellectual debate about markets
and governments no longer revolves around whether the existence and
success of one requires the exclusion of the other. There seems to be a
meeting of the minds, with advocates from both sides of the debate
recognizing that the two complement each other. In discussing the role
of the state vis-a-vis the market, Dixit (1996) argues:
One must accept that markets and government are both imperfect
systems; that both are unavoidable features of reality; that the
operation of each is powerfully influenced by the existence of the
other; and that both are processes unfolding in real time, whose
evolution is dependent on history and buffeted by surprise (quoted
in Rodrik 1997:414).
What is now clear from the debates is that although the market
accomplishes a number of things critical for economic efficiency, such
as co-ordinating the activities of a multitude of economic units, there
are certain shortcomings that cannot be addressed by the market. As
Reuschemeyer and Putterman (1992: 258) and Bruton (1992:102) argue,
'markets and competitive markets in particular, are not the natural
outgrowth of civil societies undisturbed by state intervention ... in
fact, efficient markets require strong state action'. The need for
a complementary role between the market and state has been amply
demonstrated in recent years by the failure of Russia's market
reforms. The transition of Russia's economy from a command to a
free market economy failed as a result of the general neglect of the
role of the state and the consequent lack of attention to the building
of institutions necessary for supporting the market-oriented reforms
which were being undertaken at the time (Stiglitz 1999: 579; Herrera
1999).
Markets failures notwithstanding, government interventions may also
be inefficient. As Whiteley (1986:174) remarks, a state can intervene in
the economy to make things worse; it can protect 'sunset'
industries rather than 'sunrise' industries; it can give
monopolistic privileges to support groups and it can invest in the wrong
areas, where state capacity is weak, state intervention can do more harm
than good (World Bank 1997). A study by Papanek (1992:156) found, for
instance, that excessive state intervention in the economies of India,
Pakistan, Sri Lanka and Bangladesh deterred economic growth and
development in these countries.
NEPAD and the Lessons from the FDI Theories
What are the lessons that NEPAD can draw from the above theories of
FDI? First, the classical theory which informs NEPAD's position on
FDI requires that there must be minimal government intervention. But as
the dependency theory shows, unless properly regulated, FDI can worsen
the problem of under development, through the crowding out of domestic
firms and repatriation of profits. As Ulmer (1980:462) points out:
It would be ridiculously naive to suppose that multinationals are
at all times and in all places an unqualified force for the good.
They are simply business institutions, which is to say cold and
generally implacable seekers of profit. In any particular case,
strictly business operations may or may not be fully compatible
with the public welfare.
The challenge for NEPAD is therefore to ensure the proper
regulation of FDI. This requires that there must be no unlimited right
of entry for FDI. Rather, investors must be screened so that only
genuine ones are welcomed. This will ensure that the kind of investment
that is allowed in, is one that can complement the developmental
objectives of host states.
Apart from the need to regulate FDI, what is also clear is that FDI
can contribute to economic growth through capital flows, technology
transfer, and employment creation. These benefits are not, however,
automatic. As Kokko (2002) points out, 'there is strong evidence
pointing to the potential for significant spillover benefits from FDI,
but also ample evidence indicating that spillovers do not occur
automatically' (quoted in Nunnenkamp 2004: 668). The benefits
derived from FDI depend on the sector in which investment is made and on
the level of economic development of the host country. Investment in the
primary sector has fewer positive spillovers than investment in the
manufacturing sector. For NEPAD, this calls for promoting investment
that will enahance the growth of the secondary industries. In this way,
real employment, technological and infrastructural benefits can be
experienced.
Much of the foreign investment coming to Africa is primarly geared
towards Africa's primary sector. This kind of investment has led
not only to what is called the 'resource curse' but has also
promoted poor leadership and entrenched neo-patrimonial practices.
Additionally, as the dependency theory shows, reliance on the primary
sector has rendered states dependent on such a sector vunerable to
fluctuating demands and unfavorable trade terms. As a result, the
development of countries that rely on the production of primary
commodities is inextricably influenced by the specific demands of
countries that import these primary products. Countries that only rely
on a limited number of commodities for their economic existence tend not
to diversify. A familiar pattern of commodity-dependence is
institutionalized.
