Financial developments in India: should India introduce capital account convertibility?
Gupta, Desh ; Sathye, Milind
Abstract
The objective of this paper is to examine whether India has reached
a stage of financial development when full capital account
convertibility could be introduced. The issue is important because in
the aftermath of the Asian and other developing countries crises, there
has been some rethink and recognition that financial deregulation can't run ahead of prudence. We answer the question posed above
within the framework provided by McKinnon on financial repression and
thereafter use the relevant financial development indicators developed
by Goldsmith to assess whether India has reached a stage of financial
development when full convertibility of rupee could be introduced. The
study concludes that India has not yet reached a stage where full
capital account convertibility could be possible.
Key Words: Currency convertibility, Indian economy, capital
movements, economic integration.
JEL Classification: F 21, 32, 36.
Introduction
The objective of this paper is to examine whether India has reached
a stage of financial development when full capital account
convertibility could be introduced. 'Capital account convertibility
is the freedom to convert local financial assets into foreign financial
assets and vice-versa at market determined rates of exchange'
(Tarapore Committee, 1997). It is associated with changes of ownership
on foreign/ domestic financial assets and liabilities and embodies the
creation and liquidation of claims on or by the rest of the world.
Capital account convertibility can be, and is, coexistent with
restrictions other than on external payments. It also does not preclude
the imposition of monetary/fiscal measures relating to foreign exchange
transactions, which are of a prudential nature (Reserve Bank of India,
2000).
The issue is important, first, because until the Asian crises of
1997-98, there was a growing consensus that free global financial flows
were positive for all and more so for the developing countries. This was
based on the proposition that it would help improve global allocation of
financial resources. As the returns on capital were higher in developing
countries, finance would flow, in general, from the developed countries
to developing countries. In the aftermath of the Asian and other
developing country crises, however, there has been some rethink and
recognition that financial deregulation can't run ahead of prudence
(Stiglitz, 2002). Second, there is also the issue of the sequencing of
financial liberalisation. Even the leading proponent of financial
repression and its associated costs, McKinnon (1973, 1991) has argued
that capital account convertibility should come at the end of this
process. Though there was support for financial liberalization, opinions
differed about the pace at which it could proceed. Some countries like
Thailand abolished the controls quickly and opened up their economies
while countries like India continued to proceed at slow pace. Until
1991, the Indian economy was subject to a high degree of financial
repression and national and international controls. These controls were
being lifted slowly when the Asian economic crisis struck. Though, India
didn't experience the shock and contagion as some South East Asian
countries did, rethinking began whether or not controls should continue
to be lifted and the pace at which this should be done. It was feared
that lifting of all controls and thus making rupee fully convertible
could expose India to shocks and contagion such as those experienced by
Asian countries. At the same time, lack of full convertibility on
capital account was acting as an impediment for free flow of capital
resources. Third, India is now in race with China to attract foreign
direct investment and hence has to weigh the pros and the cons in taking
a decision about full convertibility of its currency. Thus, India
provides a good case to analyze.
We answer the question posed above within the framework provided by
McKinnon (1973) on financial repression and thereafter use the relevant
financial development indicators developed by Goldsmith (1969) to assess
whether India has reached a stage of financial development when full
convertibility of rupee could be introduced. The paper is organized as
follows: the next section provides an overview of relevant literature on
liberalization of financial flows. We also discuss the framework of
financial repression provided by McKinnon (1973). In section 3, we
assess the financial developments in India against the financial
development indicators developed by Goldsmith (1969). Section 4
concludes.
The Liberalization of Financial Flows
While examining economic liberalization we distinguish between
internal and external controls or repression. We define the internal
repression in line with McKinnon (1973). This includes controls on
interest rates, directed lending and credit ceilings, highly regulated
and controlled financial system, high reserve requirements. The external
repression refers to forex rate distortion and controls on global
financial flows.
