Contesting capitalism in the light of the crisis: a conversation with David Harvey.
Primrose, David
David Harvey is the Distinguished Professor of Anthropology and
Geography at the Graduate Center of the City University of New York. He
is author of numerous articles and books that develop a distinctively
Marxist political economy. Some of his best-known works include: The New
Imperialism (2003); A Brief History of Neoliberalism (2005); The Limits
to Capital New Edition (2006); Social Justice and the City: Revised
Edition (2009); A Companion to Marx's Capital (2010); The Enigma of
Capital and the Crises of Capitalism (2010); and Rebel Cities: From the
Right to the City to the Urban Revolution (2012). His next book will be
a companion to volumes two and three of Marx's Capital.
This interview, conducted by David Primrose in New York on 15
November, 2012, explores four major themes arising from Professor
Harvey's work: neoliberalism, Marxism, spatial political economy
and praxis.
The Contemporary State of Neoliberalism
DP: In light of the global financial crisis, many academics and
political figures proclaimed the death of neoliberalism. Yet, almost six
years later, it remains institutionalised at both the national and
global levels. Could you please, first, explain how you understand
neoliberalism?
DH: My take is grounded in the idea that neoliberalism is a project
of class power. It has been concerned with disempowering labour relative
to capital, adopting policy measures such as privatisation in order to
enable further capital accumulation and institutionalising wealth,
privilege and power within the upper-classes without cease.
Simultaneously, of course, there has been a lot of rhetoric surrounding
this project. In the latter sense, freedom and individual liberty have
regularly been espoused by various think-tanks and politicians as the
high-point of civilization which, in turn, must be enabled through an
institutional structure encouraging individual institutive and personal
responsibility, comprising free markets, strong private property rights
and free trade. Importantly, though, these have been simply the
ideological masks of what was, all along, a class project to restore and
consolidate class wealth and power which was under threat by the 1970s.
In spite of the current crisis, framed in these class-based terms, it
has been a very successful project.
DP: So, this conception relates to the distinction you have often
drawn between neoliberalism in-theory and in-practice?
DH: That's right.
DP: Is this distinction based on a fundamental dichotomy between
ideas and reality, or do you see the neoliberal ideas you mentioned,
relating to free markets and so forth, as being more constitutive of
material practices?
DH: The first thing to say is that there is a lot of theoretical
masking that has gone on and many of the policies promoted by the
institutions of neoliberalism have not really been justifiable according
to the theory. For example, a true-blue neoliberal theorist would not
argue that the IMF is justified. In espousing the virtues of free
markets, deregulation and so forth, what justification can you give for
the IMF as an institution that goes around and interferes in things? The
state is not supposed to do that and yet it does. This is what I mean
about the idea that there is a big difference between a theoretical mask
and reality--between the rhetoric and what goes on in practice. By the
same token, you can't justify predatory practices under neoliberal
theory. Yet, as we've seen during the recent mortgage crisis and
the increasing prominence of Ponzi schemes, there have been a lot of
predatory practices over the last 20-30 years. These have no
justification in neoliberal theory and yet they have been critical to
the consolidation and further accumulation of class power.
DP: So why do the practices associated with neoliberalism remain as
the prevailing institutional forms of contemporary capitalism? The ideas
of neoliberalism were certainly scrutinized--at least to some degree--in
both policy-making and academic circles in light of the crisis. Yet, in
the years following the height of the crisis, neoliberal measures have
continued to prevail as the dominant political responses to the crisis.
Can you explain why this might be the case?
DH: This is a complex question. A key component of the problem
relates to the distinction between the ideas and material practices of
neoliberalism that we've just been discussing. Most populist
attacks have missed the mark by framing the problem in terms of the
prevailing state-market dichotomy assumed to characterise neoliberalism,
rather than examining the nature of its underlying class relations. Part
of the answer, then, must lie in the fact that the class-based nature of
neoliberalism has proved to be very durable in the face of the crisis,
in spite of the varied attacks on its theoretical foundations.
Fundamentally, this means that the strategies for accumulation of
capital and power by the owners of capital are now premised on the
resilience and extension of neoliberal forms of regulation. In this
sense, neoliberalism has never been about the question of more or less
state 'intervention', but rather has been concerned with the
creation and consolidation of wealth and power in the hands of a
concentrated section of society. In turn, in the absence of a
significant shift in the balance of social forces, these same interests
have significant political power to continue to promote and
institutionalise these interests.
Thus, both academically and politically, too little attention has
been given to challenging the underlying social relations of
neoliberalism to promote a fundamental shift in institutional logics.
There has been no break in the growing social inequalities which exist
in, say, the United States and those parts of the world that are
dedicated to the neoliberal project. The result has been that,
throughout this crisis, the rich have grown astonishingly richer. In
fact, the crisis has been an excuse for even more draconian measures to
suck-out the wealth from much of the world for a very small group. For
instance, while President Obama's healthcare reforms were promoted
as an attempt to overturn the prevailing neoliberal institutions of
healthcare, in effect this has simply extended public subsidisation of
private health insurance providers. Similarly, the nationalisations of
financial institutions in both the UK and US were designed to prop-up
the viability of the system of capital accumulation, rather than being
utilised for broader social objectives such as enabling massive
investment in those communities most affected by housing foreclosures or
the promotion of full employment. So, while appearing to depart from
common sense notions of neoliberal policy, such measures have not
countered the power of capital.