As a means of achieving economic independence, the depedency theory
calls for the promotion and protection of domestic industries against
FDI. This import substitution strategy has been discredited and no
longer offers a viable alternative to development. Although a case can
be made for protecting infant industries, this must not be at the
expense of shutting out foreign investors. In fact, countries that have
experimented with the import substitution strategy have achieved neither
economic prosperity nor development. Empirical evidence attests to the
fact that countries that are open to foreign investment grow faster than
those closed to it. Being open to FDI does not mean that it should not
be regulated. For NEPAD, this calls for a rethink of its classical or
neo-liberal stance. Active state participation will be necessary to
guard against harmful corporate practices and to ensure that FDI
contributes to identified state development objectives.
Between the positions advanced by the classical and dependency
theories, the middle path theory takes an accommodating position. It
recognizes that states and markets cannot do without each other. They
are complements, "each providing a check on and facilitating the
functioning of the other" (Stiglitz 1999:579). How and where the
state or market should intervene is a matter to be assessed on a case by
case basis.
CONCLUSION
As we have seen, the empirical evidence on the impact of FDI is
mixed. However, the existence of conflicting empirical evidence on the
impact of FDI does not imply that there are no benefits to be derived
from FDI. What the evidence points to is in fact that the benefits
derived from FDI are dependent on the existence or absence of certain
factors. These include skilled labor, developed financial markets and
institutions, conducive government policies and the level of economic
development. Nonetheless, as much as FDI can be a source of good, it can
also be a source of economic harm. FDI may contribute to
underdevelopment if the profits from FDI are not reinvested in the host
country. Some types of FDI may add to environmental degradation. FDI may
also contribute to poor leadership. The challenge for NEPAD is to
attract the kind of investment that will contribute positively to the
host country's economic development. This means that NEPAD must
develop a monitoring mechanism by which it can screen and monitor all
FDI coming to Africa to ensure that only genuine investors are assisted
and welcomed. There should be no unrestricted entry of FDI. Unless FD!
is aligned with the development objectives of host countries, there will
be no added value in having FDI. However, when all things are
considered, when regard is had to Africa's level of
underdevelopment, the reliance by NEPAD on FDI is a pragmatic one.
REFERENCES
Ahiakpor, J.C.W. (1985), "The Success and Failure of
Dependency Theory: The Experience of Ghana", International
Organizations, Vol. 39 (3), 535-552.
Aitken, B. J. and Harrison, A. E. (1999), "Do Domestic Firms
Benefit from Direct Foreign Investment? Evidence from Venezuela",
The American Economic Review, Vol. 89 (3), 605-618.
Aitken, B. J; Hanson, G.H. and Harrison, A. E. (1997),
"Spillovers, Foreign Investment and Export Behavior", Journal
of International Economics, Vol. 43,103-132.
Alfaro, L; Chanda, A; Kalemli-Ozcan, S. and Sayek, S. (2004),
"FDI and Economic Growth: The Role of Local Financial
Markets", Journal of International Economics, Vol. 64, 89-112.
Alfaro, L. (2003), "Foreign Direct Investment and Growth: Does
the Sector Matter? Harvard Business School, USA.
Amiti, M. and Wakelin, K. (2003), "Investment Liberalization
and International Trade", Journal of International Economics, Vol.
61, 101-126.
Asheghian, P. (2004), "Determinants of Economic Growth in the
United States: The Role of Foreign Direct Investment", The
International Trade Journal, Vol. XVIII (1), 6483.
Balasubramanyam, V. N; Salisu, M. and Sapsford, D. (1996),
"Foreign Direct Investment and Growth in EP and IS Countries",
The Economic Journal, Vol. 106 (434), 92-105.
Biersteker, T. J. (1978), Distortion or Development: Contending
Perspectives of the Multinational Corporation, MIT Press, Cambridge,
Massachusetts.
Biersteker, T. J. (1987), Multinationals, The State and Control of
the Nigerian Economy, Princeton University Press, New Jersey.
Blumenfeld, J. (1991), Economic Interdependence in Southern Africa:
From Conflict to Cooperation? Pinter Publishers, London.
Borensztein. E; De Gregorio, J. and Lee, J-W (1998), "How Does
Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?" Journal of
International Economics, Vol. 45, 115-135.
Bruton, H. J. (1992), "International Aspects of the Role of
Government in Economic Development" in L. Putterman and D.
Rueschemeyer (eds), State and Market in Development: Synergy or Rivalry?
Lynne Rienner Publishers, Colorado, USA.
