American poverty as a structural failing: evidence and arguments.
Hirschl, Thomas A.
Empirical research on American poverty has largely focused on
individual characteristics to explain the occurrence and patterns of
poverty. The argument in this article is that such an emphasis is
misplaced. By focusing upon individual attributes as the cause of
poverty, social scientists have largely missed the underlying dynamic of
American impoverishment. Poverty researchers have in effect focused on
who loses out at the economic game, rather than addressing the fact that
the game produces losers in the first place. We provide three lines of
evidence to suggest that U.S. poverty is ultimately the result of
structural failings at the economic, political, and social levels. These
include an analysis into the lack of sufficient jobs in the economy to
raise families out of poverty or near poverty; a comparative examination
into the high rates of U.S. poverty as a result of the ineffectiveness of the social safety net; and the systemic nature of poverty as
indicated by the life course risk of impoverishment experienced by a
majority of Americans. We then briefly outline a framework for
reinterpreting American poverty. This perspective incorporates the prior
research findings that have focused on individual characteristics as
important factors in who loses out at the economic game, with the
structural nature of American poverty that ensures the existence of
economic losers in the first place.
Keywords: American poverty, low wages, U.S. economy, social
welfare, human capital, social structure
**********
Few questions have generated as much discussion across time as that
of the causes of human impoverishment. The sources and origins of
poverty have been debated for centuries. As the historian R. M. Hartwell
notes, "The causes of poverty, its relief and cure, have been a
matter of serious concern to theologians, statesmen, civil servants,
intellectuals, tax-payers and humanitarians since the Middle Ages"
(1986: 16). The question of causality has found itself at the heart of
most debates surrounding poverty and the poor.
In recent times these debates have often been divided into two
ideological camps. On one hand, poverty has been viewed as the result of
individual failings. From this perspective, specific attributes of the
impoverished individual have brought about their poverty. These include
a wide set of characteristics, ranging from the lack of an industrious
work ethic or virtuous morality, to low levels of education or
competitive labor market skills. On the other hand, poverty has
periodically been interpreted as the result of failings at the
structural level, such as the inability of the economy to produce enough
decent paying jobs.
Within the United States, the dominant perspective has been that of
poverty as an individual failing. From Ben Franklin's Poor
Richard's Almanac to the recent welfare reform changes, poverty has
been conceptualized primarily as a consequence of individual failings
and deficiencies. Indeed, social surveys asking about the causes of
poverty have consistently found that Americans tend to rank individual
reasons (such as laziness, lack of effort, and low ability) as the most
important factors related to poverty, while structural reasons such as
unemployment or discrimination are viewed as significantly less
important (Feagin, 1975; Gilens, 1999; Kluegel and Smith, 1986).
This emphasis on individual attributes as the primary cause of
poverty has also been reinforced by social scientists engaged in poverty
research (O'Connor, 2001). As the social survey has become the
dominant methodological approach during the past 50 years, and with
multivariate modeling becoming the principal statistical technique, the
research emphasis has increasingly fallen on understanding poverty and
welfare dependency in terms of individual attributes. The unit of
analysis in these studies is by definition the individual rather than
the wider social or economic structures, resulting in statistical models
of individual characteristics predicting individual behavior.
Consequently, the long standing tension between structural versus
individual approaches to explaining poverty has largely been tilted within the empirical poverty research community towards that of the
individual. As Alice O'Connor writes,
That this tension has more often been resolved in favor of the
individualist interpretation can be seen in several oft-noted
features in poverty research. One is the virtual absence of class
as an analytic category, at least as compared with more
individualized measures of status such as family background and
human capital. A similar individualizing tendency can be seen in
the reduction of race and gender to little more than demographic,
rather than structurally constituted, categories (2001: 9).
The argument in this article is that such an emphasis is misplaced
and misdirected. By focusing on individual attributes as the cause of
poverty, social scientists have largely missed the underlying dynamic of
American impoverishment. Poverty researchers have in effect focused on
who loses out at the economic game, rather than addressing the fact that
the game produces losers in the first place. An analysis into this
underlying dynamic is critical to advancing our state of knowledge
regarding American poverty.
Of course, not all social scientists have abandoned the importance
of structural considerations with respect to poverty. The work of
William Ryan (1971), Michael Katz (1989), Herbert Gans (1995), Douglass
Massey (1996) and Joe Feagin (2000) come to mind. However, it should not
be a surprise that most of these scholars have taken a theoretical or
historical approach, rather than a statistical one. There is a need to
articulate the quantitative evidence supporting the argument that U.S.
poverty is ultimately the result of structural failings at the economic,
political, and social levels.
Current Understanding of American Poverty
The current research emphasis upon understanding American poverty
has largely focused on the individual and demographic characteristics of
the poor. These characteristics have, in turn, been used to explain why
particular individuals and households experience poverty. This approach
has revealed the extent to which the risk of poverty varies across
particular individual and household attributes.
Repeated cross-sectional national surveys such as the Current
Population Survey have indicated that the likelihood of poverty varies
sharply with respect to age, race, gender, family structure, and
residence. For example, the U.S. Census Bureau (2003a) reports that
while the overall U.S. poverty rate in 2002 was 12.1 percent, it was
16.7 percent for children and for those residing in central cities, 24.1
percent for African Americans, and 28.8 percent for persons in female
headed households. Other demographic characteristics closely associated
with the risk of poverty include giving birth outside of marriage,
families with larger numbers of children, and having children at an
early age (Maynard, 1997).
In addition, cross-sectional research has shown a close association
between human capital characteristics and an individual's risk of
poverty--those who are lacking in human capital are much more likely to
experience poverty than individuals with greater levels of human
capital. Specifically, lower levels of education, less marketable work
skills and experience, and having a physical disability that interferes
with an individual's ability to participate in the labor market are
all highly correlated with an elevated risk of poverty (Blank, 1997;
Schiller, 2004). On the other hand, research comparing the attitudes and
motivation of the poor versus the non-poor, have found relatively few
differences between these two groups (Goodwin, 1973; 1983; Lichter and
Crowley, 2002; Rank, 1994; Seccombe, 1999) and little in the way of
their being a causal factor leading to poverty (Duncan, 1984; Edwards et
al., 2001).