The Two Schools of Thoughts on the Pace of Liberalization
Until the Asian crises of 1997-98, there was a growing consensus
that controls on global financial flows were harmful and the lifting of
such controls would lead to increased flows to emerging markets,
including India, and thus lift growth rates in such countries. Two
schools of thoughts have developed in this context. As per the first
school of thought, complete lifting of controls and equal treatment of
their financial institutions was advocated by countries like USA and EU.
This assumed greater significance with the signing of the WTO Financial
Services Agreement (WFSA) of 1997 that came into effect on 1st March
1999. Canada supported the first school of thought and argued that
liberalization enhances the functioning of the financial services
sector, which in turn contributes to enhanced stability in the sector
(WTO, 2001, para 4). This view, as emphasized by Dornbusch (Fischer et
al. 1998) suggests that since resources are lost through obstacles to
free capital flows the sooner it is liberalised the better.
The second school of thought was that instead of complete lifting
of controls, the way forward was to adopt differential treatment based
on levels of development and the adoption of a more orderly and
sequenced approach to liberalization in accordance with the levels of
developments in financial markets and supervisory system of member
countries. Most developing countries supported this proposal, which was
put forward by South Korea (WTO, 2001, para 5). Thus, sharp differences
have emerged between developed countries and developing countries in the
manner in which liberalization and financial development should take
place in the wake of the aftermath of the Asian financial crises. The
developing countries were concerned with developing policies and
capacity before they could introduce full capital account convertibility
whereas the developed countries assumed that these would be undertaken
simultaneously. Though India was also a signatory to the WFSA it was in
agreement with the views of the second school of thought.
The two schools of thought differed with each other partly because
of the weight they put on the pros and the cons of the liberalization
process. Those who support global liberalization of financial markets
and integration can use the following potential benefits of such
developments to bolster their case (Pierre-Richard, 2003).
1. It can lead to consumption smoothing, that is, global funds can
be used to maintain consumption during a cyclical downturn or over a
life-cycle. Certainly the USA and Australia have been able to not only
maintain, but also enhance consumption over the last 15 to 20 years,
because of the availability of global funds.
2. It improves macroeconomic discipline, because the financial
markets would penalize bad policies.
3. It can promote domestic investment and growth as global source
of funds become available.
4. It can increase banking system efficiency and financial
stability. It can increase the depth and breadth of domestic financial
markets and lead to an increase in the degree of efficiency of the
financial intermediation process by lowering costs and excessive
profits.
Those who oppose liberalization can use the following potential
costs to support their case:
1. Capital flows remain concentrated to developed countries and
some emerging markets, such as China.
2. They are subject to 'surges' or pro-cyclical
short-term flows--inflow surges during good times due to excessive
exuberance and outflow surges during bad times due to excessive
pessimism and herding behaviour. Thus they are destabilizing. This
situation has worsened because of the growth of highly leveraged
speculative institutions, such as hedge funds, which operate from
off-shore unregulated places.
3. They may lead to misallocation of capital inflows. Such inflows
may fund speculative or low-quality domestic investment, such as real
estate investment and reduce capacity of the country to increase exports
and thus create external imbalances. These are likely to be the result
of pre-existing distortions in domestic financial system, with weak
capacity to finance new export ventures as well as poor supervision of
the financial system.
4. They can lead to loss of macroeconomic stability. This can
result from rapid credit (monetary) expansion, due to difficulty of
pursuing effective sterilization policies, leading to inflationary
pressures (resulting from the effect of capital flows on domestic
spending), real exchange rate appreciation and widening of current
account deficit.
5. Entry of foreign banks in the context of directed lending for
domestic banks can create an unequal playing field, whereby foreign
banks 'cherry-pick' the most creditworthy lenders and
depositors. This may worsen the non-performing assets (NPAs) of the
domestic banks. To counter the competition posed by foreign banks,
domestic banks resort to risky lending. During crisis, however, foreign
banks may walk out of the market as they did during the Asian crises.