Simultaneously, mobilisations by some labour movements against
further neoliberalisation have been mostly ineffective in countering
these prevailing social relations. Take the example of Greece, for
instance. In spite of the pervasive and militant social movements raging
against neoliberal responses to the 'sovereign debt crisis',
successive Greek governments have agreed bailout packages conditional on
austerity programs including massive cuts to public- sector wages,
social services and extensive privatisations. Taken together, I think
these examples point to at least one important explanation for the
continued dominance of neoliberalism: that is, the durability and
inability to effectively challenge the class relations underpinning the
neoliberal project.
DP: So, can this situation be viewed as one in which neoliberalism
has trumped democracy, or is this too simplistic an explanation? As you
outline in A Brief History of Neoliberalism, democracy was violently
undermined in establishing the social structures of Pinochet's
Chile and Thatcher's Britain. Yet, particularly in the USA, as
opposed to the scenes of protest we are witnessing in Europe, there
appears to be a fair amount of public support for rolling-back the state
in order to trim the deficit. Can this be attributed to some sort of
'false consciousness' on the part of the American people, or
is democracy also a necessary part of the neoliberal project?
DH: What I call 'The Party of Wall Street' controls
politics. It controls the media. It controls the courts. It increasingly
controls education, particularly since state education has become less
state-funded and increasingly subject to corporate donations or research
projects. So, in a way, all the cards are stacked against. In this
sense, in addition to the class-based project we have just been
discussing, neoliberalism has been an ideological assault as well, there
can be no question. It is one that has been going on for the last 35
years under the notion of personal responsibility. So, for instance, of
the many people who lost their houses in the crisis, most surveys would
show that most would see this as being their own fault. They are unable
to see a systemic question here and blame themselves, which is what the
neoliberal ethic says you should do. So, it is not false consciousness
in the sense that people are stupid, but rather that there has been an
ideological assault and voices that want to refute this have no space.
Since the onset of the crisis, we have seen numerous right-wing
explanations of the crisis which explain it in terms of personal greed,
both in Wall Street and those who borrowed money to buy houses. So they
attempt to blame the crisis on the victims. In turn, one of the central
tasks of critical political economists must be to refute such
explanations and to work to create a consolidated, more systemic
explanation of this crisis, framed as a class event in which a certain
structure of exploitation broke down and is about to be displaced by an
even deeper structure of exploitation. As I say, it is very important
that this alternative explanation of the crisis is discussed and
conveyed publicly. Yet, my own personal experience, for instance, is
that I have not been able to get into the mainstream media at
all--occasionally, I have been able to get onto local, regional or
national public radio, so it is a sewn-up job and it is impossible to
really find a good way to get out of it. The institutionally entrenched
logic and interests of neoliberalism in key centres of power affords it
enormous inertia.
Moreover, in those countries where there are residual institutions,
such as strong union movements in certain countries of Europe, there are
certainly movements against austerity. Yet, these are strikes primarily
against something rather than putting forward an alternative. That is,
they are not going out and demanding that the system be revolutionised
in favour of something else. It is primarily about protest, rather than
an alternative vision of, for instance, a socialist world informed by
alternative conceptions of income distribution, equality and so forth.
DP: With that in mind, it seems particularly apposite at the moment
to discuss the result of the recent US elections. In Rebel Cities, you
posit that 'The Party of Wall Street has one universal principle of
rule: that there shall be no serious challenge to the absolute power of
money to rule absolutely.' What is the interaction between this
Party of Wall Street and the traditional parties in the US, Republican
and Democrat? Do you think the outcome of the Presidential election will
have any impact on this relationship?
DH: No, it doesn't have a basic effect. What was a little bit
encouraging about the last election was the vast amount of money
invested by the Party of Wall Street in the Republicans, and yet they
still lost. In other words, intuitively I think there was a populist
resistance to the way money power was being used and, as things go on,
there may be more evidence of popular backlash by groups against tactics
used by the rightwing -attempts at voter suppression backfired, for
instance, and was a source of great angst amongst voters on the day and
in the media--there was some recognition that attempts to stop people
voting highlighted just how much was at stake. At the same time, there
was an over-reach of totally negative advertising by money power and
people simply switched-off after a while. However, I think next time
they will have learnt this lesson and be more sophisticated.
This does not, of course, mean that large sections of the
Democratic Party are not also captive to Wall Street. In fact, one of
the things we've seen in the week since the election is a call for
Obama to get closer to Wall Street and stop any, admittedly very weak,
rhetoric relating to class struggle and get back to negotiating. Having
lost the election, Wall Street will be looking to cuddle-up to the
President and Democratic majority in the Senate.