Longitudinal studies examining the dynamics of poverty have
addressed the length of time and particular factors related to a spell
of poverty. This body of work indicates that most spells of poverty are
of modest length. The typical pattern is that households are
impoverished for one, two, or three years, and then manage to get above
the poverty line (Bane and Ellwood, 1986; Blank, 1997; Duncan, 1984;
Walker, 1994). They may stay there for a period of time, only to
experience an additional fall into poverty at some later point. For
example, Stevens (1994; 1999) calculated that of all persons who had
managed to get themselves above the poverty line, over half would return
to poverty within five years. Since their economic distance above the
poverty threshold is often modest, a detrimental economic or social
event can push a household back below the poverty line.
Longitudinal research has also focused on the nature of such events
and individual changes that result in a spell of poverty (Devine and
Wright, 1993; Duncan, 1984; Walker, 1994). The most important of these
have been the loss of employment and earnings, along with changes in
family structure. For example, using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics
(PSID) data, Duncan et al. (1995) found that two thirds of all entries
into poverty were associated with either a reduction in work (48
percent) or the loss of work (18 percent). Divorce and separation were
associated with triggering approximately 10 percent of all spells of
poverty. Blank (1997) found that employment and family structure changes
were also influential in ending spells of poverty. Two thirds of those
below the poverty line escaped impoverishment as a result of increases
in the individual earnings of family members or increases from other
sources of income, while the remaining third had their spells of poverty
end as a result of changes in family structure (such as marriage or a
child leaving the household). In addition, research has shown that
illness and incapacitation are also important factors contributing to
falls into poverty (Schiller, 2004).
A substantial body of work has also examined the dynamics of
welfare use and dependency. This research has shown that individuals
utilizing public assistance programs and who experience longer spells of
welfare are often at a distinct disadvantage vis-a-vis the labor market
(Bane and Ellwood, 1994; Boisjoly et al., 1998; Harris, 1996; Moffitt,
1992; Pavetti, 1992; Rank, 1988; Sandefur and Cook, 1998). Consequently,
those with work disabilities, low education, greater numbers of
children, and/or living in inner-city areas are more likely to
extensively utilize the welfare system. The results from these studies
largely mirror the findings that have been gathered regarding the length
and duration of poverty spells.
The above body of work has provided an important understanding into
who are the economic losers in American society. Yet at the same time it
has failed to address the question of why there are economic losers in
the first place? The premise of this article is that in order answer
this question, it is essential to analyze specific failings at the
structural level.
The Structural Nature of Poverty
Three lines of evidence are detailed in order to illustrate the
structural nature of poverty--1) the inability of the U.S. labor market
to provide enough decent paying jobs for all families to avoid poverty
or near poverty; 2) the ineffectiveness of American social policy to
reduce levels of poverty through governmental social safety net
programs; and 3) the fact that the majority of the population will
experience poverty during their adult lifetimes, indicative of the
systemic nature of U.S. poverty. Each of these lines of evidence are
intended to empirically illustrate that American poverty is by and large
the result of structural failures and processes.
The Inability of the Labor Market to Support All Families
Several of the pioneering large scale studies of poverty conducted
at the end of the 19'th and beginning of the 20'th century
focused heavily on the importance of labor market failings to explain
poverty. The work of Charles Booth (1892-1897), Seebohm Rowntree (1901),
Hull House (1895), Robert Hunter (1904), and W. E. B. DuBois (1899) all
emphasized the importance of inadequate wages, lack of jobs, and
unstable working conditions as a primary cause of poverty. For example,
Rowntree (1901) estimated that approximately 57 percent of individuals
in poverty were there as a direct result of labor market failures (low
wages, unemployment, irregularity of work).
Yet by the 1960's the emphasis had shifted from a critique of
the economic structure as a primary cause of poverty, to an analysis of
individual deficiencies (e.g., the lack of human capital) as the
underlying reason for poverty. As Timothy Bartik (2001) notes, U.S.
antipoverty policy has focused heavily on labor supply policies (e.g.
increasing individual's human capital or incentives to work through
welfare reform) rather than labor demand policies (increasing the number
and quality of jobs). As mentioned earlier, social scientific research
has reinforced this policy approach by focusing on individual
deficiencies to explain individual poverty.
Yet it can be demonstrated that irrespective of the specific
characteristics that Americans possess, there simply are not enough
decent paying jobs to support all of those (and their families) who are
looking for work. During the past 25 years the American economy has
increasingly produced larger numbers of low paying jobs, jobs that are
part-time, and jobs that are lacking in benefits (Seccombe, 2000). For
example, the Census Bureau estimated that the median hourly earning of
workers who were paid hourly wages in 2000 was $9.91, while at the same
time approximately three million Americans were working part-time as a
result of the lack of sufficient full-time work being available (U.S.
Census Bureau, 2001). In addition, 43.6 million Americans were lacking
in health insurance, largely because their employer did not provide such
benefits (U.S. Census Bureau, 2003b).
Studies analyzing the percentage of the U.S. workforce falling into
the low wage sector have shown that a much higher percentage of American
workers fall into this category when compared with their counterparts in
other developed countries. For example, Smeeding, Rainwater, and
Burtless (2000) found that 25 percent of all U.S. full-time workers
could be classified as working in low wage work (defined as earning less
than 65 percent of the national median earnings on full-time jobs). This
was by far the highest percentage of the countries analyzed, with the
overall average falling at 12.9 percent.
One of the reasons for this has been the fact that the minimum wage
has remained at low levels and has not been indexed to inflation.
Changes in the minimum wage must come through Congressional legislation.
This often leads to years going by before Congress acts to adjust the
minimum wage upward, causing it to lag further behind the cost of
living.