The Financial Crises: Putting Sand in the Wheel of Liberalization
The financial crises of the 1990s and others of the current decade
affected the pace of liberalization. Therefore the lessons of these
crises become important in this context. These have been documented in
various studies (see Roubini 2004). The lessons were that the effects of
crises could be minimized by avoiding real exchange rate misalignment,
limiting fiscal imbalances and preventing excessive build-up of domestic
debt, maintaining a monetary policy consistent with growth with low
inflation and that the ratio of unhedged short-term currency debt over
official reserves remains sufficiently low. Strengthening of supervision
and prudential regulation, fostering of risk management capacities in
banks and non-bank financial firms are also important. Managing NPAs and
bringing them down is an important element of supervision and impacts on
the soundness of the banking system.
The short-term capital inflows lead to build up of short-term funds
with banks. When flush with these funds, in their anxiety to lend, banks
often resort to reckless lending which in turn could lead to increase in
NPAs- a typical problem of adverse selection arising out of asymmetric
information. One way out of this is to follow the example of Chile which
successfully imposed for a period a form of 'Tobin Tax' to
counter the flows of hot money or short-term flows (Vander Maelen,
2000). Emerging markets should be willing to use short-term capital
controls as part of their arsenal of policy instruments. There may be an
argument that this may affect aggregate flows to emerging markets.
Evidence from various studies, however, tends to suggest that
restrictions on short-term flows affect the maturity structure of
foreign debt, but does not affect the overall volume of flows (Campion and Neumann, 2003; Montiel and Reinhart, 1999; Edwards, 1999). Full
capital account convertibility as the experience of South Korea,
Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia suggests (see for instance, Athukorala,
2002) can lead to massive and unsustainable inflows, followed by, as the
risk perception changes, to massive outflows or a flight to quality,
leading to a crisis. Therefore, caution is suggested in moving towards
capital account convertibility.
Such imposition of controls on short-term flows should, however,
not become a permanent feature. The down side is that it is likely to
lead to imbalances between short term and long term flows and may lead
to a reduced focus on other important financial development policies
like prudential regulations and strengthening supervision. This means
that a country has to strike a balance between the quantum of short-term
flows relative to long term flows so as to ensure that the economy is
not destabilized and at the same time not pushed into a lower growth
trajectory. This would require countries to weigh the costs and the
benefits coming from such financial flows. As countries are at different
levels of financial and economic development, the decision depends upon
country specific situation. Hence, in order to come to a conclusion
whether a country has reached a stage of full capital account
convertibility, we will need to contextualize the above. In the next
section, we examine the financial developments in India.
Developments in the Indian Financial System
A description of the Indian Financial System
From 1947 to 1969
The Indian Financial System was quite well developed even prior to
India's political independence in August 1947. Both foreign and
domestic banks were present and so was a well-developed stock market.
Mumbai (formerly Bombay) is regarded as the financial capital of India.
The headquarters of India's largest partly state owned commercial
bank--the State Bank of India (formerly the Imperial Bank of India)--are
located in Mumbai (on the Western tip of India) and so also that of the
central bank of the country, the Reserve Bank of India (RBI-established
in 1935). Besides these, head offices of several commercial banks,
insurance companies, financial institutions and others are located in
Mumbai. After Independence several legislative measures were taken to
develop an appropriate banking system so as to help the social and
economic ideals that the newly independent nation pursued. The Banking
Regulation Act 1949 was passed which gave considerable powers to the RBI to tune the banking system to the needs of planned development. In 1955
the State Bank of India was established nationalizing the Imperial Bank
of India. Term lending and project financing institutions owned by the
government were soon established to provide credit for industry and
agriculture. In 1956 the life insurance business was nationalized.