Marxism
DP: Could we now take a brief conceptual detour to consider your
vast contribution to Marxism. Can you please elaborate why you draw on
the conceptual currents of, primarily classical, Marxism that you do,
rather than post-classical or post-Marxism?
DH: It is a bit of an accident really. I've always felt that
if people were going to be acolytes or critics of Marx, then they should
read him and read all of him carefully. So, I have spent much of my time
teaching Marx's Capital. Through doing this, my own understanding
of Marx has come back further to trying to understand why Marx was
trying to do in Capital, Theories of Surplus Value and the Grundrisse.
Indeed, I've even found it less and less interesting to go back to
Lenin. In turn, I seemed to be getting further in my own interpretation
of processes of urbanisation or what occurred in second empire Paris by
using Marx's own text, rather than a lot of the later Marxist
works, so I keep going with this. It occurred to me that there is so
much discussion about Marx, but I've increasingly found that much
of the discussion--even that by Marxists--has been very ill-informed
about what Marx actually said. So I've increasingly thought it
important to continue lecturing on his work and placing the lectures
online, as well as writing the Companion volumes. You do what you can
do. So I thought, given my experience in teaching it over the years, I
could probably do this as well as anybody could and at least it would
encourage people to go back and look at the original texts. In turn,
over the course of it, you can see that there are some very significant
misinterpretations of what Marx said simply by going back to the
original texts.
DP: That is one of the most interesting things about your own
contribution--particularly in The Limits to Capital and A Companion to
Marx's Capital, where you emphasise the great insights to be drawn
from Marx while not losing sight of the limitations of his conceptual
oeuvre. Does this have any implications for how you see the state of
play in contemporary Marxist political economic thought? Particularly in
light of the global financial crisis, do you see the plethora of works
utilising Marx's insights as moving in the right direction--both
conceptually and politically--or are you concerned that it has stagnated
somewhat? For instance, do you feel that contemporary works are going
around in circles about what Marx really meant in particular passages or
in attempting to make Marx respectable to a mainstream audience, such as
in Howard Nicholas' Marx's Theory of Price and its Modern
Rivals?
DH: I find it difficult to comment on that. Maybe it's partly
an age-factor, but I don't really go out and read all of the latest
works being produced. I do what I can do and hope that people will get
something out of it. My impression is that there has been quite a
positive reception to the online video and companion books. I do get
some impression, though, if I go to a conference such as Historical
Materialism. One of the impressions I have got recently, and it is not a
very favourable one, is that people seem to be increasingly interested
in making Marx even more complicated than he already is. Without
oversimplifying, I think we should be trying to develop clearer
presentations of what his work is about, while also not evading the
revolutionary impulses and significance of his political economy: trying
to identify what the revolutionary project should be focussed on.
At the same time, I have also found that many Marxists can be very
conservative, locking themselves into a particular conception of Marx.
For instance, there is currently a very large body of work focussing
almost solely on Marx's notion of the 'tendency of the rate of
profit to fall', as if this is the only thing Marx ever wrote. I
think this is crazy. In turn, this form of conservatism carries over
into some strange reactions to some of my own work. For instance, when I
began discussing the notion of 'accumulation by
dispossession', many Marxists reacted quite poorly and suggested
that I was doing nothing more than a semantic job on the existing notion
of 'primitive accumulation'. In part, this is true, though I
wanted to emphasise that the notion is an evolving one with distinct
forms in contemporary capitalism. If I go out in Iowa, for instance and
speak to farmers about the notion of 'accumulation by
dispossession', they know exactly what I am talking about. On the
other hand, if I go and posit the notion of 'primitive
accumulation, they do not know what I am talking about. So why be
fixated on not changing the language to something that common people can
understand and relate to? Consider the recent crisis in the housing
market and all the associated predatory practices therein: why refer to
this as primitive accumulation when it can be conceptualised as
accumulation by dispossession and people can understand it? This is the
sort of conservatism that worries me in Marxist circles.
Having said that, though, the third point I would make is that
there have been scholars who have been developing Marx's project is
various, often useful and positive ways. I admire the way they're
done this. People such as Peter Gowan and Giovanni Arrighi have already
made contributions to the way we should understand Marxian theory. At
the same time, while I disagree with certain aspects of it, the more
recent work on finance by Costas Lapavitsas and Leo Panitch, as well as
the work by David McNally, have contributed to revitalising the interest
in Marx and, at the same time, advance certain arguments that are
apposite for understanding the current conjuncture. So there is a lot to
be admired.
DP: Is this why, for instance, in The Enigma of Capital, you
develop the concept of a crisis of overaccumulation in order to
understand the present conjuncture rather than, for instance, taking
Marx ex cathedra and drawing on his concept of the 'tendency of the
rate of profit to fall'?
