Kazakhstan: long-term economic growth and the role of the oil sector.
Kalyuzhnova, Yelena ; Patterson, Kerry
INTRODUCTION
Over the last 10 years mineral wealth has played a significant role
in the economic development of resource-rich countries, which have
benefited greatly from their hydrocarbon reserves. Kazakhstan is an
exemplar in this respect, and has successfully overcome a transition
period from a central planned to a market-driven economy; overall, the
Kazakhstani government has provided institutional and policy support to
effect this transition and has delivered more in terms of economic
prosperity than other Central Asian countries and, possibly, Russia.
This study examines the relationship between long-term economic
growth and oil exports for Kazakhstan and, in so doing, it addresses two
related questions for an 'oil-rich' country: (i) does
'oil matter' in the long run; (ii) is oil a resource curse, a
blessing or neither? We first provide a brief review of the key
arguments in the 'curse versus blessing' debate. Thereafter,
we develop a narrative background to recent economic developments in
Kazakhstan, which includes an overview of relevant institutional and
policy initiatives. This narrative tends to support the view that,
overall, these developments have been positive, a view that is supported
by an examination of the governance indicators that have been developed
by The Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) Project (2015), see also
Kaufmann et al. (1999). The narrative analysis is then complemented by
an econometric model that directly addresses the key questions in terms
of cointegration and the estimated steady state between growth in real
gross domestic product (GDP) and oil exports; the empirical model then
provides the basis of some relevant long-term projection scenarios.
The article is organised as follows. The section 'Natural
resources and economic growth' briefly reviews the literature on
the subject of natural resources and economic growth. In the section
'Kazakhstan: Recent economic development' we examine and
evaluate economic development before the 2008 economic crisis and
beyond, to understand the evolution of the economy of Kazakhstan. The
section 'Institutional and policy factors' discusses the roles
of institutions and policies in providing a framework for the successful
extraction of oil resources, the encouragement of foreign investment and
the general improvement of governance indicators for Kazakhstan. The
empirical analysis is reported in the section 'Long-term economic
growth' and provides the basis for the scenario projections. The
section 'Conclusions' concludes the article.
NATURAL RESOURCES AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
The role of resource abundance in economic growth is the subject of
an ongoing debate, see, for example, Gelb (1988), Karl (1997a, b), Wood
(1999), Auty (2001), Frankel (2010) and Mohaddes and Pesaran (2013),
with mixed evidence about the relationship between resource abundance
and its effect on economic growth. We briefly consider, in turn, the
arguments that resource abundance is, respectively, bad and good, for
economic growth.
Natural resources are a resource curse
Recent history provides examples where the role of the raw
materials sector has been blamed for the underdevelopment or low growth
rates of some economies (Bravo-Ortega and de Gregorio, 2005). (1) The
worst example of such performance is Nigeria (Bevan et at, 1999), where
the increase in oil revenue did not make a positive impact on income per
capita. The experience of Nigeria is not an exception. During the last
several decades other resource-rich countries, including Qatar,
Venezuela, Iraq and Kuwait, have had similar experiences of negative
growth.
As early as the 1950s it was noticed that there was a correlation
between slow growth and a decrease in the relative prices of exports of
the natural resources industries. The Singer--Prebisch (1959 [1962])
hypothesis on the declining terms of trade, states that the prices of
export-orientated commodities decrease over time relative to the prices
of imported manufacturing goods. This leads to a situation where the
available revenue will be less and less able to buy the manufacturing
output, hence preventing investment and economic development. The 1970s
and 1980s were characterised as an era of adoption of
import-substitution policies as a pathway to increase the
competitiveness of manufacturing, although this strategy was often
inefficient and caused further problems in the manufacturing sector.
Concerns have also been raised regarding 'Dutch disease',
caused by an appreciation of the real exchange rate driven by a boom in
natural resources, the negative consequence of which is the shrinking of
manufacturing exports and production, see Gylfason et al. (1999), Sachs
and Warner (2001). The validity of the Dutch disease hypothesis has,
inter-alia, been tested by examining the relationship between real oil
prices and real exchange rates; for example, Jahan-Parvar and Mohammadi
(2011) used a sample of 14 oil-exporting countries, with a
co-integration approach, to demonstrate the existence of a stable
relationship between real exchange rates and real oil prices in all
countries, suggesting strong support for the Dutch disease hypothesis.
The transmission mechanisms directly linking natural resource
exploitation and economic growth suggested by Gylfason (2001) were: the
Dutch disease, rent-seeking, government mismanagement and low levels of
human capital. There have been attempts to identify empirically the
potential channels of transmission for the resource curse (also known as
the paradox of plenty) by regressing institutional quality, human
capital and so on, on natural resource dependence, and then calculating
the indirect effects of resource dependence on growth from the
coefficients of these intermediate variables on growth, see Lay and
Mahmoud (2004), Papyrakis and Gerlagh (2004) and, for a critique of this
approach, see Van der Ploeg (2011).
The price volatility of raw materials has also been blamed for the
increasing difficulties in the fiscal management of export revenues and,
ultimately, limiting growth. Further arguments have been developed that
foreign companies investing into the raw materials sector of the
resource-rich countries only benefit themselves and their countries,
leaving behind the host countries, see Singer (1950) and Humphreys et al
(2007).
In the assessing the likelihood of the resource curse, Isham et al.
(2003) suggest a distinction between point and diffused resources, where
the former relate to natural resources extracted from a narrow
geographic or economic base, such as oil, minerals, coffee and cocoa,
and the latter to resources, such as agricultural produce, which are
geographically or economically diffused, with the latter contributing
more robustly in sustain economic growth.
Using cross-section regressions, Sachs and Warner (1995, 1999,
2001) found a negative relationship between economic growth and natural
resources. They supported this relationship with measures of resource
abundance, such as the share of mining production in GDP, land per
capita, and the share of natural resource exports in GDP and found that
an increment of 1 standard deviation in the contribution of natural
resources exports to GDP implied a lower rate of growth of the order of
1 % point each year.
Natural resources are a blessing
In contrast to the view that natural resources are a curse, there
are several reports of development where natural resources are
considered to have been the driver of economic growth, Wright (1990),
Sarraf and Jiwanji (2001). Gylfason (2001) reports that of 65
resource-rich developing countries, only Botswana, Indonesia, Malaysia
and Thailand managed to achieve long-term investment exceeding 25% of
gross domestic product (GDP), and an average GDP growth above 4% p.a.
The success of these three resource-rich Asian countries could be
explained by the economic policies of their governments, specifically by
economic diversification and industrialisation, see Van der Ploeg
(2011).
Another example of economic diversification policy can be found in
the United Arab Emirates (UAE), see Fasano (2002), where oil and gas
wealth have been used to improve standards of living, especially in the
provision of free health care, education and the modernisation of
infrastructure. The UAE government has been aware of the depletion of
its natural resources and, therefore, the creation of its petrochemical
and fertilizer industries has become a priority. In contrast, Dubai took
the route for diversification into tourism, finance, light manufacturing
and telecommunications.