Beyond the low wages, part-time work, and lack of benefits, there
is also a mismatch between the actual number of available jobs and the
number of those who need them. Economists frequently discuss what is
known as a natural unemployment rate-that in order for a free market
economy to effectively function, a certain percentage of laborers need
to be out of work. For example, full employment would impede the ability
of employers to attract and hire workers, particularly within the low
wage sector. Consequently, a certain degree of unemployment appears
systematic within a capitalist economy, irrespective of the individual
characteristics possessed by those participating in that economy.
During the past 40 years, U.S. monthly unemployment rates have
averaged between 4 and 10 percent (U.S. Census Bureau, 2001). These
percentages represent individuals who are out of work but are actively
looking for employment. In 2001 this translated into nearly 7 million
people unemployed at any particular point in time throughout the year,
while over 15 million people experienced unemployment at some point
during the year (Schiller, 2004). Certainly some of these individuals
have voluntarily left their jobs in order to locate another job (known
as frictional unemployment), while in other cases the unemployed may
include individuals whose family's are not dependent upon their job
for its economic survival , such as teenagers looking for summer work.
Nevertheless, a good proportion of unemployment is the result of
involuntary reasons, such as layoffs and downsizing, directly affecting
millions of heads of households.
Bartik (2001; 2002) used several different approaches and
assumptions to estimate the number of jobs that would be needed to
significantly address the issue of poverty in the United States. Data
were analyzed from the 1998 Current Population Survey. His conclusion?
Even in the booming economy of the late 1990's, between five and
nine million more jobs were needed in order to meet the needs of the
poor and disadvantaged.
The structural failing of the labor market to support the pool of
labor that currently exists can be further illustrated through an
analysis of the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP). The
SIPP is a large ongoing longitudinal study that interviews households
every four months over the course of three or four years, gathering
detailed monthly information regarding individual's employment and
income across these periods of time. It allows one to map the patterns
of labor force participation for a large nationally representative
sample (for an in-depth discussion of the history, methodology, and
specific details of the SIPP data set, see Westat, 2001).
An analysis of the SIPP illustrates the mismatch between the number
of jobs in the labor market that will enable a family to subsist above
the threshold of poverty, versus the number of heads of families in need
of such jobs. Table 1 is based upon the jobs and work behavior of family
heads across all 12 months of 1999. From this we can estimate the annual
number of hours worked, the annual amount of pay received, and whether
such earnings were sufficient to raise a family above the poverty line.
The analysis is confined to heads of families who are between the ages
of 18 and 64.
In Table 1, we examine whether the jobs that family heads were
working at during the year were able to get their current families out
of poverty. Three poverty thresholds are examined-below 1.00 (the
official poverty line); below 1.25 of the poverty line (the official
poverty line raised by 25 percent); and below 1.50 of the poverty line
(the official poverty line raised by 50 percent). To illustrate, the
poverty line for a family of 4 in 1999 was $17,029. Consequently the
1.25 poverty threshold for this family would be $21,286, while the 1.50
poverty threshold would be $25,544. These thresholds provide us with
several alternative levels of poverty and near poverty.
Our focus is on the availability of jobs in the labor market to
lift various families out of poverty. We examine this question for three
different populations of family heads who are in the labor market. The
first panel focuses only on those heads of families who are working
full-time throughout the year (defined as averaging 35 or more hours per
week across the 52 weeks of the year). The second panel includes those
working full-time as well as those who are working at least half-time
throughout the year (defined as working an average of 20 or more hours
per week across 52 weeks). The third panel includes all heads of
families in the labor market (defined as any head of family who has
either worked at some point during the year or who has been actively
looking for work).
For those employed full-time during 1999, 9.4 percent are working
in jobs where their annual earnings will not get their families above
the poverty line, 15.3 percent are at jobs in which their earnings will
not get their families above 1.25 of the poverty line, and 22.0 percent
are employed at jobs that will not get their families above 1.50 of the
poverty line. We can clearly see that the jobs one parent family heads
are working at are much less able to sustain these households above the
level of poverty than that for all families. On the other hand, single
men and women are more likely to be able to lift themselves out of
poverty through their work. Married couples fall in between these two
family types (it should be kept in mind that for these couples, we are
only focusing on the ability of the family head's job to lift the
household above the threshold of poverty, rather than the earnings of
both partners).
The middle panel illustrates that if we include family heads who
are working either full-time or at least half-time throughout the year,
nearly 15 percent were working at jobs in which their income would not
raise their families above the poverty line, 21.4 percent were at jobs
that would not get their families over 1.25 of the poverty line, while
28 percent fell below 1.50 of the poverty line. Finally, the bottom
panel includes all family heads that were in the labor market at some
point during the year. Here we can see that the percentages for the
three poverty thresholds are 20.3, 26.5, and 32.7.
Consequently, depending on the level of poverty and the size of the
pool of labor, the failure of the labor market to raise families out of
poverty ranges from 9.4 percent (utilizing the official poverty line for
those working full-time) to 32.7 percent (applying 1.50 of the poverty
line for all who are in the labor market). To use an analogy that will
be developed later, the supply of jobs versus the demand for labor might
be thought of as an ongoing game of musical chairs. That is, there is a
finite number of jobs available in the labor market that pay enough to
support a family above the threshold of poverty (which might be thought
of as the chairs in this analogy). On the other hand, the amount of
labor, as represented by the number of family heads in the labor market
(and hence the players in the game), is greater than the number of
adequately paying jobs. As indicated in Table 1, this imbalance ranges
from 9.4 percent to 32.7 percent. Consequently, the structure of the
labor market basically ensures that some families will lose out at this
musical chairs game of finding a decent paying job able to lift a family
above the threshold of poverty.
Table 2 illustrates this in a slightly different fashion. Here we
estimate the earnings capacity of jobs held by family heads to support
various hypothetical family sizes above our three different thresholds
of poverty. What is clear from this table is that for the pool of family
heads who are working full-time, the jobs that they are employed at are
quite able to support a one or two person family above the official
poverty line. For example, only 2.4 percent are in full-time jobs in
which their earnings would not raise a one person family above the
official poverty line, while 4.7 percent of family heads are working at
jobs that would not raise a family of two above the poverty line.