DH: Well, it is always a question of absorption of surpluses and I
think that is terribly important. However, there are various ways you
can talk about this. So, in Engima, I wanted to discuss how capital does
not solve its crises but simply moves them around from one sector to
another, or even geographically. It is important to be sensitive to
this. For example, in May this year, I spent some time in Istanbul,
which is a boom-town in Turkey and growing rapidly. In contrast, flying
a few hours to Athens I found a complete contrast. So how do we create a
theory of political economy to account for the contrast between Istanbul
and Athens? Do we suggest that these differences are something that are
annoying and push them to the background? Or do we regard them as
fundamental to the capitalist dynamic, as I argue in discussing uneven
geographical development? In the latter case, this requires developing a
theory to explain why Turkey, which was in crisis in 2001, is now not;
why Argentina, which was in crisis in 2001, is now not (even if it is
now sliding back in); and why these same tendencies are not uniform in
other parts of the world. So, the most important argument about crisis
theory is to come up with a conceptualisation of how crises move around
and what they are about in different places and what the political
responses are in these places and questioning whether these ameliorate
or exacerbate the crisis tendencies. These are the sorts of issues that
need to be addressed.
DP: This obviously has implications for your understanding of the
current crisis. Coupled with the problematic assumption that
deregulation is the cause of our current economic woes is the belief
perpetuated in much mainstream and progressive circles that finance is
simply a parasite on the real economy. What you argue, however, in both
The Limits to Capital and The Enigma of Capital is that, although part
of finance is obviously speculative, finance actually plays a crucial
role for accumulation in general. Can you explain why?
DH: Finance is what I might call a form of 'butterfly
capital': based on an analogy of motion, I see finance as
fluttering around the world, landing and then taking off again when it
likes. In contrast, commodities crawl around like a caterpillar and
production tends to be stuck in place. So you have different mobilities
for capital in different forms. Clearly, you would not get an
equalisation of profit if the butterfly form of capital did not exist
and could not flutter from one place where profits are low to where they
are higher. So it becomes, as Marx depicts it in Volume 3 of Capital,
really the centre of where the common capital of class operates in the
way of coordinating and managing the total global capital. So, without
this, you wouldn't have globalisation as we know it, nor the
equalisation of the rate of profit going on. So, without finance and
credit, we would have to hoard so much capital to deal with the
temporality of fixed capital and reinvestments and so on, that
everything would be slowdown and be hoarded. So you liberate capital and
free it up by turning it into the butterfly form so it can flutter
around, which in turn opens up possibilities. For instance, by
fluttering from a location where it is difficult to produce surplus
value to somewhere else where it is easier, it is (at least indirectly)
redirecting capital to those sites where you can increase the surplus
value production. So while it is not directly contributing to the
production of surplus value itself, it does direct capital to that place
where greater surplus value can be produced.
Geography and Spatial Political Economy
DP: On that point, could you please elaborate why you place great
emphasis on the spatial dimensions of neoliberalism and contemporary
capitalism? Moreover, why do you utilise Marxism in order to
conceptualise this significance?
DH: Marx is talking about the circulation process, which is
necessarily a temporal process. He suggests that a commodity is not
complete until it is brought to the market. To do this, it must travel
across space. The optimum for capital is when circulation time is zero,
which means that any time which is taken to cover space is a deduction
in surplus value. So there is a tremendous incentive in capital to
reduce spatial barriers, meaning that it is necessary to produce space
in order to remove space. It is necessary to make airports, highways,
railways and so on, which are all fixed in space, in order to get the
motion. It is necessary to construct a landscape which is optimal from
the standpoint of reducing circulation time. This becomes absolutely
critical ...
DP: So, in this sense, you could suggest that the production of
space is inherently tied-up with innovation processes under capitalism?
DH: Exactly. I ask you, what have been the major innovations in the
history of capitalism? How many of them have been about precisely
reducing spatial barriers? Railroads. Canals. The automobile.
Telecommunications. Looking at the history of innovation, most social
scientists seem to come the conclusion that these developments have
occurred because capitalism is interested in progress. On the other
hand, I would posit that such developments were necessary in order to
lower the barriers to circulation time. There is an impulsion within
capitalism to, as Marx said in the Grundrisse, annihilate space through
time. So, this means that it is necessary to produce a geography of a
certain kind. This production absorbs vast amounts of capital--often
fixed capital--which is vulnerable to devaluation. Then ask the
question: what triggered many of the crises in the 19th century?
Railroads and over-speculation in their production. What caused the most
recent crisis? Over-speculation in the property market! So, to discuss
the production of space and consider it as a site of contradictions and
crisis production is terribly important. Only if you imagine that all
economic activity occurs on the head of a pin, can you develop a
non-geographical theory about what is actually going on in contemporary
capitalism.
DP: So it is for you, then, both a question of ontology and praxis?
DH: Precisely.
DP: In Rebel Cities, you talk about monopoly rent and the
contradictions inherent in that process. Could you please explain those
contradictions and their significance for your analysis?
DH: I use the term 'monopoly rent' in a locational sense.