An analysis of a number of individual case studies suggests that
the consistently successful countries among the resource-rich economies
are the developed countries, such as Norway, the UK, Canada, Sweden and
Finland, see Innis (1956), Andersen (1993), Kemp and Stephen (2005),
Al-Kasim et al. (2006), Larsen (2006) and Blomstrom and Kokko (2007). An
explanation of such success can be based on a low level of corruption
and well-developed institutions that help to form and implement
efficient governmental policies towards the oil and gas sectors, and
make coherent managerial decisions regarding economic development, see
Acemoglu et al (2005). The industrialisation in these countries was
based on the initial export of raw materials, which later created
linkages to other sectors of the economy, especially the manufacturing
sector.
Other research, see Maloney (2002), Stijns (2005), Lederman and
Maloney (2007), using different measures, such as net resource export
per worker or reserves per capita, has found a positive effect on
economic growth 'regardless of econometric technique ... several
plausible indicators of the incidence of natural resource exports seem
to have a positive rather than a negative effect on subsequent economic
growth. Put bluntly, there is no resource curse', Lederman and
Maloney (2007, p. 3). Continuing the thought further, Mohaddes and
Pesaran (2013) have argued that it is the volatility in oil revenues and
the government's inappropriate economic and political responses to
these volatilities, which are the curse and not resource abundance in
itself.
Further studies have tended to confirm these results, bringing good
news for the resource-rich countries, namely that their natural
resources can have a positive effect on economic growth, depending on
the optimal use of them, see Cavalcanti et al. (2011) and Kurtz and
Brooks (2011). In September 2013, an International Monetary Fund (IMF)
conference on 'Harnessing Natural Resource Wealth for Inclusive
Growth and Economic Development', highlighted that the key
challenges faced by all countries in ensuring that resource wealth
contributes in a sustained and inclusive fashion to growth and higher
living standards for all, are macro-fiscal issues and ways to promote
economic diversification (Singh, 2013). The role of strong institutional
settings, with powerful enforcement mechanisms, is an essential element
in sustaining long-term economic growth. In their work, Mehlum et al.
(2006) argued that natural resources are negatively associated with
economic growth in the case of weak institutions.
The research evidence also suggests that avoiding the resource
curse requires sound and forward-looking policy in addition to the
existence of strong institutions. This gives a primary role to the
governments of resource-rich countries, which typically play a dominant
role in the economy through their control of natural resources and
associated income. Decisions regarding taxation expenditures, including
public investment, fiscal deficits, savings mechanisms such as the role
of sovereign wealth funds, and the governance framework, will have
important consequences--not just for today but also for future
generations--with the potential to ensure successful development or
alternatively to destabilise the economy, see Hannesson (2005).
Gylfason et al. (1999) suggested that the natural resources sector
needs less human capital than other productive sectors, so that
diversification is a key area for economic policy; and the fact that the
resource is exhaustible pushes the governments to think ahead. Singh
(2013), Director of the Asia and Pacific Department, IMF noted:
'for inclusive growth in addition to wise use of the resources it
is imperative that backward and forward linkages are developed between
the natural resource sector and the wider economy. Achieving this
objective involves financial sector deepening, building infrastructure,
enhancing human capital, and promoting the agricultural sector'.
KAZAKHSTAN: RECENT ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
A number of papers have analysed economic development in the
Caspian Sea Region, and Russia since its independence, with the common
theme of highlighting the dependence of these economies on mineral
wealth (2). The last (20) years have brought significant changes to
their economic development, with the hydrocarbons sector in particular
giving these economies a new shape, for example in the strategic
importance of Russia, Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan in world energy markets.
The development of the oil and gas sector in Russia and the Caspian
region economies has been particularly noticeable in the case of
Kazakhstan from 2001 through to 2014, especially the increasing
importance of oil and gas sector revenues in total exports. Starting
from a share comparable to Russia in 2001, with 50% for Russia and 53%
for Kazakhstan, this share had increased to 77% by 2014, compared with
56% for Russia. Kazakhstan is clearly now a 'resource-based
economy' in the sense in which this term has been used by Ahrend
(2006), with the share of oil and gas revenues in total exports
regularly exceeding 40% and generally of the order of 70%, see Table 1.
Kazakhstan has attracted the largest flows of FDI in the Caspian
Region, see Figure 1. In part this has resulted from the
government's attempt to adopt a policy of continuous improvement of
the laws on investment and taxes. Overall, since 1993, US$171.2 billion
of FDI has been raised in Kazakhstan, with an FDI growth rate of 27% on
average for the last 20 years, which compares with an FDI growth rate in
the UAE of 26%, in Brazil of 15% and of 14% in Turkey. The geographical
composition of the FDI in Kazakhstan is represented by 120 countries,
the main contributors being the Netherlands, China, Switzerland, the
United States and France.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
This impressive picture is mainly because of investment into
Kazakhstan's natural resources, although the composition of the FDI
in other resource-rich Caspian economies is similar (Kalyuzhnova, 2008).
Overall, during 1993-2012, 34.8% of FDI was invested in geological
surveys and exploration, 30.2% in the production of raw materials, with
the largest share in hydrocarbons, and 10.2% in final manufacturing
production.
In order to ensure that the non-natural resource sectors of the
economy were attracting sufficient FDI, the Accelerated Industrial and
Innovative Development Programme for 2010-2014 (AAIIDP) was adopted by
the Kazakhstani government, with the first results reported in 2013.
According to Assett Issekeshev, the Minister of Industry and New
Technologies, during the implementation of AAIIDP, the share of FDI into
crude oil declined by 18%, while at the same time the share of FDI into
manufacturing production, which includes such sectors as machine
building, chemicals, petrochemical industries, and food processing,
increased by 8%. Moreover, for the first time FDI was attracted into
high-tech industries, such as pharmaceuticals, computer manufacturing,
electronic and optical products. Overall, at the present time, the
government is working together with foreign investors from 80 countries
on more than 400 initiatives; 81 projects (with a value of $8.8 billion)
of these initiatives have already been completed. As of 31 December
2014, FDIs in Kazakhstan reached 132.6 $ bn, primarily in the oil and
gas sector. Kazakhstan is widely considered to have the best investment
climate in the region.
The 1990s were very difficult years for the economic development of
Kazakhstan; however, from 1999 onwards, following a substantial currency
devaluation, an increase in proven oil reserves and an upturn in oil
prices, Kazakhstan experienced stronger economic growth starting in
2000. Until 2007 economic growth was strong, but it slowed somewhat as a
result of stress in the financial sector and the impact of this on the
construction industry. 2007 was the eighth consecutive year of real GDP
growth in excess of 7% p.a. Sharp increases in oil prices in the early
2000s, and subsequently the growth in non-oil revenues, allowed for a
further substantial expansion in budgetary expenditures and in parallel
to this a sizable increase in the overall fiscal surplus (Kalyuzhnova,
2008).
