Macroeconomic implications of financial frictions in the euro zone.
Siklos, Pierre L.
INTRODUCTION
The news from Europe is scarcely getting better. The decision by
the European Central Bank (ECB) in September 2014 to provide further
support to stimulate lending in the Eurozone, following earlier such
attempts by the ECB to ease the sovereign debt crisis, is further
indication of the central bank's concern that real economic
activity remains weak. Although, the unemployment rate in the Eurozone
is down slightly from its peak at 12% reached in September 2013, it
remains, as this is written, well-above levels experienced since the
euro was introduced. Germany, the economic powerhouse of the Eurozone
economy in recent years, is forecast to slow down to 1.3% in 2015,
according to the December 2014 Economist Poll of Forecasters down from
earlier forecasts that were more optimistic,
(http://www.economist.com/news/economic-andfinancial-
indicators/21635492-economist- poll-forecasters-december-averages) Real
GDP growth in the other major Eurozone economies of France, Italy, and
Spain is even lower with forecasts of below 1% through 2015. It is worth
adding that real GDP growth forecasts in recent years have tended to be
on the optimistic side. As growth forecasts are perilously close to
negative territory, with little indication that policymakers will loosen
fiscal policy in the foreseeable future, there is added burden on
monetary policy to deliver the Eurozone from its low growth predicament.
The 'global financial crisis' (GFC) of 2008-2009 has
reminded the profession about the connection between credit conditions,
financial stability, and economic performance that were previously
forgotten but have now become an integral part of central bank thinking
in the past few years. As a result, policymakers are now more aware than
ever of the importance of understanding the links between credit market
conditions and real economic activity.
Until recently, the notion that there were frictions in the
financial system that would hamper the monetary transmission mechanism
was dismissed as unnecessary in empirical macromodels. Now, however,
policymakers and academics are searching for ways to quantify the extent
to which these frictions can impact aggregate economic outcomes. This
has led to considerable research of late across the globe. One example
the demonstrates the importance central banks attach to the role of the
financial sectors in macroeconomic outcomes is ECB's
Macro-prudential Research Network (MaRs;
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/home/html/researcher_mars.en.html).
The purpose of this paper is to describe a simple model to
investigate the macroeconomic implications of financial frictions in the
Eurozone. In particular, I argue that a survey of lending standards in
the Eurozone countries is informative about aggregate economic activity
in the single currency area.
The difficulty, as will be explained below, is that the relevant
data remain relatively scarce thereby rendering difficult the estimation
of a more elaborate model specification incorporating credit frictions.
Indeed, the availability of data is further limited since credit
conditions for only a selection of Eurozone members are published. (1)
There exists, however, an interim proxy to overcome the problem, at
least until more ample data become available. Nevertheless, the proxy is
no substitute for more credit standards data.
I am especially interested in the empirical significance and
magnitude of two channels through which lending standards are linked to
the real side of the economy and monetary policy. These are defined as
the real and financial channels of monetary policy. Next, I ask whether
policy rate shocks influence lending standards, and whether these
standards also have an effect on monetary policy? If statistically
significant macroeconomic effects are found, and are robust, then
macro-models need to be augmented with an indicator to proxy financial
frictions.
The paper begins with the observation that a crucial element at
stake in the storm brewing in Europe since 2010 is the connection
between credit availability and real economic conditions. The essence of
the framework is the recognition that 'sentiment', as
represented by how loan officers view the ease or tightness of overall
credit conditions, represents a potentially important element in the
transmission of shocks from the financial sector, notably the crucial
bank lending channel, to the real economy. (2)
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. First, I provide a brief
literature review. I then go on to provide a description of the
framework used to think about how the real and financial sectors of
economies might be linked to each other and how lending standards data
can be potentially informative. The framework recognizes a determinant
of macroeconomic conditions, long known to economists, that credit
availability and monetary policy are intertwined and that both can have
significant effects on the real economy. Crucially, however, it is the
views of lenders that determines how smoothly financial markets function
and their views about whether lending standards are tighter or looser
that have the potential to produce real economic effects.
Next, some suggestive evidence is presented. Briefly, the paper
finds that inclusion of indicators of financial frictions in standard
macromodels is essential. Some of the results also suggest that in
2011-2012, the ECB made financial conditions worse by not only raising
the policy rate but by implementing a very gradual reduction in monetary
conditions over the next 2 years. The paper concludes with a summary and
possible policy implications.