Cheung, Kui-yin and Lin, P. (2003), "Spillover Effect of FDI
on Innovation in China: Evidence from the Provincial Data", China
Economic Review, Vol. 15, 25-44.
Clift, J. (2003), "Beyond the Washington Consensus",
Finance and Development, 9.
Dimowo, F.A. and Edo, S. (2002), "Empirical Analysis of The
Impact of Direct Foreign Investment on the Economy of Nigeria",
Indian Journal of Economics, Vol. LXXXII, (327), 443-457.
Dos Santos, T. (1970), "The Structure of Dependency", The
American Economic Review, Vol. 60 (2), 231-236.
Evans, P. (1979), Dependent Development: The Alliance of
Multinational, State and Local Capital in Brazil, Princeton University
Press, New Jersey, USA.
Evers, B. (2003), "Linking Trade and Poverty: Reinventing the
Trade Policy Review Mechanism", Paper Prepared for the Research
Project on "Linking the WTO to the Poverty Reduction Agenda,
Globalisation and Poverty Research Programme, University of Manchester,
UK.
Gao, T. (2005), "Foreign Direct Investment and Growth under
Economic Integration", Journal of International Economics, Vol. 67,
157-174.
Gastanaga, V. M; Nugent, J.B. and Pashamova, B. (1998), "Host
Country Reforms and FDI Inflows: How Much Difference do they Make?"
World Development Journal, Vol. 26 (7), 1299-1314.
Girma, S; Kneller; R. and Pisu, M. (2003), "Do Exporters Have
Anything to Learn from Foreign Multinationals?" Leverhulme Center
Research Paper 2003/22, The University of Nottingham.
Girma, S. and Wakelin, K. (2000). "Are There Regional
Spillovers from FDI in the UK?" Leverhulme Center Research Paper
2000/ 16, The University of Nottingham.
Gorg, H. and Greenaway, D. (2001), "Foreign Direct Investment
and Intra-Industry Spillovers: A Review of the Literature",
Leverhulme Center Research Paper 2001/37, The University of Nottingham.
Gorg, H. and Strobl E. (2002), "Multinational Companies and
Indigenous Development: An Empirical Analysis", European Economic
Review, Vol. 46, 1305-1322.
Greenaway, D; Sousa N; and Wakelin, K. (2001), "Do Domestic
Firms Learn to Export from Multinationals?" Leverhulme Center
Research Paper 2001 / 11, The University of Nottingham.
Hermes, N. Lensink, R. and Murinde, V. (2002), "Flight Capital
and its Reversal for Development Financing", World Institute for
Development Economics Research Discussion Paper No. 2002. 99, United
Nations University.
Hermes, N. and Lensink, R. (2003), "Foreign Direct Investment,
Financial Development and Economic Growth", Journal of Development
Studies, Vol. 40 (1), 142-163.
Herrera, Y. (1999), "Lessons from Russia's Experience
with Market-Oriented Reform", PONARS Policy Memo 85, Harvard
University, USA.
Hirshman, A.O. (1958), A Strategy of Economic Development, Yale
University Press, USA. Hollander, S. (1973), The Economics of Adam
Smith, University of Toronto Press, Canada.
Hymer, S. (1970), "The Efficiency (Contradictions) of
Multinational Corporations", The American Economic Review, Vol. 60
(2), 441-448.
IMF (1997), Good Governance: The IMF's Role, IMF, Washington
DC, USA.
Janeba, E. (2004), "Global Corporations and Local Politics:
Income Redistribution vs. FDI Subsidies", Journal of Development
Economics, Vol. 74, 367-391.
Kebonang, Z. (2001), Economic Cross Road: Tax Incentives or Tax
Competition: The Case of Botswana, Master's Thesis, Harvard
University, USA.
Kennedy, C. R. (1992), "Relations Between Transnational
Corporations and Governments of Host Countries: A Look to the
Future", Transnational Corporations, Vol. 1 (1), 67-91.
Khan, M. S. and Reinhart, C.M. (1990), "Private Investment and
Economic Growth in Developing Countries", World Development
Journal, Vol. 18 (1), 19-27.
Killick, T. (1972), "The Benefits of Foreign Direct Investment
and its Alternatives: An Empirical Exploration", Journal of
Development Studies, Vol. 9, 301-316.
Kobrin, J. S. (2005), "The Determinants of Liberalization of
FDI polity in Developing Countries: A Cross-Sectional Analysis,
1992-2001", Transnational Corporations, Vol. 14(1)-1-38.