From July 2007, Kazakhstan's banking sector was affected by
the more generally widespread financial crisis: the banks had borrowed
heavily on the international capital markets and the speculative bubble
in the residential property market burst. Falling oil prices and the
deepening economic crisis also had a significant impact on the wider
Kazakhstani economy. The 2007-2009 crisis was the first stress test for
the newly established (since 2000) National Fund of the Republic of
Kazakhstan (NFRK). By 2008, the NFRK had become one of the world's
largest sovereign wealth funds, alongside those of the oil-producing
countries of the Middle East and Russia. NFRK has worked for Kazakhstan
overall, transfers to the fund did help mitigate the pressure on
Kazakhstan's economy during the upswing, and left it better
prepared for the 2007-2009 shock, see Kalyuzhnova (2011).
INSTITUTIONAL AND POLICY FACTORS
In this section, we make a distinction between the institutional
and policy frameworks as they have affected the oil industry and the
quality of governance in Kazakhstan. To give an example of the
distinction, the rule of law is an 'institution' that provides
the contractual basis for economic participation between companies and
countries; whereas a particular law, for example, the 'Law on
Investment' (detailed below), is the result of a policy to treat
domestic and foreign investors equally. We consider each of these
factors in turn and in section 4.3 consider the good governance
indicators for Kazakhstan produced by the World Governance Indicators
project, see WGI (2015).
Institutional factors
A strong institutional setting has been shown to be a necessary
condition for the success of a national economy, with poor institutions
having a negative effect on a country's growth. There is
cross-country evidence that has demonstrated a significant negative
impact of natural resources on income per capita after controlling for
institutional quality, trade openness and geography. In cases where
countries have poor institutions and a low degree of trade openness, the
negative implications are quite drastic, see Arezki and van der Ploeg
(2010); therefore, the strategy of trade openness and improving
institutional quality could turn natural resources into the
country's blessing.
Over the last 20 years, during which Kazakhstan has been formed as
a state, the economy has been shaped and developed and the nation has
become more interested in the terms and conditions of the oil and gas
contracts concluded at the beginning of the 1990s. The verdict was that
a number of them had unfavourable terms with regard to Kazakhstan. Why
did this happen? This can be explained by a number of reasons, starting
from the economic crisis of the early 1990s, the inexperience of the
Kazakhstani negotiators, as well as the high risk associated with early
investments into fields with uncertain reserve bases (Suleimenov and
Osipov, 2010).
At the present time Kazakhstan is facing a challenge that will
determine the success of long-term economic growth: namely the creation
of an institutional framework, which is required by economic maturity
and the growth of markets, to encourage external investing partners by
providing a framework enabling transactions to take place in a secure
and orderly manner. All players will know that the decisions they take
and the contracts they make will be protected by law and enforced if
necessary. For all the participants in the Kazakhstani market it is
important to have an institutional framework that is rational, and
provides a guarantee of economic stability and certainty. This can be
achieved by good governance and sound economic policymaking.
Policy
The route through which the government operates its energy policy
is the Ministry of Oil and Gas, which effectively manages the
country's hydrocarbons industry. Overall, energy policy is based on
sound economic and environmental practices, as well as good legal
practices and technologies, which is how the government positioned
itself in its relations with foreign and domestic investors. For
example, during the investment conference of the 47th annual meeting of
the Asian Development Bank in Astana (May, 2014), the Kazakhstan
government highlighted that they would amend the corresponding laws to
create a more favourable investment climate; the government also removed
the barriers faced by foreign investors in the development of their
activity in Kazakhstan and prepared a comprehensive package of
incentives for foreign investors.
Although, overall, Kazakhstan's tax laws are among the most
comprehensive in the CIS; in January 2009, Kazakhstan adopted a new Tax
Code that lowered corporate-income and value-added taxes, replaced
royalty payments with a mineral-extraction tax, and introduced
excess-profits and rent taxes on the export of crude oil and natural
gas. 'Due to the new Tax Code, new contracts cannot include any
provisions on stability of contracts (stabilisation clauses). In
addition, the Code only expressly preserves tax stability in Production
Sharing Agreements and contracts approved by the RK President, meaning
that other contracts made before the Code may not be stabilised for tax
purposes', Suleimenov and Osipov (2010, p. 5).
On 8 December 2004, amendments to the Petroleum Law and Subsurface
Law became effective, and, finally, the Production Sharing Agreement Law
(applicable to the Caspian and Aral Seas). These changes have had a
substantial impact on the petroleum industry: they reflect the
government's policies with respect to increased participation of
the National Oil Company (in production); greater attention to the use
and development of local content and 'high technologies', a
change in government (tax) take; and increased regulation and oversight.
During the 2000s, the Kazakhstani government addressed the problem
of attracting domestic investors by creating favourable conditions for
them. In 2003, it adopted the Law on Investment, which established a
single investment regime for domestic and foreign investors and
providers, which guaranteed the stability of existing contracts, with
the qualification that new contracts will be subject to amendments in
domestic legislation, certain provisions of international treaties, and
domestic laws dealing with 'national and ecological security,
health, and ethic'. This law contains incentives and preferences
for government-determined priority sectors, providing customs duty
exemptions and in-kind grants, but the weakness of this law is that it
excludes all the norms regarding foreign investors. The Law's
narrow definition of investment disputes, its lack of clear provisions
for access to international arbitration, and certain aspects of
investment contract stability guarantees, are also points of concern of
foreign investors.
Several major acts of legislation have had an impact on oil and gas
foreign investments in Kazakhstan: the Decree of the President of the
Republic 'On Subsoil and Subsoil Use', in force from 1996, and
the Decree of the President of the Republic 'On Petroleum', in
force from 1995. One of the main principles of the Law on Subsoil Use is
the creation of favourable conditions for foreign investment. In
summary, the tax, custom and procurement regimes have also played an
important role in investment in the oil and gas sectors, specifically:
(i) the 2003 Customs Code and the Customs Code of the Customs Union,
which came into force in July 2010; (ii) the Tax Code; (in) the Law on
Currency Regulation and Currency control; and (iv) the Law on Government
Procurement. These laws provide for non-expropriation, currency
convertibility, guarantees of legal stability, transparent government
procurement and incentives for priority sectors.
The Kazakhstan government is continuing its policy initiative for
the next 5 years with the 'Concept for Industrial and Innovative
Development, 2015--2020' programme, which is aimed at continuing to
attract foreign and domestic investments and further developing an
industrial strategy aimed at diversifying Kazakhstan's economy away
from its overdependence on raw materials. In order to facilitate the
work of foreign investors, especially in targeted non- extractive
industries, the government has announced a set of industries that
feature tax waivers and simplified procedures for acquiring visas and
work permits.
Governance and economic indicators
The relationship between governance and economic growth has been
the subject of some recent research, with the WGI, now produced annually
by Kaufmann et al. (1999), particularly influential in this respect. The
underlying components of the WGI indices (such as surveys) are organised
in clusters into six indicators designed to cover the following aspects
of institutions and policies: voice and accountability, political
stability, government effectiveness (GE), regulatory quality (RQ), the
rule of law (RoL) and control of corruption (CC). The governance indices
are constructed to have the range (-2.5, +2.5), with improvements
indicated by a numerical increase in the index.