However, as we look at the ability of such jobs to get larger sized
families above the thresholds of poverty, we can see their increasing
failure to do so. Consequently, 15 percent of these jobs will not raise
a family of four above 1.00 of the poverty line. At the 1.25 level the
figure is 25.1 percent, and at the 1.50 level it is 36 percent. Thus,
the current supply of full-time jobs in the labor market would appear
able to lift most one or two person families out of poverty, but it
becomes much less effective in raising moderate sized families out of
poverty. As we include family heads who are working at least half-time
(the middle panel of Table 2) or who are in the labor market (the bottom
panel of Table 2) the percentages rise significantly.
Finally, we can illustrate this in yet another manner. Using the
SIPP data again for 1999, we estimated the annual average hourly wages
for heads of families. This analysis indicates that 12.1 percent of
family heads were working at jobs which paid an average of less than 6
dollars an hour, 21.2 percent worked at jobs paying less than 8 dollars
an hour, 31.7 percent worked at jobs paying less than 10 dollars an
hour, and 42.7 percent were earning less than 12 dollars an hour. In
order to raise a family of three above the official poverty line in 1999
one would have to be working full-time (defined as averaging 35 hours
per week across the 52 weeks of the year) at $7.30 an hour, and for a
family of four the figure would be $9.36 an hour.. The fact that nearly
one third of family heads are working at jobs paying less than $10.00 an
hour, is indicative of the significant risk of poverty that they face.
To summarize, the data presented in this section indicates that a
major factor leading to poverty in the United States is a failing of the
economic structure to provide viable opportunities for all who are
participating in that system. In particular, the labor market simply
does not provide enough decent paying jobs for all who need them. As a
result, millions of families find themselves struggling below or
precariously close to the poverty line.
The Ineffectiveness of the Social Safety Net to Prevent Poverty
A second major structural failure is found at the political level.
Contrary to the popular rhetoric of vast amounts of tax dollars being
spent on public assistance, the American welfare state, and particularly
its social safety net, can be more accurately described in minimalist terms (Esping-Andersen, 1990). Compared to other Western industrialized countries, the United States devotes far fewer resources to programs
aimed at assisting the economically vulnerable (Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development, 1999). As Charles Noble writes,
"The U .S. welfare state is striking precisely because it is so
limited in scope and ambition" (1997: 3).
On the other hand, most European countries provide a wide range of
social and insurance programs that largely prevent families from falling
into poverty. These include substantial family or children's
allowances, designed to transfer cash assistance to families with
children. Unemployment assistance is far more generous in these
countries than in the United States, often providing support for more
than a year following the loss of a job. Furthermore, universal health
coverage is routinely provided, along with considerable support for
child care.
The result of these social policy differences is that they
substantially reduce the extent of poverty in Europe and Canada, while
U.S. social policy has had only a small impact upon poverty reduction.
As Rebecca Blank notes, "the national choice in the United States
to provide relatively less generous transfers to low-income families has
meant higher relative poverty rates in the country. While low-income
families in the United States work more than in many other countries,
they are not able to make up for lower governmental income support
relative to their European counterparts" (Blank, 1997: 141-142).
This effect can be clearly seen in Table 3. The data in this table
are based upon an analysis of the Luxembourg Income Study (LIS)
conducted by Veli-Matti Ritakallio (2001). Initiated in the 1980s, the
LIS contains income and demographic information on households in over 25
different nations from 1967 to the present. Variables have been
standardized across 70 data sets, allowing researchers to conduct
cross-national analyses regarding poverty and the effectiveness of
governmental programs in alleviating such poverty (for further detail
regarding the LIS, see Luxembourg Income Study, 2000). Poverty in this
analysis is defined as being in a household in which its disposable
income is less than one half of the median annual income.
Table 3 compares eight European countries and Canada with the
United States in terms of their pre-transfer and post-transfer rates of
poverty. The pre-transfer rates (column one) indicate what the level of
poverty would be in each country in the absence of any governmental
income transfers such as welfare payments, unemployment compensation, or
social security payments. The post-transfer rates (column two) represent
the level of poverty after governmental transfers are included (which is
how poverty is officially measured in the United States and many other
countries). In-kind benefits such as medical insurance are not included
in the analysis. Comparing these two levels of poverty (column three)
reveals how effective (or ineffective) governmental policy is in
reducing the overall extent of poverty in a country.
Looking first at the rates of pre-transfer poverty, we can see that
the United States is on the lower end of the scale. Norway's
pre-transfer poverty rate is 27 percent, followed by the United States,
Canada, and Germany at 29 percent. The Netherlands pre-transfer rate is
30 percent, Finland stands at 33 percent, Sweden is at 36 percent, the
United Kingdom rate is 38 percent, and finally, France possesses the
highest level of pre-transfer poverty at 39 percent.
When we examine the post-transfer rates of poverty found in column
two, a dramatic reversal takes place in terms of where the United States
stands vis-a-vis the comparison countries. The average post-transfer
poverty rate for the eight comparison countries in Table 3 is 7 percent,
whereas the United States' post-transfer poverty rate stands at 18
percent. As a result of their more active social policies, Canada and
the European countries are able to significantly cut their overall rates
of poverty. For example, Sweden is able to reduce the number of people
that would be poor (in the absence of any governmental help) by 92
percent as a result of social policies. The overall average reduction
factor for the eight countries is 79 percent. In contrast, the United
States poverty reduction factor is only 38 percent (with much of this
being the result of Social Security).
Table 3 clearly illustrates a second major structural failing
leading to the high rates of U.S. poverty. It is a failure at the
political and policy level. Specifically, social and economic programs
directed to the economically vulnerable populations in the United States
are minimal in their ability to raise families out of poverty. While
America has always been a "reluctant welfare state," the past
25 years have witnessed several critical retrenchments and reductions in
the social safety net. These reductions have included scaling back both
the amount of benefits being transferred, as well as a tightening of
program eligibility (Noble, 1997; Patterson, 2000). In addition, the
United States has failed to offer the type of universal coverage for
child care, medical insurance, or child allowances that most other
developed countries routinely provide. As a result, the overall U.S.
poverty rates remain at extremely high levels.