BRIEF LITERATURE REVIEW
While credit availability is believed to affect the real economy
(Blinder and Stiglitz, 1983), the dynamics are quite perplexing since
asymmetric information can lead to rationing, potentially manifesting
itself as a 'non-price' element of credit conditions (Stiglitz
and Weiss, 1981). Credit conditions are also believed to be directly
linked to financial stability (eg, see Taylor, 2012, and references
therein).
The importance of non-price credit conditions for financial
stability has long been deemed critical, as emphasized by Roosa (1951),
Jaffee and Stiglitz (1990), as well as in the Stiglitz and Weiss (1981)
credit rationing model. Fuerst (1994) further refines Roosa's
availability doctrine by defining two distinct components, namely credit
rationing, a common phenomenon in virtually all credit markets, and a
role for monetary policy which can impact the supply of credit. Credit
markets do not reach equilibrium solely on the basis of price. Moral
hazard and adverse selection problems in the presence of imperfect
information (Blanchard and Fischer, 1989) are the usual culprits. These
problems lead credit markets to use a non-price element (eg, lending
standards) to reach equilibrium.
Owens and Schreft (1991) suggest that the monetary policy
authority, at least in the United States, takes the view that, as the
cost of available funds increases, interest rates applied to bank loans
lag changes in non-price lending standards. Therefore, information on
banks' non-price lending standards helps explain the impact that
monetary policy has on the banking sector. Bernanke and Blinder (1992)
empirically demonstrate that a reduction in available funds cause banks
to sell off securities in the short run. However, in the long run,
securities are replenished resulting in a decrease in loans. Hence, it
is important to understand the transmission mechanism between changes in
available funds and loan availability.
Increasingly, central banks rely on surveys of lending conditions.
For example, Murray (2012) highlights the informative role played by the
Bank of Canada's Senior Officer Loan Survey in helping set the
course of monetary policy. A comparable US survey, also called the
Senior Loan Officers Survey, is closely watched by the Fed. In the euro
zone, the Bank Lending Survey (BLS) not only asks about lending
conditions according to the type of loan (eg, commercial, mortgage,
household credit) but also deals with perceptions about the state of
loan demand. The information from these surveys combined with several
other macroeconomic variables can be used to examine, for example, how
changes in lending standards, a proxy for sentiment among issuers of
credit, interact with the rest of the economy.
There has been relatively little research on the influence of loan
officers' views and how the lending standards they enforce might
influence aggregate economic outcomes. De Bondt et al. (2010; also see
references therein) use the Eurozone bank lending survey data to examine
whether there is a connection with aggregate output. Spillover effects
within the eurozone are effectively ignored as is the possibility of a
two-way relationship between bank officers' perceptions and
macroeconomic outcomes. Moreover, their sample ends before the euro area
financial crisis erupts (ie, 2009Q2). There are a few studies for the
United States and Canada (eg, Lown et al, 2000; Lown and Morgan, 2006;
Siklos and Lavender, 2015) but such data have not been widely used
because surveys have only recently been introduced in several countries
(Japan is an exception).
Beyond contagion type effects there exists considerable
interdependence between the advanced industrial economies and their
financial systems (Forbes, 2012). The bottom line then is that the
current macroeconomic challenges faced by the single currency area may
well have potentially large, and negative, economic consequences for the
global economy. Bernanke (2012a), shortly before he stepped down as
Chair of the FOMC, noted the potential for a shock from Europe to
further restrain US economic growth. Indeed, the Fed Chairman goes on to
remark that the resulting '... strains are most problematic for the
Europeans, of course, but through global trade and financial linkages,
the effects of the European situation on the US economy are significant
as well.' (op.cit., p. 17) Approximately 3 months later, Bernanke
(2012) repeated the Fed's concern over developments in Europe while
allowing that the European Central Bank has taken some steps to ease the
burden on sovereigns. 'A prominent risk at present--and a major
source of financial headwinds over the past couple of years--is the
fiscal and financial situation in Europe. This situation, of course, was
not anticipated when the US recovery began in 2009.'
While the now famous declaration in 2012 by the ECB President,
Mario Draghi, (3) that the program to notionally purchase sovereign
Eurozone member state debt under specific conditions, known as the
Outright Monetary Transactions policy, (4) calmed financial markets it
did nothing to reinvigorate economic growth in the single currency area.
By early 2015, the threat of deflation was added to the woes confronting
the ECB and is the proximate cause for the September 2014 program of
long-term refinancing operations, among other new initiatives announced
by the central bank as well as a version of quantitative easing
introduced in January 2015.