All spatial competition is monopolistic competition. There is always
something monopolistic about space: I am monopolising the chair I am
sitting in now, you are monopolising your chair, so you and I can't
be in your chair at the same time. Thus, there is a monopoly
relationship. All spatial competition is monopoly competition which is
why most economists don't like to deal with spatial questions:
their model of an economy is a space-less one on the head of a pin. Yet,
capitalists--who are supposedly great fans of competition--prefer
monopoly. So, they try to gain a monopoly position and utilise
locational strategies to gain advantage. If I locate my factory at the
right intersections of the railroads and highway system, I will have
easier access to the market than my competitor on the other side of
town, so I can gain a monopoly rent out of this.
The second aspect is that I may try to gain a monopoly rent by
taking a particular quality of a space and market it as non-replicable.
Thus, we are increasingly seeing cities brand themselves, for example:
positing that there is no other city like their own. In turn, within
this marketing of qualities, we are increasingly seeing the embedding of
a notion of cultural specificity, so that history and culture are
increasingly being marketed as part of an experience unique to that
city. Yet, in marketing it, the city and its history and culture are
becoming commodified as a brand, which is then placed alongside other
brands from which consumers are supposed to choose. This is a phenomena
that can be seen in the production of commodities more generally: why
should a shoe with the Nike 'tick' cost more than something
else? Because of the symbolism and cultural value attached to possessing
a Nike shoe, enabling Nike to charge a monopoly price, differentiating
it from other shoes. Capitalists are constantly seeking to establish
some brand monopoly and gain a monopoly price out of it.
DP: How have neoliberalised urbanization processes destroyed the
city as a social, political and liveable commons? In particular, how
have these affected unrest among lower-income people who live in cities?
DH: It gets destroyed in a number of ways. Partly through the
transformation of spatial organisation. The neoliberalisation of the
city has been concerned with the reoccupation of central city sites
through gentrification, which has meant expelling low-income groups
from, often, favoured locations. It has also been about
'Disney-fication' and commercialisation; the introduction of
box-stores, which have destroyed the power of local neighbourhood shops.
In other words, the irony is that while neoliberalism is supposed to be
about competition, it has in reality been more about monopolising these
spaces.
At the same time, neoliberalism has also been concerned with
dividing the city into gated communities, so we were supposed to
desegregate the city 40 or 50 years ago, yet it has become increasingly
segregated by building gated communities which are socially-segregated
structures. Thus, the city as a body-politic disappears and everybody
withdraws into their fragments: people in gated communities are
concerned about their own immediate community rather than the city as a
whole. The notion of obligation, based on the responsibility of
different sections of the city to others begins to fade. It is only
occasionally resurrected, such as occurred after Hurricane Sandy in
which inhabitants in those parts of New York not greatly affected have
taken the time to help those without power and food. It is this sense of
obligation that has also been expressed by the Occupy Movement. Indeed,
it is all the members of the Occupy Movement who were out on the streets
of New York prior to the Red Cross and FEMA to help those in need. It is
this sense of obligation across the city that has been much weakened
under neoliberalism, as has the notion of social solidarity across the
city. One of the projects I am currently interested in is what forms of
institutions and social movements could be instrumental in helping to
re-establish this sense of mutual-obligation in the city as a whole: can
we organise a whole city and, if so, how would the organisation of the
whole city work in transforming it from a fragmented to collective
entity?
DP: This is presumably a project that relates to the concept you
have repeatedly espoused throughout your work on the 'right to the
city'?
DH: Yes, that's right.
DP: That is very interesting because, in the context of
neoliberalism, complemented by a resurgence of interest in Henri
LeFebvre's work, the 'right to the city' is a phrase
regularly promoted in progressive academic and political circles. Yet,
in Rebel Cities, you describe the concept as largely an empty slogan.
Does this mean that you see the concept as largely symbolic in the
contemporary context?
DH: No, rights are always what I would call an 'empty
signifier'. The only interesting question is who fills them with
meaning. Marx, for instance, discusses the dialogue that takes place
between capital and the worker: the capitalist suggests that they have a
right to employ the worker for 100 hours in the week, to which the
workers replies that this is not the case. Marx argues that both are, in
fact, equally correct--between equal rights, force decides. This is true
of claiming the right to the city which, here in New York, is currently
held by developers and a mayor who is a billionaire. Yet, what about
those on Staten Island who have been smashed by Hurricane Sandy--do they
not also have a right to the city? The point here is that the notion of
a right to the city is certainly important, though it is necessary to
ensure that it is the groups like those on Staten Island who have a
voice and a right to the city, rather than simply the well-off groups
who currently hold power. Thus, once again, it is the case that between
equal rights, force decides. If different factions of the city have
equal rights to the city, then we must examine the power relations
between those who currently dominate and claim the right the city and
those who do not have power and wish to claim it back.
Praxis
DP: Your work has always utilised theory in order to make visible
the temporal, spatial and environmental dynamics of capitalism. In the
introduction to The Urban Experience, you state that 'Theories
provide cognitive maps for finding our way in a complex and changeable
... [world]'. Likewise, in the Afterword to The Limits of Capital,
you maintain that 'the aim is ... to create frameworks of
understanding, an elaborated conceptual apparatus, with which to grasp
the most significant relationships at work within the intricate dynamics
of social transformation'. Yet, no-one could accuse you of engaging
in pure conceptualisation divorced from real world experience. Given you
earlier emphasised the necessity to maintain the revolutionary impulses
of Marx's political economy, can you please explain why theory is
so important to your work?