From 1969-1991
Fourteen major commercial banks were nationalized in 1969 bringing
over 90 percent of banking business under public ownership. Directed
interest rates on deposits and lending, exchange controls, directed
credit became hallmark of this tightly regulated new structure. All
commercial banks (whether public or private) were directed to lend to
priority sector (mainly agriculture and poverty alleviation), which rose
overtime and in March 2002 constituted 43.1 percent of net bank credit
(3). To finance government's fiscal deficit, the incremental demand
and time liabilities of all banks were required to be invested in
government debt through the mechanism of Statutory Liquidity Ratio (SLR). In early 1990s the SLR rose to its peak of 38.5 %. Add to the
above, banks also had to maintain a Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR) of 15%. It
could be seen from the above that the Indian financial system was
tightly regulated till the 1990s. The nationalization of banks brought
over 90 percent of banking business under state ownership. Given that
the public sector banks were the dominant players in the system, we
focus on the financial data of this class of banks in our analysis in
subsequent paragraphs. This situation conforms very well with the
internal repression as described by McKinnon (1973) and referred to
above.
From 1992 onwards
Following the balance of payments crisis in 1991-92, a
stabilization programme was initiated with the help of International
Monetary Fund, which specifically included a reform of the IFS. The
controls (Licence and Permit Raj as it was called) that distorted
resource allocation and inhibited entrepreneurship were sought to be
removed progressively. Wide ranging reforms were initiated in almost all
the spheres of the economy including real sector, external sector,
agricultural and industrial sector, macro-economic policy, public sector
disinvestment etc.
The foundation for the financial sector reforms was laid by
recommendations of the Committee on Financial System 1991 (Narasimham
Committee). The Committee again reviewed the financial system in 1998
and made further recommendations. The objectives of the financial sector
reforms were to bring about greater efficiency and competitiveness in
all the spheres of the economic activity. Following major reforms were
introduced:
* Gradual phasing out of prescribed interest rates on deposits and
advances. The intention was to promote competition among banks by giving
them freedom to decide interest rates.
* Reduction in pre-emption of bank deposits by means of Cash
Reserve Ratio and Statutory Liquidity Ratio (similar to non-callable
deposit ratio and prime asset ratio in Australia). These ratios were 15%
and 48.5% respectively in early 1990s and now stand at 4.5% and 25%
respectively. (In Australia, these are currently zero percent). The
freed funds could then be used for lending to efficient businesses. Thus
achieving allocative efficiency.
* To strengthen the banking system, international standards of
capital adequacy were introduced. Indian banks were required to achieve
a ratio of 9% by the year 2000 and most Indian banks already have
capital to risk assets ratio in excess of this.
* To clean the balance sheets of banks, asset classification,
income recognition and provisioning norms on par with international
standards were introduced.
Besides the above measures to liberalize internal controls,
following measures were initiated to liberalize external controls. On
20th of August 1994, India adopted Article VIII of the IMF and thus
established current account convertibility. It is possible that if the
Asian financial crisis of 1997-98 had not occurred then India may have
introduced capital account convertibility much earlier. India escaped
the contagion, because of the absence of capital account convertibility
and because of the successful policy to reduce short-term debt.
Convertibility on all deposit schemes for non-resident Indians was
introduced in March 2002. The RBI towards the end of January 2004 issued
a notification that allows remittances abroad of upto US$ 25,000 by
resident Indians annually.
The Tarapore Committee, set up by the RBI in 1997, on the issue of
capital account convertibility, recommended a phased liberalization and
set four conditions for full convertibility. These were: there should be
six months import cover, inflation should be within 3-6 percent band,
the gross fiscal deficit to GDP ratio should be less than 3.5 percent
and gross non-performing assets (NPAs) of the commercial banking system
as a whole should be less than 5 percent. In addition, the Narsimhan
Committee (1991) dealing with the Balance of Payments had argued that
India should aim to have a current account deficit (CAD) of less than
1.6 percent of GDP. As discussed earlier there is also the issue of
short-term debt and ensuring that it does not get out of control. These
six conditions seem to be guiding the policy on convertibility.