As Draghi (2014) points out '(R)estoring a functioning
transmission mechanism, notably in bank lending, is instrumental ...
[it] reaches the final borrowers and thereby supports real incomes,
...'. Loan officers are critical in this process if the ECB's
policies are to succeed.
A SIMPLE FRAMEWORK FOR EXPLORING REAL-FINANCIAL LINKS
By now it is well known that economists have been criticized for
relying on models that fail to consider how shocks from the financial
sector spillover into the real economy. Unfortunately, it is too soon to
rely upon a 'synthesis' model, likely to be accepted by the
vast majority of economists, to describe how these links actually
function.
The cost of borrowing is not only reflected in the interest rate.
There exist non-price elements in borrowing or lending costs (eg,
transactions costs, monitoring costs). One expects a positive
correlation between lending standards and interest rates, since banks
are expected to tighten the non-price element of loans contracts when
interest rates rise. However, the financial crisis in the United States
especially has raised the possibility that standards need not keep pace
with interest rates if supervision is poor or if other incentives exist
to maintain lax standards. It is not surprising then that a growing
number of central banks survey loan officers as a means of determining
how monetary conditions might be reflected in the overall supply of
credit.
As noted above the ECB is a relative newcomer in surveying lending
conditions with publicly available data available only since 2003 (or
2009 in the case of some Eurozone members such as Cyprus and Slovenia).
Nevertheless, as explained in the next section, what the ECB data lacks
in one respect is made up through the scope of the survey and its
attempt to identify demand from supply side considerations in
determining credit standards. This is potentially important because the
loan officer surveys in the United States or Canada do not explicitly
make the distinction between these separate factors. As the ECB's
attempts since 2012 have centered on easing credit conditions the
ability to identify conditions that affect the availability of funds as
opposed to funding needs by firms and households is important. Put
differently, a tightening of credit standards can produce a fall in
loans that may contribute to an economic slowdown. Alternatively, a
reduction in loan demand may well-represent a response to an ongoing
economic slowdown. Whether the problem is an economically significant
one is, of course, an empirical question.
Of course, all surveys suffer from biases. Lown et al. (2000),
however, argue that the Fed's survey is informative in spite of the
potential biases. While central banks, such as the Fed and the Bank of
Canada have explicitly stated that these surveys are useful in their
policy rate deliberations (see Murray, 2012), the information collected
is qualitative in nature, the samples of institutions covered can be
small, and there may well be some reporting biases. Nevertheless, the
balance of the evidence (eg, Lown et al., 2000; Lown and Morgan, 2006)
is that the surveys fairly reflect credit supply conditions. Evidence
from the Eurozone also supports this interpretation. Equally important,
inclusion of loan office survey data in conventional macro models
improves the forecasting performance of these models. (5) Finally, as we
shall show below, there is a strong correlation between the information
content of such surveys and economic growth forecasts.
Conventional macroeconomic models assume that the variables of
interest are endogenous and temporally related in the following manner
[y.sub.t] = [A.sub.0] + [A.sub.1] [y.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
(1)
where y is a vector of variables that include the macroeconomic
time series that summarize the key economic relations of interest to
policymakers. Typically, the contents of the vector would consist of
real GDP, the price level or inflation, commodity or oil prices, and the
central bank's policy rate. Equation 1 also makes clear that the
past history of each one of the variable in y affects all the other
variables in the model, with a lag.
The drawback with the standard macro-model formulation is that,
when the financial sector is believed to have macroeconomic
consequences, Equation 1 will produce misleading inferences as it omits
variables, such as the volume of loans and the loan officer survey
indicator of tightness or ease in credit conditions that define credit
conditions. If we add these omitted variables to the standard model we
can rewrite Equation 1 as follows
[y.sup.*.sub.t] = [A.sub.0] + [A.sub.1] [y.sub.t-1] + [A.sub.2]
[z.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t], (2)
where Equation 1 augmented by a separate set of variables, the
vector z, that are believed to represent credit conditions. Hence,
[y.sup.*.sub.t] = [[y.sub.t], [z.sub.t]]'. Equation 2 is then the
core model that captures the essence of real-financial links in the
economy.