Kohpaiboon, A. (2003), "Foreign Trade Regimes and the
FDI-Growth Nexus: A Case Study of Thailand", Journal of Development
Studies, Vol. 40 (2), 55-69.
Lall, S (1996), "Transnational Corporations and Economic
Development" in UNCTAD, Transnational Corporations and World
Development, International Thomson Business Press Publishers.
Lensink, R. and Morrissey, O. (2001), "Foreign Direct
Investment: Flows, Volatility and Growth", paper presented at the
Development Economics Study Group Conference, University of Nottingham,
UK, 5-7 April.
Li, X and Liu, X (2005), "Foreign Direct Investment and
Economic Growth: An Increasingly Endogenous Relationship", World
Development, Vol. 33 (3), 393-407.
Liew, L.H. (2005), "China's Engagement with
Neo-Liberalism: Path Dependency, Geography and Party
Self-Reinvention", Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 41 (2),
331-352.
MacMillan, F. (2003), "Multinational Enterprises, the World
Trade Organization and the Protection of the Environment", in F.
MacMillan (ed), International Corporate Law Annual, Vol. 2, Hart
Publishing, Oregon, USA.
Markusen, J. R. (1995), "The Boundaries of Multinational
Enterprises and the Theory of International Trade", Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9 (2), 169-189.
Markusen, J.R. and Venables, A. J. (1999), "Foreign Direct
Investment As a Catalyst for Industrial Development", European
Economic Review, Vol. 43, 335-356.
Maswood, J. (2000), International Political Economy and
Globalization, World Scientific Publishers, Singapore.
Maxwell, S. (2005), "The Washington Consensus is dead! Long
Live the Meta-Narrative! Overseas Development Institute, Working Paper
243, London, UK.
Miller, S.M. and Upadhyay, M. P. (2000), "The Effects of
Openness, Trade Orientation, and Human Capital on Total Factor
Productivity", Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 63, 399-423.
Mody, A. (2004), "Is FDI Integrating the World Economy",
World Economy, Vol. 27 (8), 1195-1222.
Muchlinski, P. T. (1995), Multinational Enterprises and the Law,
Blackwell Publishers, London.
Nunnenkamp, P. (2004), "To What Extent Can Foreign Direct
Investment Help Achieve International Development Goals?", World
Economy, Vol. 27 (5), 657-677.
OECD (2002), Global Forum on International Investment: Attracting
Foreign Direct Investment for Development, Shanghai, China, 5-6
December.
OECD (1995), Taxation and Foreign Direct Investment: The Experience
of Economies in Transition, Paris, France.
OECD (1990), Promoting Private Enterprise in Developing Countries,
Paris, France.
Ohiorhenuam, J.E. (1983), "Multinational Corporations in the
Nigerian Political Economy", The Nigerian Journal of Economics and
Studies, Vol. 25 (2), 156-168.
Palma, G. (1978), "Dependency: A Formal Theory of
Underdevelopment or a Methodology for the Analysis of Concrete
Situations of Underdevelopment?" World Development, Vol. 6,
881-924.
Papanek, G. F. (1972), "The Effect of Government Intervention
on Growth and Equity: Lessons from Southern Asia", in L. Putterman
and D. Rueschemeyer (eds), State and Market in Development: Synergy or
Rivalry? Lynne Rienner Publishers, Colorado, USA.
Ram, R. (2004), "Recipient Country's 'Policies'
and the Effect of Foreign Aid on Economic Growth in Developing
Countries: Additional Evidence", Journal of International
Development, Vol. 16, 201-211.
Rodriguez-Clare, A. (1996), "Multinationals, Linkages and
Economic Development", The American Economic Review, Vol. 86 (4),
852-873.
Rodrik, D. (1997), "The 'Paradoxes' of the
Successful State", European Economic Review, Vol. 41, 411-442.
Rojas, R. (2001), "International Capital: A Threat to Human
Dignity and Life on Planet Earth" available at
http://www.rrojasdatabank.org/Globalss.doc.
Rueschemeyer, D. and Putterman, L. (1992), "Synergy or
Rivalry", in L. Putterman and D. Rueschemeyer (eds), State and
Market in Development: Synergy or Rivalry? Lynne Rienner Publishers,
Colorado, USA.