DH: The odd thing here is that my primary interest all along has
not been in Marxian theory per se, but rather understanding urbanisation
and uneven geographical development, social inequality and production of
the landscape of equality and so on. Historically, I found that I could
describe all this inequality, yet I could not explain it without the aid
of developing theory. I tried various theoretical frameworks, none of
which worked adequately, until I got into Marx. So, all along, it has
been a dialogue between my understanding of Marx's theory, which in
turn has been very much shaped by that theory being in dialogue with
trying to understand particular political economic developments--whether
this be what happened in Second Empire Paris or Baltimore since the
1970s. Thus, I felt that I needed to get away from just describing the
inequalities because there is a great deal of academic work available
that, for me, is the equivalent of moral masturbation: scholars
patronisingly suggesting that other scholars go out and look at all the
poor people. It is, of course, necessary to document such empirical, but
the flip-side of the coin is to understand why: what are the processes
creating this situation? Otherwise, we are just dealing with symptoms
all the time rather than the guts of the problem.
I felt that Marxist theory was helping me get to the nature of the
problem and I still feel this way--perhaps more so now than ever. Thus,
as I put it back in the theory I wrote about in Revolutionary and
Counter Revolutionary Theory in Geography and the Problem of Ghetto
Formation, it is necessary to move to a situation whereby rather than
describing the problem, we need to understand the problem and our
politics needs to respond by changing those processes that give rise
these problems. For me, these processes are fundamentally the processes
of capital accumulation, requiring that we go after capital
accumulation. Of course, most academics writing about urbanisation and
the right to the city don't want to do that because it means
confronting political economic power. Yet, it is necessary to consider
these issues and, in order to do so, it is necessary to have a theory to
really justify the understanding that says certain inequalities have
been produced by particular processes. If the accumulation of capital
gives rise to the problem, the solution cannot be supporting further
capital accumulation and more markets.
I have been around for a long time and have heard many, many
antipoverty programmes. In all cases, the focus has been on more
development defined in terms of more growth and more capital
accumulation. Yet, it was only toward the middle of my life that I
realised that accumulation was creating the problem. Thus, we must find
another answer to the problem. In order to make this switch, however, I
needed a theoretical understanding of how capitalism works and it is
this what I get from Marx.
DP: This is a particularly striking issue in the current
crisis-ridden context, because it seems that much contemporary critical
social science has reduced questions of praxis to the elaboration of
better theories and political solutions as stemming from a contest of
rational ideas. Yet you emphasise the capacity of knowledge to enter
into the constitution of the world it seeks to describe and thus to
change the world rather than simply represent it. What role, if any, do
you see for political economic ideas in informing progressive politics
in the current conjuncture?
DH: That is a difficult question. This is an area in which I have a
problem with some Marxists who seem to think, 'yes! It's a
crisis; the contradictions of capitalism will now be solved!' Yet,
this is not a moment for triumphalism; rather it is a time for
problematising. The first point I would make is that I think there are,
in fact, problems with the way Marx set up those problems. While they
are terrific at understanding some other things, Marxists are not very
good at understanding many of the critical ingredients of the current
conjuncture, such as the state-financial-complex or urbanisation. Thus,
we now have to rethink our theoretical posture and political
possibilities.
Secondly, and relatedly, dealing with the current crisis requires a
lot of theoretical re-thinking to be combined with practical action. How
we understand the crisis is inevitably tied up with the opportunities we
see for political action. So, as I have regularly argued, I understand
the crisis as necessitating a reimagining of how we reconfigure
urbanisation. The high rate of foreclosures here in the US must be
understood not just as a financial crisis, but rather as an urban
crisis: as a financial crisis of urbanisation. In turn, this requires
solutions addressing the specifically urban: as a means of addressing
the foreclosure crisis, for instance, the creation of a national
redevelopment bank imbued with the stimulus funds approved by Congress
could have been linked to municipalities to deal with neighbourhoods
hardest hit by the foreclosure wave, with the aim of bringing back
the--primarily poor--people who used to live in those communities and
re-housing them on a different basis of residency rights, tenure and
with a different kind of financing. Similarly, to do anything on global
warming we must totally reconfigure how American cities work; to
conceptualise a completely new pattern of urbanisation, with new
patterns of living and working.
Finally, it is important to emphasise that I am not against
marginal, incremental theoretical transformations which can mitigate or
assuage some of the worst aspects of the problem. I would never say this
is a waste of time. If we can make life better for 5% of the population,
we should seize every opportunity to do so. Yet, at the end of the day,
what separates me from this line of thinking is that, given my
understanding of Marx, I would say that it is also necessary to go
beyond capital through a form of revolutionary program. Thus, while I
will always look at and promote incremental changes, I would like to
think that there is an endpoint that could be called a
'revolutionary reform': a reform that would edge things to the
end-product where the point of the completed reform is to open the
revolutionary program. Thus, rather than thinking about the reform
itself, I always think in terms of the revolutionary transformation and
how it might be scaled. So, while I would certainly enter into alliance
with reformists at various points throughout history, I would like to
redirect their reforms toward a different dynamic in the future.