Assessment of Financial Development in India
To assess whether the situation in India is ripe to introduce full
capital account convertibility we first examine the financial
development ratios as specified by Goldsmith (1969) and which the
Reserve Bank of India also adopted as relevant indicators. We compare
the compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of these ratios over the periods
1951-52 to 1970-71 and 1970-71 to 1991-92. If the CAGR of these ratios
shows a decline then we can conclude that the cost of financial
repression was higher than its benefits.
As can be seen from the above table all the financial development
ratios show a marked slow down of annual growth rate in the years after
bank nationalization. As stated above, this period was characterized by
financial repression as defined by McKinnon (1973). We would have liked
to calculate the CAGR of post liberalization years, however, the data
thereof is available only upto 1995-96. We calculated the CAGR between
the years from 1990-91 and 1995-96, for FR, which was 4.75 percent.
The costs of financial repression can also be measured by the
magnitude and changes in NPAs of public sector banks. The effect on NPAs
of banks is indicated in the table 2 below.
It may be noted that the type of data as described in Table 2 was
not readily available at the RBI website. As such we compared the ratios
from the year 1992-93 onwards. The high ratio of 1992-93 is a legacy of
financial repression period. It will be seen that the ratio shows a
declining trend after internal liberalization process started. However,
it needs to be noted that these ratios are compiled on the basis of NPA
definition, which is not in conformity with international standards. As
per international standards, advances past due for 90 days or over are
classified as NPAs while until recently the Indian guidelines reckoned
past due for 180 days and over as NPAs. It needs to be emphasized that
the improvements in the NPAs of public sector banks (PSBs) have taken
place in the context of increased competition from private sector
domestic banks as well as the foreign banks, that is, despite the risks
of 'cherry picking' by the latter group of banks. The decline
in NPAs has gathered increased momentum following the 2002
Securitisation Act. Under this the banks can attach property of willful
defaulters, which has increased repayments to the banks. Nevertheless,
the gross NPAs of PSBs at 8.8 percent at the end of fiscal year 2003 are
still substantially higher than those recommended by the Tarapore
Committee (1997).
We also look at the capital adequacy ratios of PSBs during the post
liberalization period. Prior to reforms no capital adequacy requirements
were applicable to banks. The international capital adequacy standard of
8 percent of risk' weighted assets was introduced in 1992 and banks
were advised to achieve it by March 1996. Currently, the capital
adequacy norm stands at 9 percent of risk-weighted assets. By March
2002, 25 out of 27 public sector banks had risk-weighted capital
adequacy ratios above the prescribed minimum of 9 percent with 23 banks
having it in excess of 10 percent. Importantly, risk-weight is also
assigned to gold and investment in government securities in calculating
the denominator of the ratio.
Next we look at the financial performance of PSBs. Table 3 below
shows the ratio of net profit to total assets or working funds of two
major PSB groups, that is, State Bank of India and nationalized banks.
As can be seen from the above table, there is some improvement in
both the groups in terms of profitability. As regards inflation, the
data given below shows that it was under control and has in general
remained in control after 1994-95 and has not exceeded single digit. But
India remains vulnerable to supply-side shocks, such as the oil-price
shocks as well as food production shocks. In 2004, inflation has picked
up and was close to 8 percent by September. This was because of the
increase in oil-price. Oil price in 2004 has increased, despite Saudi
Arabia, the swing producer in OPEC operating at full capacity.
Next we examine the position with respect to the current account
deficit.
Table 5 shows that the current account deficit has remained
relatively small in the post reform period.
We now examine the situation with respect to foreign exchange
reserves in India. As indicated in the table below the reserves have
shown a substantial increase over the post reform period.
As per newspaper reports (The Hindu, 2004) the reserves had crossed
US $100 billion mark and continued to head upwards. By the end of fiscal
year 2001-02, the reserves had exceeded 12 months import cover.