Sachs, J.D. (2005), The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities of
Our Time, The Penguin Press, New York, USA.
Seid, S. (2002), Global Regulation of Foreign Direct Investment,
Ashgate Publishers, England.
Selden, M. (1992), "State, Cooperative and Market: Reflections
of Chinese Developmental Trajectories", in L. Putterman and D.
Rueschemeyer (eds), State and ????
Shah, A. (ed) (1995), Fiscal Incentive for Investment and
Innovation, Oxford University Press, London.
Singh, A. (1994), "Openness and the Market Friendly Approach
to Development: Learning the Rights Lessons from Development
Experience", World Development, Vol. 22 (12), 1811-1823.
Sornarajah, M. (1994), The International Law on Foreign Investment,
Cambridge University Press, UK.
Sousa, N; Greenaway, D; and Wakelin, K. (2000),
"Multinationals and Export Spillovers" Leverhulme Center
Research Paper 2000/14, The University of Nottingham.
Stiglitz, J.E. (1999), "The World Bank at the
Millennium", The Economic Journal, Vol. 109 (459), 577-597.
Tandon Y. (2002), "Fallacies About the Theory of FDI: Its
Conceptual and Methodological Pitfalls", Third World Network, Vol.
275, 1-4.
The New Partnership For Africa's Development Base Document,
October 2001.
Todaro, M. P. (1989), Economic Development in the 3rd World,
Longman Publishers, New York.
Ulmer, M.J. (1980), "Multinational Corporations and Third
World Capitalism", Journal of Economic Issues, Vol. XIV (2),
453-471.
United Nations (2002), Report of the International Conference on
Financing for Development, Monterrey, Mexixo, 18-22 March, United
Nations, New York, USA.
UNCTAD (2001), World Investment Report. Promoting Linkages:
Overview. United Nations, New York, USA.
UNCTAD (1999), Trends in International Investment Agreements: An
Overview, United Nations, New York, USA.
Viner, J. (1928), "Adam Smith and Laissez Faire", in J.M.
Clark; P.H. Douglas; J.H. Hollader; G.R. Morrow; M. Palyi and J. Viner
(eds), Adam Smith, 1776-1926, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, USA.
Wheeler, D. and Mody, A. (1992),"International Investment
Location Decisions: The Case of U.S Firms", Journal of
International Economics, Vol. 33, 57-76.
Wilhelms, S.K.S. and Witter, M.S.D. (1998), "Foreign Direct
Investment and its Determinants in Emerging Economies, African Economic
Policy Paper no. 9, United States Agency for International Development Bureau for Africa, Office of Sustainable Development, Washington DC,
paperavailable at http://www.eagerproject.com/discussion9.shtml
Williamson, J. (2000), "What Should the World Bank Think About
the Washington Consensus?", The World Bank Research Observer, Vol.
15 (2), 251-264.
World Bank Development Report Summary (1997), The State in the
Changing World, World Bank, Washington DC, USA.
World Bank Development Report (1993), The East Asian Miracle:
Economic Growth and Public Policy, World Bank, Washington DC, USA.
World Bank Development Report (1991), The Challenges of
Development, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.
Xu, B. (2000), "Multinational Enterprises, Technology
Diffusion, and Host Country Productivity Growth", Journal of
Development Economics, Vol. 62 (2), 477-493.
ZEIN KEBONANG
University of Botswana, Gaborone, Botswana
Table 1.1
Countries that Expropriated Foreign Investments
Country Years No of Firms
Nationalized
Algeria 1965-1978 107
Angola 1975-1978 128
Benin 1974 10
Burma 1962-1983 24
Chile 1970-1973 46
Congo 1970-1977 31
Egypt 1956-1967 70
Ethiopia 1975-78 105
Guinea 1959-1979 7
India 1967-1975 58
Iraq 1968-1977 8
Jamaica 1972-1977 12
Libya 1969-1974 33
Madagascar 1975-1978 50
Morocco 1965-1978 30
Mozambique 1975-80 43
Nigeria 1967-1974 35
Peru 1968-1975 47
Somalia 1970 10
Sri Lanka 1971-1976 254
Sudan 1970-1978 25
Trinidad & Tobago 1969-1981 10
Uganda 1970 9
Tanzania 1963-1978 27
Yemen 1969-1978 30
Zambia 1964-1980 21
Total 1404
Source: Data taken from Kennedy (1992: 73). Table slightly modified.