The indicators of particular concern here are the two pairs
comprising GE and RQ, capturing policy-based issues, and RoL and CC,
which have a greater institutional focus. Of the first pair, Kaufmann et
al. (1999) note: The main focus of this (GE) index is on the inputs
required for the government to be able to produce and implement good
policies and deliver public goods.' The second index (RQ) relates
to 'perceptions of the burdens imposed by excessive regulation in
areas such as foreign trade and business development'. The GE index
relates to the ability to provide public goods, such as infrastructure,
whereas the RQ index focusses on the policies. Institutional quality is
assessed by the RoL and CC indices. The four relevant indicators are
shown in Figure 2.
Considering the policy indicators, GE and RQ, after a dip in 2002,
there was a general improvement from 2002 to 2009, followed by slight
declines more recently; note that these two indicators tend to move
quite closely together. The institutional indicators, RoL and CC, also
show a general improvement, but from a slightly lower base than for GE
and RQ. Overall, the most pronounced increase has been in the GE and RoL
indicators. Generally, the indicators provide support for the narrative
view expressed above that there have been general, if not uniform,
improvements in the institutional and policy aspects of good governance,
which have provided a framework conducive to growth and attractive to
overseas investors.
This view is supported by reference to indicators produced by a
number of other agencies; for example, the Index of Economic Freedom,
IEF (2015), is an index based on 10 underlying components related to the
following four sections: the Rule of Law (RoL); Limited Government (LG);
Regulatory Efficiency (RE); and Open Markets (OM), the lower limit for
each index 0 and the upper limit is 100, an increase in the numerical
score is intended to indicate greater 'freedom'. The IEF adds
to the WGI in the sense of explicitly scoring for freedoms in trade,
investment and finance in the Open Markets area, which should encourage
and enable overseas investment. The overall IEF and the indices for the
four sections are shown in Figure 3, where the aggregated section
indices average the respective components. All of the section indices
point to a steadily improving environment for economic development and,
as a result, a steady increase in the overall IEF. In a comparison of
the Caspian Region economies, Kazakhstan ranks above Azerbaijan and
Turkmenistan, which have IEF overall scores in 2014 of 61.3 and 41.4,
respectively, compared with 63.7 for Kazakhstan. Interestingly,
Kazakhstan, starting from a much lower base in the 1990s, now ranks
close to, and above, some Western countries, for example in 2014, Italy
had an overall IEF of 60.9, France 63.5, compared with 63.7 for
Kazakhstan.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
More specific indices are available from the Global Competitiveness
Dataset, World Economic Forum (2015), although the available time span
for Kazakhstan data is shorter than for the WGI and IEF. Of these their
value added, compared with the WGI and IEF indices, is in the indices
for technological progress, which are particularly relevant and comprise
three separate indices relating to: availability of latest technologies,
firm-level technology absorption and FDI and technology transfer. The
technology indices are indicative of the developments that have enabled
Kazakhstan in the production and export of its oil and gas resources,
combined with diversification into other industries, each of which has
been facilitated by FDI and the effective transfer of technology.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
These data are graphed in Figures 4, 5 and 6, one for each index, a
numerical increase in the index is an improvement and the upper limit is
7.0. By way of a numeraire, we also include the index values for the
Russian Federation, which separated from Kazakhstan at the same time,
but is generally second in all of these developments of its economy. The
indices support the narrative background, although not without
qualification, that since the late 1990s, Kazakhstan has developed its
natural resources and other industries in ways that are likely to avoid
the problem of the resource curse, especially with its ability to
benefit from the transfer of technology in the natural resource and
other industries. In the following section, we examine this argument in
more detailed from an econometric point of view.
LONG-TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH
The narrative background of recent economic developments in
Kazakhstan suggests that after transitional adjustments in the 1990s,
following separation from the USSR, growth in FDI, improvements in
governance and the design of oil sector policy, there was a sustained
growth in oil exports and GDP. Against this background, this section
considers a modelling and estimation framework, designed to address the
key questions set out in the first two sections: is the abundance of oil
a benefit to longer term economic development: is it a curse, a
blessing--or neither? What are the implications of the growth in oil
exports for longer-term economic growth?
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The modelling framework we adopt is because of Esfahani et al.
(2014), hereafter EMP (2014), a key point in their approach, with which
we agree, concerns the role of political systems and institutions, they
note: 'While the countries under consideration have very different
political systems and institutional economic arrangements, our theory
suggests that these differences can only affect the estimates of the
parameters rather than the nature of the long-run relationship that
holds between outputs (domestic and foreign) and oil export
revenues'., (ibid., p. 100). What matters is the oil
reserve-to-production ratio. Moreover they argue that cross-section
analysis captures short-term deviations from equilibrium and can,
therefore be misleading.
The modelling framework
The modelling framework we adopt is because of Esfahani et al.
(2014), hereafter EMP (2014), whose theory and empirical results
suggested a key distinction between countries with reserves, and hence
future oil income, over the short to medium term (approximately less
than 10 years) and over the longer term, broadly greater than 10 years.
In economies, such as Kazakhstan, in which oil income is growing at
least as fast as the natural rate of growth, [g.sup.n] = g + n, where g
and n are, respectively, the rates of growth of technical progress and
of the domestic population, EMP derive the following long-run
relationship:
[y.sup.ss.sub.t] = [[mu].sup.*] + [[psi].sub.1][y.sup.*.sub.t] +
[[psi].sub.2] [x.sup.0.sub.t] + [[gamma].sub.y]t + [[epsilon].sub.y,t]
(1)
Where [y.sub.t] is the log of GDP in constant prices;
[y.sup.*.sub.t] is the are the log of overseas output, in practice a
weighted average of the real GDPs of key trading partners;
[x.sup.0.sub.t] is the log of real oil income adjusted for exchange rate
movements and the domestic price level, that is [x.sup.0.sub.t]
[equivalent to] log ([RER.sub.t]([P.sup.o.sub.t] [X.sup.bo.sub.t])),
where [RER.sub.t] [equivalent to] [E.sub.t]/[P.sub.t] is the real
exchange rate, [E.sub.t] is the nominal exchange rate expressed as the
number of domestic currency units per US$ (3), [P.sup.o.sub.t] is the
unit price in US$ per barrel of oil, [X.sup.bo.sub.t] is domestic oil
exports in 000s of barrels and [P.sub.t] is a domestic price index, here
the CPI which is also used for the deflation of nominal GDP and t is a
time trend. For future reference we define [rer.sub.t] [equivalent to]
log ([RER.sub.t]) and [xo.sub.t] [equivalent to] log ([P.sup.o.sub.t]
[X.sup.bo.sub.t]).
The long-run relationship in Equation 1 relates real domestic GDP
(output), [y.sub.t], to 'overseas' output [y.sup.*.sub.t] with
an elasticity of [[psi].sub.1], to real oil income with an elasticity of
[[psi].sub.2] and a time trend, with coefficient [[gamma].sub.y] the
latter term is absent in the case of common deterministic trends among
the variables, which is referred to a co-trending. The model enables
three important distinctions to be made, which are relevant to the key
statements raised in the Introduction concerning the importance of oil
to output, specifically: (i) oil does not matter, it is neither a
resource curse nor blessing; (ii) oil is a 'blessing'; and
(iii) oil is a 'curse'. These distinctions give rise to three
hypotheses, as follows:
[H.sub.0] [[psi].sub.2] = 0 (oil does not matter);
[H.sub.A;1] [][psi].sub.2] > 0 (oil is a blessing);
[H.sub.A,2] [[psi].sub.2] <0 (oil is a curse).