Once again, this failure has virtually nothing to do with the
individual. Rather it is emblematic of a failure at the structural
level. By focusing on individual characteristics, we lose sight of the
fact that governments can and do exert a sizeable impact on reducing the
extent of poverty within their jurisdictions. In the analysis presented
here, Canada and Europe are able to lift a significant percentage of
their economically vulnerable above the threshold of poverty through
governmental transfer and assistance policies. In contrast, the United
States provides substantially less support through its social safety
net, resulting in poverty rates that are currently the highest in the
industrialized world.
The one case where the U.S. has effectively reduced the rate of
poverty for a particular group has been that of the elderly. Their
substantial reduction in the risk of poverty over the past 40 years has
been directly attributed to the increasing generosity of the Social
Security program, as well as the introduction of Medicare in 1965 and
the Supplemental Security Income Program in 1974. During the 1960's
and 1970's, Social Security benefits were substantially increased
and indexed to the rate of inflation, helping many of the elderly escape
from poverty. It is estimated today that without the Social Security
program, the poverty rate for the elderly would be close to 50 percent
(rather than its current 10 percent). Put another way, Social Security
is responsible for getting 80 percent of the elderly above the poverty
line who would otherwise be poor in its absence.
The Widespread Life Course Risk of Poverty
A third approach revealing the structural nature of American
poverty can be found in a life course analysis of poverty. As discussed
earlier, previous work on poverty has examined the cross-sectional and
spell dynamic risk. Yet there is another way in which the incidence of
poverty can be examined. Such an approach places the risk of poverty
within the context of the American life course. By doing so, the
systematic nature of American poverty can be revealed.
The work of Rank and Hirschl (1999a; 1999b; 1999c; 2001a; 2001b)
has developed this approach. Building upon the longitudinal design of
the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, Rank and Hirschl have utilized a
technique for constructing a series of life tables estimating the
probability that Americans will experience poverty at some point during
their adulthood (see Rank and Hirschl, 2001c, for a more detailed
description of their methodology and approach, and Hill, 1992, for a
further discussion of the PSID).
Table 4 is based upon three separate life tables estimating the age
specific and cumulative probabilities of experiencing poverty between
the ages of 20 and 75 for the following poverty thresholds--1.00 (the
official poverty line); 1.25 (the poverty line raised by 25 percent),
and 1.50 (the poverty line raised by 50 percent). Table 4 reports the
cumulative percentages of the American population that will encounter
poverty at various points of adulthood.
At age 20 (the starting point of the analysis), we can see that
10.6 percent of Americans fell below the poverty line (which is similar
to the cross-sectional rate of poverty for 20 year olds), with 15
percent falling below the 1.25 threshold and 19.1 percent falling below
the 1.50 threshold. By the age of 35, the percent of Americans
experiencing poverty has increased sharply--31.4 percent of Americans
have experienced at least one year below the poverty line; 39 percent
have experienced at least one year below 1.25 of the poverty line; and
46.9 percent have experienced a year below 1.50 of the poverty line. At
age 55 the percentages stand at 45.0, 52.8, and 61.0, and by the age of
75, they have risen to 58.5 percent, 68 percent and 76 percent.
What these numbers indicate is that a clear majority of Americans
will at some point experience poverty during their lifetimes. Rather
than an isolated event that occurs only among what has been labeled the
"underclass," the reality is that the majority of Americans
will encounter poverty firsthand during their adulthoods.
Such patterns illuminate the systematic essence of American
poverty, which in turn points to the structural nature of poverty.
Occasionally we can physically see widespread examples of this. For
instance, the economic collapse during the Great Depression of the
1930's. Given the enormity of this collapse, it became clear to
many Americans that most of their neighbors were not directly
responsible for the dire economic situation they found themselves in.
This awareness helped provide much of the impetus and justification
behind the New Deal (Patterson, 2000).
Similarly, the existence of the "other" America as noted
by Michael Harrington (1962) during the early 1960's, pointed again
to the widespread nature of U.S. poverty. The other America was
represented by the extremely high rates of poverty found in economically
depressed areas such as rural Appalachia and the urban inner city. The
War on Poverty during the 1960's was an attempt to address these
large scale structural pockets of poverty amidst plenty.
The analysis in this section indicates that poverty may be as
widespread and systematic today as in these more visible examples. Yet
we have been unable to see this as a result of not looking in the right
direction. By focusing on the life span risks, the prevalent nature of
American poverty is revealed. At some point during adulthood, the bulk
of Americans will face impoverishment. The approach of emphasizing
individual failings or attributes as the primary cause of poverty loses
much of its explanatory power in the face of such patterns. Rather,
given the widespread occurrence of economic vulnerability, a life span
analysis points to a third line of evidence indicating that poverty is
more appropriately viewed as a structural failing of American society.
As C. Wright Mills notes in his analysis of unemployment,
When, in a city of 100,000, only one man is unemployed, that is his
personal trouble, and for its relief we properly look to the
character of the man, his skills, and his immediate opportunities.
But when in a nation of 50 million employees, 15 million men are
unemployed, that is an issue, and we may not hope to find its
solution within the range of opportunities open to any one
individual. The very structure of opportunities has collapsed. Both
the correct statement of the problem and the range of possible
solutions require us to consider the economic and political
institutions of the society, and not merely the personal situation
and character of a scatter of individuals (1959: 9).
To summarize, three lines of evidence have been detailed suggesting
that American poverty is primarily the result of structural conditions.
These include a lack of sufficient paying jobs in the labor market, the
ineffectiveness of America's social safety net to pull individuals
and families out of poverty, and the fact that a clear majority of
Americans will experience poverty at some point during their adulthood
years. Other structural failings could have been explored as well (e.g.,
the inequities in educational quality in the United States, the
systematic lack of political power for the economically disenfranchised,
or the widespread patterns of racial residential segregation, to name
but a few). Nevertheless, the lines of evidence discussed in this
section would appear particularly illuminating in revealing the
structural nature of American poverty.