Nevertheless, it is important to note, that around 30 percent of these
deposits comprise of NRI funds, which were attracted by higher Indian
relative interest rates, and in the context of full capital account
convertibility for NRIs in the post-2002 changes. In addition there are
annual flows of remittances of between US $10 billion to US$15 billion,
which may be affected by a change in sentiment, which can occur as the
global interest rate regime changes and as the perception of risk of
depreciation of the Indian rupee increases. Bank inflows have also
increased; mainly driven by foreign banks. This could improve
competition; though it could also slow down improvements in NPAs of
government-owned banks. Such sharp increases have made the task of
managing the inflows difficult; both in terms of their sterilization and
in terms of ensuring a competitive exchange rate. There is also the risk
that as global interest rates change and the perception of a
depreciation of the rupee rise that there will be large outflows. Action
by the RBI and the newly elected Government in India has reduced this
risk. In 2004, RBI reduced the incentive for NRIs to benefit from
interest arbitrage by removing the margin they enjoyed over LIBOR. In
the 2004 budget of the new government (the United Progressive Alliance),
the attractiveness of such flows to NRIs have been further reduced by
the introduction of a 10 percent tax on interest on NR external
deposits.
Improvements in reserves have enabled the RBI to relax small and
nit-picking controls on resident Indians.
Developments in the Capital Market
The following table gives details of various indicators of capital
market development.
Data relating to years after 1997 were not readily available.
However, as can be seen from the above table, post liberalization market
capitalization as indicated by the ratio MCAP/GDP has risen. Similarly
the number of listed companies has gone up. In addition data on market
capitalization from Economic Survey 2004 show a sharp rise in 2003-2004
to Rs.13.77 trillion from Rs.7.25 trillion. These are indicators of
increased depth in the capital market.
We now assess the position with regard to external debt and more
specifically short-term external debt. Short-term external debt
increased rapidly, as policy controls on borrowings were relaxed (Joshi,
2003) and was a contributory factor in the 1990-91 balance of payments
crisis of the Indian economy, when India ran out of foreign exchange,
which situation had been exacerbated by some withdrawal of NRI deposits
and by the sudden stoppage of NRI remittances to India, mainly because
of the Gulf war and loss of jobs by Indian nationals in the Middle East.
The short-term external debt has fallen substantially by the mid 1990s
and was 3 percent of total external debt by June 2002. However, in
response to policy changes with regard to NRI deposits and the continued
gap between Indian interest rates and foreign interest rates, there has
been substantial rise in the percentage during 2003. The percentage
stood at 5.3 percent by end' of June 2003.
The gross fiscal deficit declined in mid 1990s but again picked up
and now stands between 9 to 10 percent. This is substantially higher
than what the Tarapore Committee (1997) had recommended as the
precondition for full convertibility.
In this section we assessed the relevant financial development
indicators such as NPAs, inflation, gross fiscal deficit, CAD, external
debt of the Indian economy. Our assessment shows that there has been
continuous improvement with regard to all the indicators with the
exception of gross fiscal deficit.
Conclusion
There is a continual debate among economists about the relative
merits of a rapid transition to full capital account convertibility (the
so-called "big bang" approach) and a more gradualist approach
which emphasises reforms in the real economy and financial system and
liberalising the current account before opening the capital account. In
line with the Stiglitz-Krugman argument, India has not rushed into
capital account convertibility. It has steadily moved in this direction
at a slow and calibrated pace. Starting from current account
convertibility in 1994, it introduced full capital account
convertibility first for NRIs in early 2002 and with the decisions in
January 2004 it has substantially begun the process of introducing full
convertibility for resident Indians. There have been noticeable gains in
terms of strengthening of the financial system. Nevertheless, we feel
that until the position with respect to gross fiscal deficit and the
NPAs improves, India should not introduce full capital account
convertibility. There is also the question of whether or not introducing
capital account convertibility for NRIs was necessarily in the best
interest of India at this time. It has increased short-term liabilities;
around a third of foreign exchange reserves in 2004. It has also made
the task of keeping the exchange rate competitive much more difficult.
In addition, there are rising difficulties in sterilising such inflows.
A change in policy in 2004 to pay no margin over LIBOR to such deposits
has helped to slow down these flows; as has the tax on such deposits.