Empirical results
The theory-consistent relationship in Equation 1 is a steady-state,
relationship, which needs to be embedded in a dynamic estimation
framework that enables transient movements to be captured. An
appropriate estimation framework for the sample period in this case, is
the autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) method because of Pesaran and
Shin (1999), see also Pesaran et al. (2001). (4)
The ARDL relevant to Equation 1 is as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
The ARDL is referred to by the lag orders on the component
variables on the right-hand side of Equation 2, ARDL(p, [q.sub.1],
[q.sub.2], [q.sub.3]). Next, define [phi] (1) [equivalent to]
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. The long-run
coefficient for [y.sup.*.sub.t] is given by [[psi].sub.1] =
[[beta].sub.1](1)/[phi](1); Equation 2 allows separate transient
adjustments from the real exchange rate, RER, and the US$ value of oil
income, [xo.sub.t], while maintaining the steady-state restriction that
[[psi].sub.2] = [[beta].sub.2](1)/[phi](1) = [[beta].sub.3](1)/[phi](1).
The steady-state level of [y.sub.t], [y.sup.ss.sub.t], is then as given
by Equation 1, where [[mu].sup.*] = [mu]/[phi] (1) and [[gamma].sub.y] =
[beta]/[phi](1). (Lag lengths are selected using AIC.)
The ARDL model of Equation 2 can be reparameterised into the
following error correction model (ECM), which captures both the
transient dynamics and the steady-state solution:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
Where[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], which is
interpreted as the deviation from the (estimated) steady state. The
interpretation of the ECM is well known, with the key coefficient being
that on the lagged [ecm.sub.t], [gamma], which is expected to be
negative and governs the speed of adjustment when out of equilibrium.
While the overall sample period available with quarterly data was
1995ql to 2013q4, it is clear from narrative of the economic development
of Kazakhstan that consideration would have to be given to obtaining a
relatively homogenous period for estimation. There were four factors
supporting the view of a structural break in 1999, which was best
accommodated by treating the sample 1999q4 to 2013q4 as a relatively
homogenous period. First, the substantial currency devaluation of the
Kazakhstan tenge (Kt) in 1999, which started the year at 85Kt:US$ and
ended at 140Kt:US$, second, as indicated above, a number of structural
changes in the financial infrastructure of Kazakhstan; the developments
in institutions and policies associated with the post-1999 period; and
the general lack of output growth in the 1990s, compared with the
'take-off in 1999.
The proxy for 'overseas' output, y* was based on
Kazakhstan's main trading partners, Russia, the EU and China, which
together account for approximately 80% of trade (imports and exports),
with weights of 0.4, 0.4 and 0.2, based on the mid-point of the sample.
The estimates of the steady-state coefficients, together with diagnostic
statistics for the corresponding ARDL equation, are reported in Table 2.
The ARDL is well-specified in terms of the diagnostic statistics and the
estimated steady-state coefficients are consistent with the theoretical
model. (A prior regression included a trend, as suggested by Equation 1,
but the coefficient was not significant, thus the hypothesis of
cotrending was not rejected.) The bounds test for cointegration (see
Pesaran et ai, 2001), in both the F and W versions, strongly support
cointegration, with sample values well in excess of the 95 % upper
bound. Forming the corresponding ECM, the coefficient on the estimate of
the lagged disequilibrium, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] with a t statistic of -4.36 and, hence, a p-value of 0,
indicating a relatively fast recovery from disequilibrium.
Conjectural projection
In this section, we consider a long-term conjecture or
'scenario' to assess the growth potential in real GDP based on
the estimated version of Equation 1, which conditions the growth of
output on the growth of 'world' output, [y.sub.t], and oil
exports, [x.sup.o.sub.t]. It is relevant to consider projections using
the steady state equation as dynamic adjustments are transient. The
empirical results (see section Table 2) support the following general
specification of steady state:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
Where [g.sup.ss.sub.y] is the steady-state growth in
[y.sup.ss.sub.y] (home-country GDP) and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and [g.sup.o.sub.ss] are the steady-state growth
rates in [y.sup.*.sub.t] ('overseas' GDP) and [x.sup.o.sub.t]
(real value of oil exports), respectively.
The real value of oil exports can be decomposed into its component
parts as follows: [x.sup.o.sub.t] [equivalent to] [p.sup.o.sub.t] +
[xo.sub.t] + [rer.sub.t], where, [p.sup.o.sub.t] [equivalent to]
ln([P.sup.o.sub.t]), [x.sup.o.sub.t] [equivalent to] 1n
([X.sup.o.sub.t]) and [rer.sub.t] [equivalent to] 1n
([E.sub.t]/[P.sub.t]); thus, the growth in the real value of exports,
[g.sup.o.sub.t], can be (identically) decomposed into the growth rates
of the price of oil, [g.sup.po.sub.t], the number of barrels exported,
[g.sup.po.sub.t] and the real exchange rate, [g.sup.rer.sub.t], so that:
[g.sup.o.sub.t] [equivalent to] [g.sup.po.sub.t] + [g.sup.po.sub.t] +
[g.sup.rer.sub.t]. A scenario projection will need to consider each of
these components and the growth in overseas output, [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Over the sample period the price of oil in nominal terms has
increased on average by just under 3 % p.q,; however, the recent decline
in oil prices has led to a substantial revision to the potential course
of oil prices over the coming decade. The Department of Energy and
Climate Change (DECC, 2014), has recently summarised a number of
sources, for example the International Energy Agency (IEA) and the US
Energy Information Administration (EIA), and provided projections of the
price of a barrel of oil. The 'central' projection for 2014 is
based on the Brent futures curve, where the projections for 2015 to 2020
are an average of eleven expert projections and thereafter they are
based on the IEA and EIA projections of constant growth.
The DECC projections, which are in terms of 2014 prices, US$2014,
are converted to nominal prices using the IEA default rate of 2.3% p.a.
in the numeraire price index and are shown in levels and logs in Figure
7. The oil price is assumed not to return to its 2014 level (in 2014
prices) until 2022 and thereafter increase to 135US$2014 in 2025, which
corresponds to approximately $220 in nominal prices. The projection
shows that the oil price declines through to 2017 and then grows at an
assumed constant rate of 4.6% p.a. in nominal terms thereafter.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Although the three variables [rer.sup.t], [p.sup.o.sub.t] and
[x.sup.o.sub.t] do not cointegrate (which affects the modelling of
levels of the variables), we can exploit the relationship between these
variables in differences, where [g.sup.po.sub.t] =
[DELTA][p.sup.o.sub.t], [g.sup.bo.sub.t] [equivalent to]
[DELTA][xo.sub.t] and [g.sup.rer.sub.t] [DELTA][rer.sub.t]. A scenario
projection will need to consider each of these components to model the
required growth rates. Empirically, we find that there is recursive
causal structure, in which causality in differences runs from
[g.sup.po.sub.t] to [g.sup.bo.sub.t], and then from [g.sup.po.sub.t] and
[g.sup.bo.sub.t] to [g.sup.rer.sub.t]; thus, a projection of
[g.sup.bo.sub.t] can be conditioned on the projected path of
[g.sup.po.sub.t] and then the projection of [g.sup.rer.sub.t] can be
based on the projected paths of [g.sup.po.sub.t] and [g.sup.bo.sub.t].