Discussion
Given the above arguments and evidence indicating that American
poverty is primarily the result of structural failings, how might we
reconcile this perspective with the earlier discussed research findings
indicating that human capital and individual attributes largely explain
who is at risk of experiencing poverty? An approach that bridges the
empirical importance of individual attributes with the significance of
structural forces has been the concept of structural vulnerability
(Rank, 1994; 2000; 2001; 2004). This framework recognizes that human
capital and other labor market attributes are associated with who loses
out at the economic game (and hence will be more likely to experience
poverty), but that structural factors predominately ensure that there
will be losers in the first place.
An analogy can be used to illustrate the basic concept. Imagine a
game of musical chairs in which there are ten players but only eight
chairs. On one hand, individual success or failure in the game depends
on the skill and luck of each player. Those who are less agile or less
well placed when the music stops are more likely to lose. These are
appropriately cited as the reasons a particular individual has lost the
game. On the other hand, given that there are only eight chairs
available, two players are bound to lose regardless of their
characteristics. Even if all the players were suddenly to double their
speed and agility, there would still be two losers. From this broader
context, the characteristics of the individual players are no longer
important in terms of understanding that the structure of the game
ensures that someone must inevitably lose.
We would argue that this analogy applies with respect to poverty.
For every ten American households, there are good jobs and opportunities
at any point in time to adequately support roughly eight of those ten.
The remaining two households will be locked out of such opportunities,
often resulting in poverty or near poverty. Individuals experiencing
such economic deprivation are likely to have characteristics putting
them at a disadvantage in terms of competing in the economy (lower
education, fewer skills, single-parent families, illness or
incapacitation, minorities residing in inner cities, etc.). These
characteristics help to explain why particular individuals and
households are at a greater risk of poverty.
However, given the earlier discussed structural failures, a certain
percentage of the American population will experience economic
vulnerability regardless of what their characteristics are. As in the
musical chairs analogy, increasing everyone's human capital will do
little to alter the fact that there are only so many decent paying jobs
available. In such a case, employers will simply raise the bar in terms
of the employee qualifications they are seeking, but nevertheless there
will remain a percentage of the population at risk of economic
deprivation. Consequently, although a lack of human capital and its
accompanying vulnerability leads to an understanding of who the losers
of the economic game are likely to be, the structural components of our
economic, social, and political systems explain why there are losers in
the first place.
The critical mistake that has been made in the past has been that
social scientists have frequently equated the question of who loses out
at the game, with the question of why the game produces losers in the
first place. They are, in fact, distinct and separate questions. While
deficiencies in human capital and other marketable characteristics help
to explain who in the population is at a heightened risk of encountering
poverty, the fact that poverty exists in the first place results not
from these characteristics, but from the lack of decent opportunities
and supports in society. By focusing solely upon individual
characteristics, such as education, we can shuffle people up or down in
terms of their being more likely to land a job with good earnings, but
we are still going to have somebody lose out if there are not enough
decent paying jobs to go around. In short, we are playing a large scale
version of a musical chairs game with ten players but only eight chairs.
The recognition of this dynamic represents a fundamental shift in
thinking from the old paradigm. It helps to explain why the social
policies of the past two decades have largely been ineffective in
reducing the rates of poverty. We have focused our attention and
resources on either altering the incentives and disincentives for those
playing the game, or in a very limited way, upgrading their skills and
ability to compete in the game, while at the same time leaving the
structure of the game untouched.
When the overall poverty rates in the United States do in fact go
up or down, they do so primarily as a result of impacts on the
structural level that increase or decrease the number of available
chairs. In particular, the performance of the economy has been
historically important. Why? Because when the economy is expanding, more
opportunities (or chairs) are available for the competing pool of labor
and their families. The reverse occurs when the economy slows down and
contracts. Consequently, during the 1930's or early 1980's
when the economy was doing badly, poverty rates went up, while during
periods of economic prosperity such as the 1960's or the middle to
later 1990's, the overall rates of poverty declined.
Similarly, changes in various social supports and the social safety
net available to families will make a difference in terms of how well
such households are able to avoid poverty or near poverty. When such
supports were increased through the War on Poverty initiatives in the
1960's, poverty rates declined. Likewise, when Social Security
benefits were expanded during the 1960's and 1970's, the
elderly's poverty rates declined precipitously. Conversely, when
social supports have been weakened and eroded, as in the case of
children's programs over the past 25 years, their rates of poverty
have gone up.
The recognition of poverty as a result of the way the game is
structured also makes it quite clear why the United States has such high
rates of poverty when compared to other Western countries. These rates
have nothing to do with Americans being less motivated or less skilled
than those in other countries, but with the fact that our economy has
been producing a plethora of low wage jobs in the face of global
competition and that our social policies have done relatively little to
support families compared to our European neighbors. From this
perspective, one of the keys to addressing poverty is to increase the
labor market opportunities and social supports available to American
households.
The structural vulnerability perspective thus recognizes the
importance of human capital in being able to predict who is more likely
to experience economic deprivation, while at the same time emphasizing
the importance of structural constraints in guaranteeing that some
Americans will be left out of the economic mainstream. In short, the
structure of the American economy, accompanied by a weak social safety
net and public policies directed to the economically vulnerable, ensure
that a certain percentage of the American population will experience
impoverishment at any point in time, and that a much larger percentage
of the population will experience poverty over the course of a lifetime.
The fact that three quarters of Americans will experience poverty or
near poverty (at the 1.50 level) during their adulthoods is emblematic
of these structural level failings.
As noted at the beginning of this article, social scientists
investigating poverty have largely focused upon individual deficiencies
and demographic attributes in order to explain the occurrence of poverty
in America. As such, they have reinforced the mainstream American ethos of interpreting social problems as primarily the result of individual
failings. In addition, a culture of poverty perspective has occasionally
been used to explain the occurrence of poverty within specific
geographical settings such as inner cities or remote rural areas. This
approach also tends to largely place the dynamic of poverty within the
framework of individual deficiencies.
We have argued and attempted to demonstrate in this article that
such perspectives are misguided. Whereas individual attributes (such as
human capital) help to explain who faces a greater risk of experiencing
poverty at any point in time, the fact that substantial poverty exists
on a national level can only be understood through an analysis of the
structural dynamics of American society.