Any further liberalisation is not yet warranted and the RBI should keep
open its option of introducing controls on short-term flows, if the
situation changes. This is because the gains from additional
improvements in allocative efficiency are now small and the additional
costs of 'herd' behaviour both in terms of inflows and
outflows have increased and are likely to be large. Moreover, as the
upsurge in inflation in 2004 shows, India remains vulnerable to supply
side shocks, such as the upsurge in oil-price. This can increase its
vulnerability to a rapid change in sentiment in the context of capital
account convertibility for resident Indians.
REFERENCES
Athukorala, Prema-chandra (2003), FDI in crisis and recovery:
lessons from the 1997/98 Asian crisis. Technical Report Working papers
in Trade and Development No. 2003/ 04, Economics, RSPAS, ANU.
Campion, M. and Neumann, R. (2003), Compositional Effects of
Capital Controls--Theory and Evidence. The World Economy Vol. 26 (7),
pp. 957-974.
Edwards, S. (1999), How effective are Capital Controls? Journal of
Economic Perspectives. 13 (4), pp. 65-84.
Fischer, S. & Cooper, R.N. & Dornbusch, R. & Garber,
P.M. & Massad, C. & Polak, J.J. & Rodrik, D. & Tarapore,
S.S., (1998), "Should the IMF Pursue Capital-Account
Convertibility?," Princeton Essays in International Economics 207,
International Economics Section, Departement of Economics, Princeton
University,
Goldsmith, R. (1969), Financial Structure and Development, New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Government of India.(2004), Economic Survey of India 2003-04. New
Delhi.
Joshi, V. (2003), India and the Impossible Trinity. The World
Economy April. Vol. 26 (4), pp. 555-584.
McKinnon, R. (1973), Money and Capital in Economic Development;
Brookings.
--(1991), The Order of Economic Liberalisation; Baltimore: John
Hopkins University Press.
Montiel, E and Reinhart, C. (1999), Do Capital Controls and
Macroeconomic Policies InflUence the Volume and Composition of Capital
Flows? Evidence from the 1990s. Journal of International Money &
Finance, 18, pp. 619-635
Narasimham Committee, (1991), Report of the Committee on Financial
System, Chairman M. Narasimham, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai.
Narasimhan Committee (1997), Committee on Banking Sector Reform,
Gazette of India-Extraordinary Notification, Part II, See 3 (ii),
Ministry of Finance, Government of India.
Pierre-Richard, A. (2003), Benefits and costs of International
Financial Integration: Theory and Facts, The World Economy, Vol. 26 (8),
pp. 1089-1118.
Reserve Bank of India. 2002, A. P. (DIR Series) circular No. 28,
March 4.
Roubini, N. (2004), http://www.stern.nyu.edu/globalmacro/Accessed
on 20 February 2004.
Stiglitz, J. (2002), Globalization and Its Discontents, W.W. Norton
& Company. USA.
Tarapore Committee (1997), Report of the Tarapore Committee on
capital account Convertibility, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai.
The Hindu (2004), Full Convertibility: Caution Still the Watchword,
The Hindu, February, 9.
Vander Maelen, D. (2000), Tempering Speculation: The Tobin Tax
Would Calm Global Markets and Ease Poverty, Toward Freedom, Vol. 49 (2),
[Available at http://www.towardfreedom.com/2000/may00/index.htm Accessed
on 18 Feb 2004].
World Trade Organisation (2001), Document S/CSS/W/71, para 4, 4th
May.
World Trade Organisation (2001), Document S/CSS/W/86, para 5, 11th
May.
NOTE
(1.) Corresponding author.