To illustrate, given the projected path of [g.sup.po.sub.t], the
projected value of [g.sup.bo.sub.t] converges to 0.0205, that is 2.05%
p.q, which is an estimate of the steady-state value [g.sup.bo.sub.ss] of
[g.sup.bo.sub.t]; then, given the projected paths of [g.sup.po.sub.t]
and [g.sup.bo.sub.t], the estimated [g.sup.rer.sub.t] converges to
[g.sup.rer.sub.t] = - 0.0158, that -1.58% p.q. The DECC projections of
the oil price imply [g.sup.po.sub.ss] = 0.0113, then [g.sup.o.sub.ss]
[equivalent to] [g.sup.po.sub.ss] + [g.sup.bo.sub.ss] +
[g.sup.rer.sub.ss] = 0.0113 + 0.0205 - 0.0158 = 0.016, that is 1.60% p.q
(6.56% p.a.). This is less than the sample average of 3.16% p.q, but
reflects the changed view on the consensus course of the oil price.
A scenario projection also requires a projection of overseas
output, here comprising the weighted GDPs of Russia, the EU and China.
Recent projections of World GDP by region prepared by the EIA (2014)
suggest annual growth rates over the period 2015-2025 of 3.0% p.a.,
2.45% p.a. and 6.0% p.a., respectively, for these countries. Applying
the weights 0.4, 0.4 and 0.2, gives a projected weighted growth rate of
3.4% p.a., which is less than the average over the sample period of 5.4%
p.a. and reflects the slow recovery following the 2008 financial crash
and a slowing in the growth rate of China's GDP. At a quarterly
rate [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] = 0.0083.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
The steady-state growth projection [g.sup.y.sub.ss] can now be
constructed from its components and the estimated counterpart of
Equation 1; these depend on the projected growth rates and the
coefficients, thus: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
see Table 2. The projected steady-state growth rate after 2018 is
[g.sup.y.sub.ss] = 0.53 x 0.0083 + 0.62 x 0.0160 = 0.0143, that is 1.43%
p.q giving an annualised rate of 5.85% p.a. Although this is high by the
standards of industrialised countries, the rate is much lower than has
been the case for Kazakhstan over the sample, with an average annual
growth rate of just under 13% p.a.
In order to project [g.sup.y.sub.t], and hence yt, over the period
2015-2025, we need to accommodate the dip in the projected oil price
from 2015 until 2018, where [g.sup.po.sub.t] < [g.sup.po.sub.ss] =
0.0113. This is simple enough to do by simulating [g.sup.bo.sub.t] and
[g.sup.rer.sub.t] using the estimated recursive model conditioned on the
DECC projection of [g.sup.po.sub.t] (as shown in Figure 7). The
resulting projected values of [y.sub.t], taking 2015q1 as the starting
point, are [y.sub.p,t] = [y.sub.p,t-1] + [g.sup.y.sub.p,t], where the p
subscript indicates a projection, and [y.sub.p,t-1] = [y.sub.t-1] for t
- 1 = 2014q4. The projected values are shown in Figure 8; taking into
account the slower growth in the early part of the projection period
because of the dip in the oil price, the projected average growth rate,
2015-2025, is [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is
5.09% p.a. which, as anticipated, is slightly less than in the
steady-state projection.
CONCLUSIONS
A major concern for nations with substantial oil reserves is
whether their exploitation will prove to be a longer-term benefit. This
concern has given rise to the question of whether such reserves are a
blessing, a curse or neither. There is empirical evidence across a range
of countries that all are indeed possible and have indeed occurred. The
experience of recent countries to join the oil-rich 'club' is
particularly relevant to an evaluation of this question as they have had
the chance to learn from the experiences of earlier members. In this
context, Kazakhstan is a leading player. Having separated from the USSR
in 1991, it underwent a transition to a market-based economy, which
involved not only the transition to market pricing decisions, but the
development of institutions and policies similar to those in the western
industrialised economies. These developments were concerned with
building up the institutional and physical infrastructure necessary to
compete in world markets, both in exporting and in attracting FDI, so as
to develop existing resources and diversify away from an over dependence
on natural resources.
The narrative of this article supports the general view that
despite some autocratic elements of government, Kazakhstan has,
generally, been successful in this aim, although there is still some way
to go to match the European countries; nevertheless, it has been very
successful amongst the newly transitioning economies in attracting FDI
and, to a degree, in diversifying its economy. These developments are at
least suggestive that Kazakhstan has avoided the danger that oil is a
curse. To analyse its performance in this respect, we developed the
modelling framework because of Esfahani et al (2014), in which the
blessing/curse/neither trichotomy can be tested. The empirical results
strongly suggest that oil has been a blessing for Kazakhstan, with a
significantly positive steady-state relationship between oil exports and
GDP. We concur with EMP that to the extent that policy and institutional
arrangements have an impact they do so on the parameter estimates; they
summarised the situation as follows: '... what matters most is the
extent to which oil revenues are likely to be sustainable over the
medium to long term, and in this regard it is the oil
reserve-to-production ratio that could be important as to whether oil
income enters the long-run output equation as a major determinant.'
(EMP, p. 10).
This framework was then further developed to consider projections
of the growth of GDP conditioned on projections of the oil price. The
recent central projection of oil price produced by the UK's
Department of Energy and Climate Change, based on an average of 11
expert projections and IEA and EIA projections, was used to provide an
illustrative 'scenario' projection of GDP. On the basis of the
estimated steady-state relationships, and conditional on the DECC oil
price projection, GDP was projected to grow at an average annual rate of
just over 5% p.a. for the period 2015-2025, in contrast to its
previously much higher growth rates. This is a 'scenario'
rather than a forecast, it is intended to answer or provide guidance to
questions starting with 'what if' and to encourage discussion
of the implicit sensitivities that it uncovers; scenarios can also be
helpful to policy discussions that may lead to changes in potentially
endogenous variables, such as the (real) exchange rate, and to reinforce
the need for accompanying infrastructure developments.
Acknowledgements
The authors are grateful to Maxim Romanov for his excellent
research assistance, to Azat Aituar and Dina Azhgaliyeva for data
assistance, and to Tom Fletcher of the Department of Energy and Climate
Change (DECC). They are also grateful to a referee for his encouragement
and constructive comments on previous versions of this article.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D, Johnson, S and Robinson, JA. 2005: Institutions as the
fundamental cause of long-run growth. In: Aghion, P and Durlauf, S
(eds). Handbook of Economic Growth. Chapter 6. Elsevier: North Holland,
pp. 385-471.
