Guest editorial.
Mitchell, William ; Wrightson, Graham
This special issue of the Australian Journal of Social Issues
presents a number of papers by researchers largely working at the Centre
of Full Employment and Equity (CofFEE), which is an official research
centre at the University of Newcastle, Australia. The exception is the
paper by Catherine McDonald and Greg Marston who work in social work at
the University of Queensland, but who maintain close ties with CofFEE.
Most of the papers were based on research that has been presented at
various workshops and conferences over the last 12 months and have been
re-written to appeal to the readership of this journal.
The research mission of CofFEE is to promote research aimed at
restoring full employment and achieving an economy that delivers
equitable outcomes for all. Over the last 30 years we have seen an
abandonment of the goal of full employment by government and the
emergence of a new goal, which has been termed 'full
employability'. The former recognises the role of the system over
the individual in providing enough jobs to meet the desires of the
workforce whereas the latter focuses on the characteristics, attitudes
and motivations of the individual. The application of the new
'active labour market approach' has changed the way we view
'rights of citizenship' in that increasingly onerous
requirements have been placed on individuals in order to get income
support. CofFEE contends that this 'individualistic' approach
merely blames the victims of erroneous federal macroeconomic policy
which has generated a systemic constraint on the freedom of individuals
to work and enjoy income. In addition to being a paucity of jobs and
hours of work, a majority of new jobs are now part-time and increasingly
casual. Workers now are more precariously attached to the labour market
than before and this trend will worsen as the gains made by unions
through arbitral processes over the last 100 or so years are wound back
with the advent of the new Work Choices legislation. The papers examine
various aspects of the labour market changes that have occurred in the
'neo-liberal' era and present a different picture to the
constructions provided by mainstream economic and social policy
analysis. They also provide, in our view, material which allows
progressive commentators and policy activists to build viable critiques
of government policy with the aim of restoring full employment and
equity in Australia.
The papers also reflect the team-based nature of work at CofFEE
where academics at different stages of research maturity typically work
together on large projects. Much of the research reported in this volume
has been funded by the Australian Research Council Discovery and Linkage
grants schemes.
Three glaring facts describe macroeconomic outcomes in Australia
over the last 10 years or so: (a) the Federal Government has
consistently run record budget surpluses; (b) the private sector has
achieved record levels of indebtedness; and (c) labour underutilisation
(unemployment and underemployment) has persisted at high levels (around
10 per cent of more). The three outcomes are related and driven by the
first. The consequences of these linkages underpin much of the research
reported here.
Far from deserving congratulations for the surplus, the Government
should be condemned for ripping off the Australian public the critical
health, education and environmental services, which underwrite a fair
and sustainable future. Overlooked by policy makers is the issue of our
tolerance for badly needed forgone real output, as evidenced by
persistently high levels of labour underutilisation. Real issues like
this, which will determine whether there is a real capacity by the
population to enjoy adequate health and aged care in the future, are
being overshadowed by an errant comprehension of government finances.
The relentless pursuit of budget surpluses is not good economics. They
retard economic growth and the purchasing power seized is lost forever.
They do help government accumulate future spending capacity, to meet the
needs of our ageing population. The path to a fair and sustainable
future is to maintain full employment through appropriate levels of
spending requiring budget deficits. Our willingness to applaud the
surplus mongers is one of the great ironies in public life.
To address these issues, the first paper by William Mitchell and
Warren Mosler Understanding the economic fallacies of the
intergenerational debate develops a basic macroeconomic framework that
binds the papers in the volume. This framework is applied to the
so-called intergenerational debate. The authors highlight the flaws in
Federal Government claims that a number of federal programs (such as
health, social security, and education) are sensitive to demographic
factors and with population ageing, the budget 'blow out' will
be unsustainable. They challenge, at their most elemental level, the
validity of the 2002 Federal Intergenerational Report claims that: (a)
the budget cannot be allowed to reach the projected level because the
increasing public debt would push interest rates up and 'crowd
out' productive private investment; (b) increasing debt will also
impose higher future taxation burdens for our children which will reduce
their future disposable incomes and erode work incentives.
They argue that while some of the Government's real aims are
sound (for example, high quality health care) the pursuit of budget
surpluses undermines the capacity, of the economy to provide future real
goods and services of a particular composition desirable to an ageing
population. Their analysis indicates that Government would be providing
the best basis for future real growth by achieving and maintaining full
employment via appropriate levels of deficit spending now. They conclude
that in a fully employed economy, the intergenerational spending
decisions come down to political choices sometimes constrained by real
resource availability, but never constrained by monetary issues, either
now or in the future. Their case is based on a detailed study of the
spending, taxation and debt issuing systems which ineluctably shows that
federal spending is not financially constrained. They conclude that
neo-liberal misconceptions expressed in the intergenerational report
lead to the nonsensical claim that by running surpluses now the
Government will be better able (because it has 'more funds stored
away') to cope with future spending demands.