As pointed out above a peculiar constraint faced in estimating
relationships such as (2) above in the Eurozone context is that the
available span of data is rather short in duration while VAR type
specifications can easily use up precious degrees of freedom. Solutions
are, however, available. Suppose that we can take all the relevant time
series and reduce them to two series that capture real and financial
factors in the Eurozone. Under these conditions the dimension of VARs
such (1) or (2) can be significantly reduced. This is accomplished by
estimating the first two principal components of the vector [y.sup.*],
or one like it, and establishing that the resulting series actually
mimic real and financial conditions in the Eurozone. More formally, we
can estimate the relationship between the factors in a VAR framework
which yields
[[GAMMA].sup.j.sub.t] = A(L) [[GAMMA].sup.j.sub.t-1] +
[[eta].sup.j.sub.t] (3)
where [GAMMA] is the vector of real and financial factors for the
Eurozone. Equation 3 is a dynamic factor VAR.
Of course, real and financial factors are unobservable while policy
variables (eg, policy rates) are observable. In another variant we can
instead estimate the following relationship
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
where [[GAMMA].sup.j.sub.t] = {[[phi].sup.R.sub.t],
[[phi].sup.F.sub.t]} are the real (R) and financial (F) factors,
exclusive of observable policy variables, while [X.sub.t], represent the
observable policy variable for the Eurozone, namely the ECB's
policy rate. Equation 4 is a factor augmented VAR (FAVAR) model. (6)
DATA AND STYLIZED FACTS
All data are quarterly for the sample 2000Q1 to 2014Q1, inclusive.
Real GDP, prices, the volume of credit, the ECB's policy rate as
well as other interest rates, were obtained from the ECB's
Statistical Warehouse (http://sdw.ecb.europa.eu/). Some interest rate
data (ie, the long-term interest rate and a short-term interest rate)
were collected from the IMF's International Financial Statistics
(August 2014 CD-ROM version). (7) The proxy for commodity prices is oil
prices as measure by the per barrel price of West Texas Intermediate
(WTI) crude oil. (8) This series is obtained from FRED II, the data base
of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
(http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/). (9) Real GDP growth forecasts
also play an important role in the analysis. Monthly data, from
Consensus Economics, were converted into the quarterly frequency via
simple arithmetic averaging. Finally, since the sample being
investigated is, arguably, a fairly turbulent one, I also consider an
indicator of policy uncertainty based on the measure originally
developed for the United States by Baker et al. (2013). They have
constructed a version for Europe
(http://www.policyuncertainty.com/europe_monthly.htral).
In what follows the frictions resulting from imperfect information
are proxied by the standards for lending as viewed from the perspective
of the bank lending survey conducted by the ECB in individual eurozone
countries since 2003 (http://sdw.ecb.europa.eu/browse.do?node=9484577).
The euro area's the Bank Lending Survey (also see Berg et al.,
2005; De Bondt et al., 2010) is comparable to the ones conducted in
Canada and the United States but, arguably, more comprehensive. For
example, over 80 institutions in the euro area have been surveyed since
2003. Initially, 40% of the euro area was covered by the survey. Given
differences in banking structures and relative sizes, the distribution
of the survey is not uniform and the individual euro zone member country
data are weighted (see Berg et al, 2005; Tables 1 and 2).
Respondents are asked to provide an answer to questions about
lending standards and the availability of funds on a scale from
'tightened considerably' to 'eased considerably'. In
addition to loans to enterprises the survey asks similar questions
concerning loans to finance the purchase of housing and for the
provision of household credit. While the series broadly parallel each
other (results not shown), the evidence presented below relies on the
survey that covers enterprises. The survey also asks about loan
officers' expectations of lending conditions over the next 3
months. As this version of the question is forward looking and,
therefore, more compatible with economic explanations of possible
real-financial links, in what follows, I rely exclusively on this
version of the survey.
There is an important limitation with this data. While data for the
economically most important euro zone members are published those from
key periphery members are not. (10) The ECB make available BLS data
since 2003 for only eight Eurozone economies. They are: Austria,
Germany, Spain, France, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, and Portugal.
Data for a few other economies (eg, Cyprus, Slovenia) are only available
since 2009 or later and, hence, are too short to be useful for
estimation purposes. As this study investigates the impact of credit
conditions in the Eurozone the individual demand and supply indexes are
separately aggregated by estimating the first principal component for
the respective series. (11) Finally, the difference between Supply and
Demand measures of the ease or tightness of credit standards and the
availability of funds is used to proxy financial frictions in the
Eurozone.