Ahrend, R. 2006: How to sustain growth in a resource based economy?
The main concepts and their application to the Russian case. OECD
Economics Department Working Paper No. 478, Paris.
Al-Kasim, F, Skinner, R and Arnott, R. 2006: Managing petroleum
resources: The 'Norwegian model' in a broad perspective.
Oxford, UK: Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.
Andersen, SS. 1993: The struggle over North sea oil and gas:
Government strategies in Denmark. Scandinavian University Press: UK;
Oslo, Norway.
Arezki, R and Van der Ploeg, F. 2010: Do natural resources depress
income per Capita? Review of Development Economics 15(3): 504-21.
Asea, P and Lahiri, A. 1999: The precious bane. Journal of Economic
Dynamic and Control 23(5/6): 823-49.
Aslund, A. 2007: Russia's capitalist revolution. Petersen
Institute: Washington DC.
Auty, RM. 2001: The political economy of resource-driven growth.
European Economic Review 46(4/6): 839-46.
Bevan, D, Collier, P and Gunning, JW. 1999: The political economy
of poverty, equity and growth: Nigerian and Indonesia. Oxford University
Press: Oxford.
Blomstrom, M and Kokko, A. 2007: From natural resources to
high-tech production: The evolution of industrial competitiveness in
Sweden and Finland. In: Lederman, D and Maloney, WF (eds). Natural
Resources: Neither Curse nor Destiny. Stanford University Press:
Stanford, CA, pp. 71-99.
Bravo-Ortega, C and de Gregorio, J. 2005: The relative richness of
the poor? Natural resources, human capital and economic growth. World
Bank Working Paper, 3484, Washington, USA.
Cavalcanti, TV, de Mohaddes, K and Raissi, M. 2011: Growth,
development and natural resources: New evidence using a heterogeneous
panel analysis. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 51(4): 305-18.
Department of Energy and Climate Change. 2014: DECC Fossil Fuel
Price Projections, URN 14D/351, www.gov.uk/DECC, accessed on 26 June
2015.
Esfahani, HS, Mohaddes, K and Pesaran, MH. 2014: An empirical
growth model for major oil exporters. Journal of Applied Econometrics
29(1): 1-21.
Fasano, U. 2002: Review of the experience with oil stabilisation
and savings funds in selected countries. IMF Working Paper WP/00/112,
Washington, USA.
Frankel, J. 2010: The natural resource curse: A survey. National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 15836, March, Cambridge,
Massachusetts.
Gelb, A. (ed) 1988: Oil windfalls: Blessing or curse? Oxford
University Press: Oxford.
Gylfason, T. 2001: Natural resources, education, and economic
development. European Economic Review 45(4/6): 847-59.
Gylfason, T, Tryggvi, TH and Zoega, G. 1999: A mixed blessing:
Natural resources and economic growth. Macroeconomic Dynamics 3(2):
204-25.
Hannesson, R. 2005: Saving petroleum wealth: Tales of three
jurisdictions. In: Glomsrod, S and Osmundsen, P (eds). Petroleum
Regulation with Stable Steady States. Ashagate: Farnham, UK, pp.
112-130.
Hanson, P. 2002: Barriers to long-run growth in Russia. Economy and
Society 31(1): 62-84.
Hanson, P. 2008: The August 2008 Conflict: Economic Consequences
for Russia. Chatham House Briefing Note, September, London, UK.
Hanson, P. 2009: Russia to 2020. Finmeccanica Occasional Paper,
November, Rome, Italy.
Humphreys, M, Sachs, J and Stiglitz, JE. 2007: Escaping the
resource curse. Columbia University Press: New York.
IEF (Index of Economic Forum). 2015:
http://www.heritage.org/index/explorelview = by-region-country-year.
Innis, H. 1956: Essays in Canadian economic history. University of
Toronto: Toronto.
Isham, J, Woolcock, M, Pritchett, L and Busby, G. 2003: The
varieties of resource experience: Natural resource export structures and
the political economy of economic growth. World Bank Economic Review
19(2): 141-74.
Jahan-Parvar, MR and Mohammadi, H. 2011: Oil prices and real
exchange rates in oil-exporting countries: A bounds testing approach.
Journal of Developing Areas 45(1): 309-18.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. 1998: The Kazakhstani economy: Independence and
transition. Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. 2002: Economies and energy. In: Kalyuzhnova, Y,
Jaffe, AM, Lynch, D and Sickles, R (eds). Energy in the Caspian Region:
Present and Future. Chapter 3. Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. 2008: Economics of the Caspian oil and gas wealth:
Companies, governments, policies. Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. 2011: The national fund of the Republic of
Kazakhstan (NFRK): From accumulation to stress-test to global future.
Energy Policy 39(10): 6650-7.
Karl, TL. 1997a: The perils of the petro-state: Reflections on the
paradox of plenty. Journal of International Affairs 53(1): 31-48.
Karl, TL. 1997b: The paradox of plenty: Oil booms and petro-states.
University of California Press: Berkeley.
Kaser, M. 1997: The economies of Kazakhstan and Uzbekistan. The
Royal Institute of International Affairs: London.
Kaser, M. 2003: The economic and social impact of systemic
transition in Central Asia and Azerbaijan. Perspectives on Global
Development and Technology 2(3): 459-73.
Kaufmann, D, Kraay, A and Zoido-Lobaton, P. 1999: Aggregating
governance indicators. World Bank Policy Research Department Working
Paper No. 2195, Washington DC.
Kemp, AG and Stephen, L. 2005: Petroleum policy and prospects in
the UK continental shelf (UKCS). In: Glomsrod, S and Osmundsen, P (eds).
Petroleum Industry Regulation Within Stable States. Ashgate Publishing:
Aldershot, pp. 131-156.
Kurtz, MJ and Brooks, SM. 2011: Conditioning the 'resource
curse': Globalization, human capital, and growth in oil-rich
nations. Comparative Political Studies 44(6): 747-70.
Lane, P and Torrnell, A. 1996: Power, growth and the voracity
effect. Journal of Economic Growth 1 (June): 213-241.
Larsen, ER. 2006: Escaping the resource curse and the dutch
disease? When and why Norway caught up and forged ahead of its
neighbours. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 65(3): 605-40.
Lay, J and Mahmoud, TO. 2004: Bananas, oil and development:
Examining the resource curse and its transmission channels by resource
type. Working Paper No. 1218. Kiel Institute for World Economics, Kiel,
Germany.
Lederman, D and Maloney, WF. 2007: Natural Resources: Neither Curse
nor Destiny. Stanford University Press: Stanford, CA.
Maloney, W. 2002: Missed opportunities: Innovations and
resource-based growth in Latin America. Economia 3(1): 111-67.
Mehlum, H, Moene, K and Torvik, R. 2006: Institutions and the
resource curse. Economic Journal 116(508): 1-20.
Mohaddes, K and Pesaran, MH. 2013: One hundred years of oil income
and the iranian economy: A curse or a blessing? Cambridge Working Papers
in Economics 1302, University of Cambridge: Faculty of Economics,
Cambridge, UK.