Desh Gupta Milind Sathye (1)
Desh Gupta, School of Business & Government, University of
Canberra, Canberra, Australia. E-mail: Desh.Gupta@canberra.edu.au
Milind Sathye (1), School of Business & Government, University
of Canberra, Canberra, Australia. E-mail: Milind.Sathye@canberra.edu.au
Table 1: Financial Development Ratios for India
CAGR CAGR
1951-52 1970-71 % 1991-92 %
Financial Ratio (FR) 0.75 17.15 17.91 41.30 4.27
Financial Interrelations 0.08 1.18 15.22 2.29 3.21
Ratio (FIR)
Intermediation Ratio (IR) 0.27 0.66 4.22 0.79 0.86
New Issue Ratio (NIR) 0.17 0.71 7.81 1.28 2.85
FR : Ratio of total financial issues in a year to national income.
FIR : Ratio of increase in the stock of financial claims to net
capital formation.
IR : The proportion of claims issued by financial institutions to
the issues of non-financial sectors.
NIR : The proportion of primary claims issued by non-financial
institutions to net capital formation.
Source: Rangarajan, C. 1998. Indian Economy Essays on Money and
Finance, New Delhi, UBS Publishers.
Table 2: Proportion of Gross NPAs to Gross Advances
of Public Sector Banks
1992-93 23
1996-97 17.84
1997-98 16.02
1998-99 15.89
1999-2000 13.98
2000-2001 12.37
2001-2002 11.09
2002-2003 8.8
Source: Reserve Bank of India, Report on Trend and Progress of Banking
in India, various years for 2002-2003 Economic Survey 2004).
Table 3: Ratio of Net Profit to Total Assets
State Bank Nationalized
Year Group Banks
1994-95 * 0.5 0.1
1995-96 * 0.4 -0.4
1996-97 0.8 0.4
1997-98 1.1 0.6
1998-99 0.51 0.37
1999-2000 0.8 0.44
2000-2001 0.6 0.3
2001-2002 0.8 0.7
Note : * refers to net profit to working funds.
Source: Economic Survey of India, Government of India,
various years.
Table 4: Annual Inflation Rate Based on Wholesale Price Index
Fiscal years End of year
(April-March) (point to point)
1992-93 7.0%
1993-94 10.8%
1994-95 10.4%
1995-96 4.4%
1996-97 6.9%
1997-98 4.4%
1998-99 5.9%
1999-00 3.3%
2000-01 7.2%
2001-02 3.6%
2002-03 3.4%
Source: http://www.indiaonestop.com/inflation.htm
From 1997-98 Reserve Bank of India Annual Report 2003.
Table 5: Current Account Deficit as a Percentage of GDP
1990-91 -3.2
1996-97 -1.2
1997-98 -1.0
1998-99 -1.0
1999-2000 -0.9
2000-2001 -0.5
2001-2002 +0.26
Source: http://www.iif.edu/data/fi/fd/FD4-4.pdf and
Economic Survey of India 2003.
Table 6: Foreign Exchange Reserves (US$ billion)
1990-91 5.834
1996-97 26.423
1997-98 29.367
1998-99 32.490
1999-2000 38.036
2000-2001 42.281
2001-2002 54.106
Dec 2002 70.445 (P)
(P) Provisional.
Source: http://indiabudget.nic.in/es2002-03/chapt2003/tab6l.pdf
Table 7: Indicators of Capital Market Development
Financial MCAP/ Turnover/ Turnover/ No. of
Year GDP GDP ratio Listed Cos.
1981 9.64 5.2 59.5 1031
1988 8.6 4.4 59.2 2240
1991 36.2 9.6 57.0 2556
1992 39.0 8.3 37.0 2781
1993 50.3 8.4 27.5 3263
1994 51.3 9.0 24.0 4413
1995 45.4 4.1 10.5 5398
1996 50.2 7.4 17.0 5999
1997 52.6 -- 42.0 5843
Source: http://www.ieg.nic.in/dis_rna_20.pdf
Table 8: Gross Fiscal Deficit as Percentage of GDP
1990-91 1996-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04
RE BE
Gross Fiscal 9.4 6.5 9.9 10.1 9.2
Deficit
RE: Revised Estimates. BE: Budget Estimates.
Source: RBI. 2003. Annual Report Table 4.1.