Although all of the estimates reported below are, generally
speaking, the same when I rely on the shorter sample relying on BLS
data, there is a strong correlation between the proposed financial
frictions proxy and one year ahead forecasts of real GDP growth (see
below). This allows me to report results for the full sample which is
less affected by events since 2008, dominated by the GFC, soon followed
by the 2010-2012 sovereign debt crisis in the Eurozone.
Bank loans in euros are deflated by the harmonized index of
consumer prices (HICP) to obtain a real measure of the volume of credit.
Growth rates are obtained by evaluating the log difference of the
variables in question (eg, prices) and multiplying the result by 100.
The BLS data, and the volume of credit, are assumed to capture credit
conditions in the Eurozone.
Figure 1 illustrates some of the potential sources of differences
between the United States and the Eurozone as far as credit conditions
are concerned. (12) The volume of loans since 1999 is plotted in the top
portion of the figure while the bottom portion displays the policy rates
for the ECB and the US Federal Reserve. Whereas the volume of loans in
the United States has recovered somewhat from the depths reached in the
aftermath of the GFC loans in the Eurozone display a downward trend from
the peak reached in 2008. This is briefly interrupted twice as the world
economy began to emerge from the GFC in 2009 only to experience another
shock as the 2010 Eurozone sovereign debt crisis took hold. The bottom
portion of the Figure reveals that while the pattern of policy rate
setting is comparable across both central banks the US Federal Reserve
appears to have been more aggressive both in raising interest rates
before the onset of the GFC and in lowering them relatively more quickly
in reaching the zero lower bound by 2008 where they have remained
unchanged ever since. In contrast, the ECB not only raised policy rates
as the crisis in Europe erupted but did not reduce its policy rate to
near zero until early 2015.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 2 provides some illustrations from the ECB's BLS. Data
from Germany, Cyprus, and Italy serve to motivate the usefulness of the
demand and supply survey measures. (13) The plots reveal the extent to
which credit demand and supply conditions are balanced in the three
economies considered. It is clear that credit conditions experience
persistent imbalances. In Germany's case demand conditions were
perceived to be noticeably tighter than supply roughly from 2005 to 2007
and again during the Eurozone's sovereign debt crisis of 2010-2012.
The extent to which credit frictions rise significantly is also apparent
in Cyprus in 2012 and continue to date. Of course, Cyprus' case is
notable not only for its debt crisis but thanks to the imposition of
capital controls. It is visually apparent how supply conditions tighten
sharply beginning in 2010 while demand for loans begin to soften around
the same time. Finally, In Itay's case imbalances do not appear to
persist and credit conditions do not appear to either tighten or loosen
very much throughout much of the sample. This is perhaps a reflection of
that country's low economic growth trap.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
A few additional insights about the usefulness of BLS data are
relegated to Table 1. The top portion of the Table provides some
insights into the challenges faced in implementing a single monetary
policy across diverse Eurozone members. The correlations indicate some
fragmentation in loan demand conditions between Germany and the other
Eurozone economies as perceived by senior loan officers. For example,
tightness or ease of loan demand in Germany is uncorrelated with those
in France, the Eurozone's second largest economy, as well as those
of Ireland and Portugal. The latter is unsurprising given that both of
these countries were directly implicated in the sovereign debt crisis.
Elsewhere, the correlations are statistically significant but hardly
very high. Turning to the correlations in supply conditions all the
correlations shown are statistically significant. The results combine to
suggest that there is a bigger mismatch on supply conditions than in
demand conditions, and this reflects the fact that there are local
factors as well as Eurozone-wide factors in explaining credit
conditions. The bottom portion of Table 1 highlights the strong
correlation between loan demand conditions and 1 year ahead forecasts of
real GDP growth in the Eurozone, at least for the largest Eurozone
economies. In contrast the correlations on the supply side are weak to
insignificant. Both of these results combine to support the notion that
real GDP growth forecasts can serve as a useful proxy of credit
conditions paralleling those reported in the BLS. As there is better
data availability for the forecast series the results reported below
take advantage of this stylized fact.