DP: With that in mind, I'm interested in your discussions
about strategy. As you argue in Justice, Nature and the Geography of
Difference, the traditional conception that the left has had of the
industrial working class as the sole revolutionary subject, the agent of
change, is not one that we can cling to in the West. Yet, while
recognising the importance of adopting a plurality of strategies, you
also argue that it is important not to descend into a form of postmodern
identity politics. Can you explain how you re-conceive of the
revolutionary subject and who might constitute that now?
DH: The first thing to say is that I would emphasise is that it is
up to the social movements themselves to discern and identify the
strategies and policies they would embrace. As academics, we must not
view ourselves as ever having some missionary role in relation to social
movements; we should, instead, develop a dialogue and discuss how we
view the nature of the problem. Thus, for me, the core problem in any
capitalist economy is how you are going to absorb capitalist surpluses
in a productive and profitable way. Social movements must coalesce
around the pursuit of increased control over the surplus product. While
this does not mean a return to the 'Keynesian' model that
prevailed in the 1960s, this period did exhibit far greater social and
political control over the production, utilisation and distribution of
the surplus, which was invested into the building of schools, hospitals
and infrastructure. Indeed, this was what angered the capitalist class
and led to a counter-movement toward the end of the 1960s--that they did
not possess sufficient control over the surplus. Yet, at least here in
the US, examination of the
data suggests that the proportion of the surplus absorbed by the
state has not shifted much since around 1970. So, the effect of this
counter-movement was for the capitalist class to effectively stop the
further socialisation of the surplus.
The question of which groups may take a leading role in this
struggle to regain control over the surplus is a more complex matter. It
is difficult to discern which groups may constitute the agents of change
in the current conjuncture, particularly as so much political energy has
recently been expended on re-establishing the legitimacy of the system.
In addition, this will obviously vary in different parts of the world.
At the height of the crisis in the US, for instance, many people were
made redundant in the financial services--even having their mortgages
foreclosed in some instances. Consequently, there were--and, indeed,
remain--at least some signs that elements of the managerial class, who
had lived off the earnings of finance capital for years, had become
annoyed and may become somewhat more radical. In the present context,
though, it is more difficult to discern what, if anything, may come of
this.
In my case, since I've always been interested in urbanisation,
and have always worked far more experientially with urban social
movements than labour movements, I have often had to confront the
commentary from Marxist colleagues that I am not really working with the
revolutionary proletariat. Over time, I have always said that there is
as much revolutionary potential in an urban social movement concerned
with affordable housing as there is in a labour union--I don't see
one as more revolutionary than the other. In turn, I have increasingly
come to agitate in terms of questions of the role of the city and
redefining the proletariat in terms of all those people who produce and
reproduce urban life. Under these circumstances, we would be in a
position to explain the significance of something like the Paris
Commune, the significance of the movements arising in Buenos Aires and
so forth. Indeed, if you look back at the urban history of capitalism in
the USA, you will see urban riots frequently taking place. So, why not
look on such movements as part of a rebel history which can be
recuperated and articulated by the left as being at the centre of its
political concerns, rather than being marginalised so that a dichotomy
is drawn between urban social movements and the revolutionary vanguard
of the proletariat? This is an unfortunate way of thinking about
things--in the US, much of the revolutionary vanguard has disappeared
over to China and so is diminished in terms of its power and
significance. In the current context, as I alluded to in answering your
previous question, we need to begin to exercise our right to the city.
And the only way in which we are really going to be able to exert the
right to the city is to take control of the capitalist surplus
absorption problem. The capital surplus needs to be socialised and we
must transcend the problem of 3% accumulation forever.
So, for me, labour--particularly organised labour--is only one part
of the whole problem, and is only going to have a partial role in
addressing the current conjuncture. The reason for this harks back to
Marx's shortcomings in how he established the political economic
problem to be resolved. Consider, for instance, how the development of
what I call a 'state-finance nexus' constitutes a core element
in shaping the dynamics of capitalism. Now consider what social forces
have been at work in establishing or contesting these institutional
arrangements--labour has never been at the forefront of that struggle.
Rather, it has been at the forefront in struggles over the labour
process and in labour market. Of course, these are critical moments in
the circulation process; yet most of the struggles which have gone on
over the state-finance nexus are populist struggles in which labour has
only been partially present. The most obvious example, of course, is
that many of the current struggles taking place in Latin America are
more populist than labour led--those contesting the privatisation of
natural resources and corporate control of agriculture, for instance.
Obviously, this is not to dismiss the importance of labour, which always
has a very important role to play in achieving transformational
political economic change. However, the conventional view of the
proletariat being the vanguard of struggle is not very helpful in the
current context when it is the architecture of the state-finance
nexus--as the central nervous system of capital accumulation--that is
the central issue. There may be contexts in which proletarian movements
may be highly significant, such as in China where I envisage them
playing a fundamental role which I do not see being replicated in
countries such as the US.