Table 1
Inability of the Labor Market to Support Various Family Structures
Above Different Poverty Thresholds
Current Family Status
Poverty All Married Couple One Parent Single
Threshold Families Families Families Families
Heads of Families Working Full-Time
Below 1.00 9.4 9.9 16.9 3.2
Below 1.25 15.3 16.0 26.4 6.6
Below 1.50 22.0 23.0 36.6 10.2
N 9,891 6,053 1,557 2,281
Heads of Families Working Half-Time or More
Below 1.00 14.9 13.5 27.7 9.5
Below 1.25 21.4 19.8 37.0 14.3
Below 1.50 28.0 26.7 46.5 18.3
N 11,312 6,623 1,969 2,720
Heads of Families in the Labor Market
Below 1.00 20.3 17.1 36.8 15.8
Below 1.25 26.5 23.3 44.9 20.4
Below 1.50 32.7 30.0 53.4 24.2
N 12,190 6,972 2,259 2,959
Source: Survey of Income and Program Participation, authors'
computations
Table 2
Inability of the Labor Market to Support Various Family Sizes Above
Different Poverty Thresholds
Hypothetical Family Size
1 2 3 4 5 6
Poverty Person Person Person Person Person Person
Threshold Family Family Family Family Family Family
Heads of Families Working Full-Time
Below 1.00 2.4 4.7 7.6 15.0 22.3 29.0
Below 1.25 4.3 8.9 14.0 25.1 35.0 42.4
Below 1.50 7.2 14.5 21.8 36.0 46.3 54.6
Heads of Families Working Half-Time or More
Below 1.00 6.3 10.2 13.8 21.6 28.9 35.3
Below 1.25 9.6 15.2 20.6 31.6 41.0 47.9
Below 1.50 13.2 21.1 28.3 42.0 51.6 59.3
Heads of Families in the Labor Market
Below 1.00 12.0 15.8 19.3 26.9 33.7 39.7
Below 1.25 15.3 20.8 25.9 36.3 45.0 51.5
Below 1.50 18.8 26.4 33.2 46.0 54.9 62.1
Source: Survey of Income and Program Participation, authors'
computations
Table 3
Comparative Analysis of Governmental Effectiveness in Reducing
Poverty Across Selected Countries
Pre-transfer Post-transfer Reduction
Country Poverty Rates Poverty Rates Factor
Canada (1994) 29 10 66
Finland (1995) 33 4 88
France (1994) 39 8 79
Germany (1994) 29 7 76
Netherlands (1994) 30 7 77
Norway (1995) 27 4 85
Sweden (1995) 36 3 92
United Kingdom (1995) 38 13 66
United States (1994) 29 18 38
Source: Luxembourg Income Study, adapted from Veli-Matti Ritakallio
(2001) computations
Table 4
The Cumulative Percent of Americans Experiencing Poverty Across
Adulthood
Level of Property
Age Below 1.00 Below 1.25 Below 1.50
Poverty Line Poverty Line Poverty Line
20 10.6 15.0 19.1
25 21.6 27.8 34.3
30 27.1 34.1 41.3
35 31.4 39.0 46.9
40 35.6 43.6 51.7
45 38.8 46.7 55.0
50 41.8 49.6 57.9
55 45.0 52.8 61.0
60 48.2 56.1 64.2
65 51.4 59.7 67.5
70 55.0 63.6 71.8
75 58.5 68.0 76.0
Source: Panel Study of Income Dynamics, authors' computations
References
Bane, M. J., & Ellwood, D. T. (1986). Slipping into and out of
poverty: The dynamics of spells. Journal of Human Resources, 21, 1-23.
Bane, M. J., & Ellwood, D. T. (1994). Welfare realities: From
rhetoric to reform. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Bartik, T. H. (2001). Jobs for the poor: Can labor demand policies
help? New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Bartik, T. H. (2002). Poverty, jobs, and subsidized employment.
Challenge, 45, 100-111.
Blank, R. M. (1997). It takes a nation: A new agenda for fighting
poverty. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Boisjoly, J., Harris, K. M., & Duncan, G. J. (1998). Trends,
events, and duration of initial welfare spells. Social Service Review,
72, 466-492.
Booth, C. (1892-97). Life and labour of the people of London, first
series: Poverty. London: Macmillan.
Devine, J. A., & Wright, J. D. (1993). The greatest of evils:
Urban poverty and the American underclass. New York: Aldine De Gruyter.
DuBois, W. E. B. (1899). The Philadelphia Negro. Philadelphia:
University of Pennsylvania Press.
Duncan, G. J. (1984). Years of poverty, years of plenty: The
changing economic fortunes of American workers and families. Ann Arbor,
MI: Institute for Social Research.
Duncan, G. J., Gustafsson, B., Hauser, R., Schmaus, G., Jenkins,
S., Messinger, H., Muffels, R., Nolan, B., Ray, J., & Voges, W.
(1995). Poverty and social-assistance dynamics in the United States,
Canada, and Europe. In K. McFate, R. Lawson, & W. J. Wilson (Eds.),
Poverty, inequality and the future of social policy: Western states in
the new world order (pp. 67-108). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Edwards, M. E., Plotnick, R., & Klawitter, M. (2001). Do
attitudes and personality characteristics affect socioeconomic outcomes?
The case of welfare use by young women. Social Science Quarterly, 82,
827-843.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Feagin, J. R. (1975). Subordinating the poor: Welfare and American
beliefs. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Feagin, J. R. (2000). Racist America: Roots, current realities, and
future reparations. New York: Routledge.
Gans, H. J. (1995). The war against the poor: The underclass and
antipoverty policy. New York: Basic Books.
Gilens, M. (1999). Why Americans hate welfare: Race, media, and the
politics of antipoverty policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Goodwin, L. (1972). Do the poor want to work? A
social-psychological study of work orientations. Washington, DC:
Brookings Institution.