The practical consequences for government employment social workers
of the shift to a residual welfare state and an emphasis on disciplining
welfare recipients are examined in Room to move? Professional discretion
at the frontline of welfare-to-work, Catherine McDonald and Greg
Marston, both social policy researchers at University of Queensland.
They examine how different forms of professional knowledge are either
supported or weakened as well as how organisational structures can block
or form possibilities for judgement and consideration. To pursue these
aims, the authors use the Australian government's welfare-to-work
agenda to focus on the practices of social workers in Centrelink. The
authors relate that Centrelink social workers belong to a work culture
that goes back to the late 1940s when the Departments of Employment and
Social Security aimed to improve the well-being of people in receipt of
income support. Within this culture, front-line staff exercised
discretion in their work and readily tackled senior staff about best
practice.
The paper tracks a transition phase from welfare to workfare in the
late 1990s and show that professionals working within Centrelink
influenced policy and protected welfare rights and entitlements.
However, the new 'participation' agenda has led to changes in
Centrelink work practices which have made it difficult for professionals
to exercise discretion with their clientele and to influence their
managers.
Somewhat tangential is John Jenkins paper, Non-Resident Fathers
Engagement with their Children: The Salience of Leisure which critically
examines the nature of the leisure relationship between non-resident
fathers and their children. The link with the other papers is
established once we recognise that a parent's labour market
activities influence their ability to enjoy leisure. Unemployment is not
leisure despite the mainstream text-book depiction of non-work.
Disadvantages in the labour market spill over into leisure space.
Jenkins' paper is motivated by the increasing incidence of
non-resident fathers as a result of family fracture. While the
literature indicates the importance of fathers in determining their
children's well-being, for many reasons non-resident fathers
contact with their children is inadequate. One time dimension is
leisure, which allows a non-resident father and his child to engage in
mutually beneficial activities. However, within this space constraints
of limited and affordable contact are real and set the responsibilities
and commitments are often legally determined.
The author seeks to redress the scant literature on this topic by
focusing on the opportunities and constraints that mediate the leisure
relationship between non-resident fathers and their children. He
provides qualitative survey evidence which shows that non-resident
fathers struggle to have adequate contact time with their children. The
policy import is clear given the changes to legislation in recent days.
It is important to determine the factors which influence the time a
father spends with his children and to determine whether non-residence
is an intrinsic factor or not.
Beth Cook's paper Privatising health: the demise of Medicare
considers the policy developments in health care in Australia with
particular emphasis on Medicare. She demonstrates that health policy was
an integral component of the post-war Welfare State, which in effect was
a non-market, nationally-based class compromise providing income support
and service provision In the post-war period, national government
assumed 'responsibility for a socially just level of welfare'.
There were three components to this: (a) a commitment to full
employment; (b) income support to smooth out market fluctuations around
full employment; and (c) entitlement as a 'right of
citizenship.' In recent decades, national governments have been
retrenching their welfare state commitments largely because they have
falsely assumed that they were financially constrained and could no
longer afford the outlays.
The author uses the rise and decline of the universal health system
(Medicare) as the case study to demonstrate her argument about the
decline in government commitment. It is shown that Medicare has been
subjected to continuing retrenchment since the 1970s largely driven by
privatisation and the transfer of responsibility from the collective to
the private sphere. Together a residual welfare system has evolved that
threatens the Medicare goal of equitable access to quality medical
treatment. The author concludes that the principle of universal health
care has been abandoned.
The problems of the health system in the Welfare State retrenchment
era are dealt with by Anthea Bill, Sally Cowling, William Mitchell and
Victor Quirk in Employment programs for people with psychiatric
disability: the case for change. This paper presents an evaluation of
the effectiveness of existing employment policy in assisting people with
psychiatric disability to find, or return to, paid work. The Australian
Government is signatory to international agreements which obligate it to
create policy that creates adequately remunerated employment and the
reduction of unemployment for people with disability. However, the
realisation of these objectives has become shackled by the operation of
restrictive macroeconomic policy in many of the signatory countries. In
the absence of a prescribed right to work, and a state commitment to
effective full employment policy, the job prospects of those with
psychiatric disability, will remain remote. The authors argue that the
poor employment outcomes from current programs establish the need for a
paradigmatic policy shift in the form of state-provided employment
guarantees for people with psychiatric disability. Accordingly, they
argue that government's role should be: (a) to provide the enough
public sector jobs to satisfy need; and (b) ensure the design of jobs is
flexible enough to meet the heterogeneous and variable support needs of
workers. To maintain continuity, of care, an effective integration of
the public job creation scheme with mental health, rehabilitation and
employment support services is required.