DP: Finally, I wanted to ask you about the role you see for the
state in addressing the ongoing crisis. There is a divide in
contemporary progressive political economy between those positing that
the state is necessary as a political counter to the economistic drive
of neoliberalism, while others see the state as the root of the current
impasse and call for greater political decentralisation. As you argue in
A Brief History of Neoliberalism, the former focuses on neoliberalism at
the level of theory and fails to recognise the political force central
to the neoliberal project. In the case of the latter, you note in Rebel
Cities that 'Decentralization and autonomy are primary vehicles for
producing greater inequality through neoliberalization.' What role,
therefore, do you see for the state in promoting progressive
alternatives--both to contemporary neoliberalism and the systemic
contradictions of capitalism?
DH: I think you're right. In particular, many thinkers on the
left assume that capturing state power has little significance in
achieving political transformations. I think this is a crazy position.
Here in the US, in particular, there is quite a marked anarchist
political thread running through the left and, while sympathetic to many
anarchist views, I feel that their seemingly perennial complaints about
and refusal to utilise the state is more obstructive than productive as
a political project. Great power is located in the state as an
institution and it cannot simply be ignored as though it doesn't
matter. In particular, I am quite sceptical of the increasingly
pervasive belief that civil society organisations and NGOs are likely to
change the world--not because these institutions are powerless or
worthless, but rather, as we've just discussed, because it is
necessary to adopt a different form of political movement and conception
of the nature of power relations in contemporary capitalism if we are
going to have any impact on the ongoing crisis.
So, the first step we need to take is to disaggregate what
constitutes 'the state'. It is not a monolithic institution.
There is a core of the state which is foundational to capitalism and how
it works--that is, the 'state-finance nexus'. Right now, the
Federal Reserve and the Treasury constitute this nexus in the USA.
Consider, for instance, how following the collapse of Lehmann Brothers,
it was Ben Bernanke and Hank Paulson who appeared on television to
explain to the world what had happened and what needed to be done moving
forward, rather than the President. More broadly, sovereignty over and
management of the money supply is crucial to capital. One of the great
powers of the state is its monopoly over money. The state has two great
forms of monopolistic power, as Max Weber discussed: that over violence
and over currency. When monopoly over currency is challenged, as
occurred in Russia, for instance, large sections of the economy operated
on barter, the Ruble disappeared and state power vanished. This was a
good way to make the state wither away: shift to a barter economy! In
turn, there was a great struggle to regain control over the money
supply. So, this aspect of the state is so tightly bound with capital
that it seems to have no progressive capacities within it--if you want
to smash elements of the state, this is what should be targeted.
On the other hand, there are other aspects of the state which are
managing important things. Consider the air traffic control system.
Would you want to smash this? What about municipal sewer or water
Systems--should these be smashed? In other words, there are elements of
the state that deliver important use-values to people. It is a
collective way of delivering these use-values which, in the past, has
not been neoliberalised--part of the neoliberal project has been to
subsume greater chunks of the state, so that public services education,
healthcare and water provision have become privatised. In turn, I think
that there are aspects of the state such as these that I would like to
see turned back into public utilities at worst and, at best,
publicly-supplied free goods to the population. I think education and
health-care should be freely provided. Even Hardt and Negri suggest that
everyone should have a guaranteed minimum income. In fact, they provide
an interesting example, as their works simultaneously call for smashing
the state as well as its provision of public services.
In turn, when discussing the state, my point is that we are
discussing different potentialities in different parts of the state
apparatus in terms of what could be taken-over, recuperated and utilised
for more public purposes. Even in a situation where the anarchist vision
of communes were set up, some form of institution would be established
concerned with elaborating on territorial-administrative structures
which would resemble a state. Thus, there is no avoiding an institution
of this kind. My approach to the state, in turn, is consequently rather
pragmatic in that I argue that there exists a certain core of the state
that is totally embedded in the processes of capital accumulation--the
'state-financial nexus' that I referred to earlier. Many other
aspects of the state are also embedded in capital accumulation, such as
the military-industrial-complex, that should be challenged. Other
aspects relating to the state's monopoly on violence must also be
addressed, such as the increasingly omnipresent systems of surveillance
and recently augmented police power. Yet, there are other aspects of the
state concerned with public provision of goods to the community as a
whole that I would like to see preserved and enhanced, because you can
see what happens when these goods are not delivered particularly in the
context of the aftermath of Hurricane Sandy here in New York, where
electricity, water and sewage have not been readily available. Thus, I
do not think it is helpful to get into questions about whether one is
for or against the state: it is more important to consider those pieces
that should be preserved and utilised and those that should be abolished
because they are at the heart of endless processes of capital
accumulation.
The interviewer, David Primrose, is a postgraduate research student
in the Department of Political Economy at the University of Sydney.
david.primrose@sydney.edu.au
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]