Goodwin, L. (1983). Causes and cures of welfare: New evidence on
the social psychology. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Harrington, M. (1962). The other America: Poverty in the United
States. New York: Macmillan.
Harris, K. M. (1996). Life after welfare: Women, work, and repeat
dependency. American Sociological Review, 61, 407-426.
Hartwell, R. M. (1986). The long debate on poverty. Paper presented
at the Political Economy Seminar Series, Washington University, St.
Louis, Missouri.
Hill, M. S. (1992). The Panel Study of Income Dynamics: A
user's guide. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.
Hull House (1895). Hull House maps and papers. New York: Thomas Y.
Crowell.
Hunter, R. (1904). Poverty. New York: Macmillan.
Katz, M. B. (1989). The undeserving poor: From the war on poverty
to the war on welfare. New York: Pantheon Books.
Kluegel, J. R., & Smith, E. R. (1986). Beliefs about
inequality: Americans' views of what is and what ought to be. New
York: Aldine de Gruyter.
Lichter, D. T., & Crowley, M. L. (2002). Poverty in America:
Beyond welfare reform. Population Bulletin, 57, 1-36.
Luxembourg Income Study (2000). LIS quick reference guide.
Syracuse, NY: Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse
University.
Massey, D. S. (1996). The age of extremes: Concentrated affluence
and poverty in the twenty-first century. Demography, 33, 395-412.
Maynard, R. A. (1997). Kids having kids: Economic costs and social
consequences of teen pregnancy. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute
Press.
Mills, C. W. (1959). The sociological imagination. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Moffitt, R. (1992). Incentive effects of the U.S. welfare system: A
review. Journal of Economic Literature, 30, 1-61.
Noble, C. (1997). Welfare as we knew it: A political history of the
American welfare state. New York: Oxford University Press.
O'Connor, A. (2001). Poverty knowledge: Social science, social
policy, and the poor in twentieth-century U.S. history. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. (1999).
Social expenditure database 1980-1996. Paris: Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development.
Patterson, J. T. (2000). America's struggle against poverty in
the twentieth century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Pavetti, L. A. (1992). The dynamics of welfare and work: Exploring
the process by which young women work their way off welfare. Paper
presented at the APPAM Annual Research Conference, October, Denver,
Colorado.
Rank M. R. (1988). Racial differences in length of welfare use.
Social Forces, 66, 1080-1101.
Rank, M. R. (1994). Living on the edge: The realities of welfare in
America. New York: Columbia University Press.
Rank, M. R. (2000). Poverty and economic hardship in families. In
D. H. Demo, K. R. Allen, & M. A. Fine (Eds.), Handbook of family
diversity (pp. 293-315). New York: Oxford University Press.
Rank, M. R. (2001). The effect of poverty on America's
families: Assessing our research knowledge. Journal of Family Issues 22,
882-903.
Rank, M. R. (2004). One nation, underprivileged: Why American
poverty affects us all. New York: Oxford University Press.
Rank M. R., & Hirschl, T. A. (1999a). The likelihood of poverty
across the American adult life span. Social Work, 44, 201-216.
Rank, M. R., & Hirschl, T. A. (1999b). Estimating the
proportion of Americans ever experiencing poverty during their elderly
years. Journal of Gerontology: Social Sciences, 54B, S184-S193.
Rank, M. R., & Hirschl, T. A. (1999c). The economic risk of
childhood in America: Estimating the probability of poverty across the
formative years. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 61, 1058-1067.
Rank, M. R., & Hirschl, T. A. (2001a). The occurrence of
poverty across the life cycle: Evidence from the PSID. Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management, 20, 737-755.
Rank, M. R., & Hirschl, T. A. (2001b). Rags or riches?
Estimating the probabilities of poverty and affluence across the adult
American life span. Social Science Quarterly, 82, 651-669.
Rank, M. R., & Hirschl, T. A. (2001c). The measurement of long
term risks across the life course. Social Science Quarterly, 82,
680-686..
Ritakallio, V. M. (2001). Trends of poverty and income inequality
in cross-national comparison. Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper No.
272, Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse
University, Syracuse, New York.
Rowntree, B. S. (1901). Poverty: A study of town life. London:
Macmillan.
Ryan, W. (1971). Blaming the victim. New York: Pantheon Books.
Sandefur, G. D., & Cook, S. T. (1998). Permanent exits from
public assistance: The impact of duration, family, and work. Social
Forces, 77, 763-786.
Schiller, B. R. (2004). The economics of poverty and
discrimination. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Seccombe, K. (1999). So you think I drive a Cadillac? Welfare
recipients' perspectives on the system. Needham Heights, MA: Allyn
and Bacon.
Seccombe, K. (2000). Families in poverty in the 1990s: Trends,
causes, consequences, and lessons learned. Journal of Marriage and the
Family, 62, 1094-1113.
Smeeding, T. M., Rainwater, L., & Burtless, G. (2000). United
States poverty in a cross-national context. Luxembourg Income Study
Working Paper, No. 244, Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public
Affairs, Syracuse University, Syracuse, New York.
Stevens, A. H. (1994). The dynamics of poverty spells: Updating
Bane and Ellwood. American Economic Review, 84, 34-37.
Stevens, A. H. (1999). Climbing out of poverty, falling back in:
Measuring the persistence of poverty over multiple spells. The Journal
of Human Resources, 34, 557-588.
U.S. Bureau of the Census (2001). Statistical Abstract of the
United States: 2001 (121th edition.) Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Printing Office.
U.S. Bureau of the Census (2003a). Poverty in the United States:
2002. Current Population Reports, Series P60-222. Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Bureau of the Census (2003b). Health Insurance Coverage: 2002.
Current Population Reports, Series P60-223. Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office.
Walker, R. (1994). Poverty dynamics: Issues and examples.
Aldershot, England: Avebury.
Westat (2001). Survey of Income and Program Participation
Users' Guide, Third Edition. Rockville, MD: Westat.
MARK R. RANK
Washington University
George Warren Brown School of Social Work
HONG-SIK YOON
Chonbuk National University
Department of Social Welfare
THOMAS A. HIRSCHL
Cornell University
Department of Rural Sociology