Accompanying the macro spending restraint have been major
employment policy changes. The radical new industrial relations terrain
in Australia and the likely outcomes for disadvantaged workers are
considered by Sally Cowling, Robert LaJeunesse, William Mitchell and
Martin Watts in Work Choices: the low productivity road to an
underclass. The Work Choices legislation became law in March 2006 amid
claims by the Federal Government that a fairer balance of forces within
the labour market and higher employment, productivity and real wages
will result. The authors argue that Work Choices jettisons the last
vestige of equity in the labour market--the judicially-determined
wage-setting and dispute resolution machinery. While low-paid workers
will bear the brunt of the impact, few workers will be garrisoned from
the radical and damaging transformation in the way we work, earn income,
take leisure, and engage in social relationships. Far from being a move
to increasing flexibility and liberalisation, the authors argue that
Work Choices is, in fact, a significant reregulation of the labour
market in favour of capital.
They propose that under Work Choices, the imperative is to minimise
labour costs which will spur a race to the bottom and a profusion of
insecure, low-paid, poor-quality work. Allocative inefficiency will
result because a low-wage regime represents a subsidy to low
productivity firms. In addition, the failure of the Act to promote
physical and human capital formation to raise productivity signals
dynamic inefficiency and a future characterised by stagnant real wages
and living standards, and declining international competitiveness; it
ignores the role of macroeconomic policy in directly addressing the
efficiency, fairness and distributional issues that have been said to
motivate its provisions. The Bill also ignores the different bargaining
power of workers and capital and pays no attention to the serious social
repercussions that will flow when labour is treated like a commodity.
CofFEE researchers consider that the macroeconomic context
(particularly the Federal fiscal policy position) dominates in the
determination of employment. However, to explain why significant
regional unemployment disparities persist, the challenge is to uncover
how macroeconomic constraints are 'distributed' across
regional space. The paper by Anthea Bill, William Mitchell and Martin
Watts entitled Examining commuting patterns, employment growth and
unemployment in Sydney, focuses on labour mobility in the Sydney Main
Statistical Region between 1996 and 2001. The paper shows that when
employment growth is spatially uneven regionally localised growth (and
stagnation) may promote strong migratory and commuting responses, as
relatively advantaged workers seek out new employment opportunities. It
is the unevenness in the distribution of employment opportunities that
is the key factor, rather than differentials in the rewards and risks of
the destination region that motivates mobility.
From a policy view point, strong in-commuting may frustrate the
attempts of local policymakers to deliver opportunities to resident
unemployed or to stimulate local business via increased resident
purchasing power. On the other hand, local job creation strategies may
not be strictly necessary to revitalise flagging local economies, if
resident workers are able to secure employment in neighbouring regions.
This reliance on residential mobility may heavily disadvantage
low-skilled workers who are less likely to commute or migrate. As a
consequence, local employment generation does not typically benefit the
most disadvantaged unemployed local residents. The authors conclude that
the main problem motivating the mobility flows is that overall
employment growth has not been sufficient to generate enough jobs to
satisfy the desires of the workers. This is a macroeconomic problem as
indicated in the first paper in this special issue.
The final paper by William Mitchell, Jenny Myers and James Juniper,
The dynamics of job creation and destruction in Australia examines the
labour market from the perspective of job flows, which is unusual in the
Australian context. They develop measures of job creation and
destruction for different industry sectors and show how these flows
behave during the 1991 recessions. They show that recessions impact
differentially on job creation and destruction for part-time employment
compared with full-time employment. Recessions particularly damage
full-time work and with an underlying trend towards high proportions of
part-time work. Full-time job creation is positively related to GDP growth but asymmetries are present--it declines more when GDP growth is
negative than it rises when GDP growth is positive. In the case of goods
production, part-time job destruction is lower when GDP growth is
negative. Full-time job destruction is highly asymmetric and rises
sharply when GDP growth is negative, especially in the Goods and Trades
sectors. Part-time job creation is less volatile. The policy
implications of these cyclical sensitivities are straightforward. What
is lost through net job loss during the downturn takes much longer to
recover from in the upturn. Moreover, recessions appear to leave a
residue of underemployment, largely through their differential influence
over the composition of part-time and full-time employment. As a policy
application, the authors use their empirical results to conjecture about
the likely consequences of the Work Choices legislation.
We thank Louise Sims at AJSI for her patience in dealing with the
guest editors and Deborah Mitchell for inviting us to bring this
research to a wider, non-economics audience. Graham Wrightson, a
co-editor of this issue, handled all the refereeing and quality control.
We hope you find the issue interesting and thought-provoking.
Bill Mitchell and Graham Wrightson
May 2006