Papyrakis, E and Gerlagh, R. 2004: The resource curse hypothesis
and its transmission channels. Journal of Comparative Economics 32(1):
181-93.
Pesaran, MH and Shin, Y. 1999: An autoregressive distributed lag
modelling approach to cointegration analysis. In: Storm, S. (ed).
Econometrics and Economic Theory in the 20th Century: The Ragnar Frisch
Centennial Symposium. Chapter 11. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.
Pesaran, MH, Shin, Y and Smith, R. 2001: Bounds testing approaches
to the analysis of level relationships. Journal of Applied Econometrics
16(3): 289-326.
Pomfret, R. 1995: The economies of central Asia. Princeton
University Press: Princeton, NJ.
Pomfret, R. 2003: Economic performance in Central Asia since 1991:
Macro and micro evidence. Comparative Economic Studies 43(4): 442-465.
Pomfret, R. 2006: The central Asian economies since independence.
Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.
Prebisch, R. 1959 [1962]: The economic development of Latin America
and its principal problems. Reprinted in. Economic Bulletin for Latin
America 7(1): 1-22.
Rodriguez, F and Sachs, JD. 1999: Why do resource-abundant
economies grow more slowly? Journal of Economic Growth 4(3): 277-303.
Rosser, A. 2006: The Political Economy of the Resource Curse: A
Literature Survey. IDS Working Paper 268. Brighton, UK: Institute of
Development Studies, www.ids.ac.uk/publication/
thepolitical-economy-of-the-resource-curse-a-literature-survey, accessed
9 December 2013.
Rutland, P. 2008: Putin's economic record: Is the oil boom
sustainable? Europe-Asia Studies 60(6): 1051-72.
Sachs, JD and Warner, AM. 1995 [1997]: Natural resource abundance
and economic growth. In: Meier, G and Rauch, J (eds). Leading Issues in
Economic Development. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Sachs, JD and Warner, AM. 1997: Fundamental Sources of Long Run
Growth. American Economic Review 87(2): 184-188.
Sachs, JD and Warner, AM. 1999: The big push, natural resource
booms and growth. Journal of Development Economics 59(1): 43-76.
Sachs, JD and Warner, AM. 2001: The curse of national resources.
European Economic Review 45(4/6): 827-38.
Sarraf, M and Jiwanji, M. 2001: Beating the resource curse: The
case of Botswana. Environment Department, World Bank: Washington DC.
Singer, H. 1950: The distribution of trade between investing and
borrowing countries. American Economic Review 40(2): 473-85.
Singh, A. 2013: Keynote Speech. Conference on Harnessing Natural
Resource Wealth for Inclusive Growth and Economic Development.
International Monetary Fund, Dili, 18 September, Washington,
https://www.imf.org/extemal/np/speeches/2013/091813.htm.
Stijns, J-PC. 2005: Natural resource abundance and economic growth
revisited. Resources Policy 30(2): 107-30.
Suleimenov, MK and Osipov, YB. 2010: Review of the Legislative Base
for Investments in Oil and Gas Sector of the Republic of
Kazakhstan--Executive Summary (English). Project document. IIED/British
Embassy, Kazakhstan.
Van der Ploeg, F. 2011: Natural resources: Curse or blessing?
Journal of Economic Literature 49(6): 366-420.
WGI. 2015: http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pubs/aggindicators.htm.
Wood, A. 1999: Natural resources, human resources and export
composition: A cross- country perspective. In: Mayer, J, Chamber, B and
Farooq, A (eds). Development Policies in Natural Resource Economies.
Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK.
Wright, G. 1990: The origins of American industrial success,
1879-1940. American Economic Review 80(4): 651-68.
World Economic Forum. 2015: www3.weforum.org/docs/GCR2014 ...
/GCI_Dataset_2006-07-201415.xls, accessed on 21 June 2015.
YELENA KALYUZHNOVA [1] & KERRY PATTERSON [2]
[1] The Centre for Euro-Asian Studies, Henley Business School,
University of Reading, Whiteknights, PO Box 218, Reading, RG6 6AA, UK.
E-mail: y.kaluyzhnova@reading.ac.uk
[2] Department of Economics, University of Reading, Reading, RG6
6AA, UK.
E-mail: k.d.patterson@reading.ac.uk
(1) Further references include Sachs and Warner (1995 [1997],
1997), Lane and Torrnell (1996), Asea and Lahiri (1999), Gylfason et al.
(1999), Rodriguez and Sachs (1999), Sachs and Warner (1999, 2001) and
Rosser (2006).
(2) For further references see Pomfret (1995,2003,2006), Kaser
(1997,2003), Kalyuzhnova (1998, 2002, 2008), Hanson (2002, 2008, 2009),
Aslund (2007) and Rutland (2008).
(3) Here we follow EMP in referring to Et/P, as the real exchange
rate; however, the latter term is usually defined as
[E.sub.t][P.sup.*.sub.t]/[P.sub.t], where [P.sup.*.sub.t] is the
overseas price level, so that the numerator is in effect the cost of a
'unit' of overseas output in domestic currency units relative
to the domestic cost in domestic currency units.
(4) The ARDL approach is parsimonious with respect to the lag
structure compared with VARbased approaches, such as Johansen's
maximum-likelihood method, which are more costly in terms of degrees of
freedom.
Table 1: Caspian economies: Share of oil and gas revenues
in total exports
Country 2001 (%) 2002 (%) 2003 (%) 2004 (%)
Azerbaijan 91 88 86 82
Kazakhstan 53 56 59 63
Russia 50 51 53 53
Turkmenistan 89 90 89 88
Country 2005 (%) 2006 (%) 2007 (%) 2008 (%)
Azerbaijan 76 84 81 97
Kazakhstan 68 67 64 67
Russia 60 61 60 64
Turkmenistan 90 86 91 82
2009 (%) 2010 (%) 2011 (%) 2012 (%)
Azerbaijan 93 94 95 93
Kazakhstan 68 71 70 69
Russia 60 63 64 67
Turkmenistan 70 68 90 93
2013 (%) 2014 (%)
Azerbaijan 93 92
Kazakhstan 75 77
Russia 68 56
Turkmenistan 90 91
Source: http://www.trademap.org/BUateral_TS.aspx
Table 2: Estimates of the long-run coefficients
and diagnostic tests
Variable [y.sup.*.sub.t] [x.sup.o.sub.t]
[[??].sub.1] [[??].sub.1]
Estimate 0.53 0.62
't' [p] 2.99 [0.00] 5.82 [0.00]
Cointegration tests F-statistic W-statistics
8.16 {4.60} 32.62{18.4}
Diagnostic tests Serial correlation Normality
Test statistic [p] 2.62 [0.624] 4.96 [0.09]
Variable
Estimate
't' [p]
Cointegration tests
Diagnostic tests Heteroscedasticity [??]
Test statistic [p] 1.95 [0.163] 0.044
Notes: [p] is the p-value for the null hypothesis that the population
regression coefficient is 0 against the one-sided positive alternative
for [[psi].sub.1] and [[psi].sub.2]; {x} are the respective 95% upper
bound critical values for the test of cointegration; [??] is the
estimated eguation standard error for the ARDL model.