ECONOMETRIC ESTIMATES
A principal components analysis is used to extract the common, or
Eurozone-wide, feature of loan demand and supply conditions. The
difference between the two serves then as the proxy for financial
frictions which, alongside the volume of loans, defines credit frictions
in the Eurozone. The top portion of Figure 3 depicts the results of this
analysis. Financial frictions, shown in the bottom portion of Figure 3,
are seen to be at their lowest in the years preceding the GFC, that is,
in the dying days of the so-called Great Moderation. There is a sharp
rise in frictions during the GFC which dwarfs that experience during the
height of the Eurozone sovereign debt crisis. It is worth recalling that
policymakers in Europe at the time felt that the GFC would have few
repercussions on Europe. (14) Moreover, and in spite of the sovereign
debt crisis, the ECB did intervene, albeit some felt belatedly, and this
may partially explain the fact that financial frictions rose sharply in
2010-2012 but not to the same degree as in 2008-2009. It is also notable
that frictions only begin to fall to levels reached in 2004-2006 after
Mario Draghi, the ECB President, made his now famous announcement in
2012 referred to above.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Figure 4 (a) shows a selection of impulse response functions
linking inflation or financial frictions to the growth rate of real GDP
in the Eurozone. The results are based on estimates of Equation 2 which
augments the standard macro VAR with variables that proxy credit
conditions. (15) The plots, and the confidence bands (16) around the
point estimates indicate how a shock, defined as a one percent (or one
standard deviation) rise in either inflation or the proxy for financial
frictions described above affects real GDP growth over a 10 quarter
period. The top plot illustrates the negative connection between
inflation and real GDP growth, reflecting both central bankers and
academic views of the trade-off between these two variables. The bottom
two plots show that a rise in the ECB's policy rate leads to a rise
in financial frictions although the effect appears significant only over
4 quarters. The bottom plot reveals that a rise financial frictions
equivalent here to a tightening of lending standards has a negative
impact on real GDP growth in the Eurozone. Note, however, that the
impact is short-lived since, after 2 quarters the impulse responses no
longer appear to be significant. In any event, there is a clear
empirical link between credit conditions and economic activity that
conventional models (ie, such as Equation 1) would have missed. As I am
unable to provide separate estimates for the core versus the periphery
economies in the Eurozone a second best solution is to perform the
following counterfactual experiment. Suppose that the frictions proxy
for the entire Eurozone is replaced with one constructed for Ireland, a
country severely impacted by the crisis. This experiment is not entirely
satisfactory as the other variables in the model are assumed to remain
unchanged. Nevertheless, the results shown in Figure 4(b) reveal that
frictions would be far more sensitive to inflation under this scenario
than under the one that relies for data from the entire Eurozone. It is
conceivable then that a loosening of frictions, via higher inflation,
would have a more beneficial impact on the financially hardest hit
Eurozone economies. The remaining impulse responses are broadly similar
to the ones shown in Figure 4(a) although a policy rate rise appears to
modestly loosen frictions while frictions have a slightly longer lasting
negative impact on lending when Irish standards are applied. The latter
result illustrates the potential for frictions to severely curtail
lending while the former result opens the possibility for traditional
policy tightening to be decoupled, albeit briefly, from frictions.
One may well-wonder how resilient the foregoing results are to
alternative models, especially since samples are short. As a result, I
examine models where factors replace some of the observables in the
relationships of interest. Table 2 and Figure 5 provide details of the
extraction of real and financial factors from the data set. Table 2
provides the factor loadings based on the individual country estimates
of lending standards. As the latent variable represents credit
conditions the factor loadings essentially reveal the strength of the
relationship between our Eurozone proxy and individual country
conditions. In the case of both demand and supply factors the connection
is fairly strong although the loadings are clearly higher on the supply
side than on the demand side. However, since it is the supply side that
can be problematic for jump-starting growth in the Eurozone the results
do suggest that the impact of constraints on the availability of credit
because of the tightness of supply is widespread across the single
currency area.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
The bottom of the same Table asks which one of the observables
contributes most to explaining our proxy for real and financial
conditions in the Eurozone. It is immediately evident that some
observables impact both the real and financial factors proxy shown in
Figure 5. The ECB's policy rate, the volume of bank loans, the term
spread, inflation and policy uncertainty all have a sizeable weight on
determining financial conditions. Similarly, inflation, the policy rate,
the term spread, policy uncertainty and, of course, real GDP growth are
all critical determinants of real economic conditions in the Eurozone.
Turning to Figure 5 the real factor captures quite clearly the double
recession that impacted the Eurozone in 2008-2009 and again in
2011-2012. Similarly, we see from the bottom plot in Figure 5 that
financial conditions were at their worst in 2008-2009 with another sharp
rise in 2011-2012. The latter was not as pronounced as the one
associated with the GFC. However, as noted above, the ECB did eventually
act, on more than one occasion, to prevent further deteriorations in
financial conditions.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Once the real and financial factors are obtained via principal
components analysis we estimate the factor-augmented VAR, or FAVAR,
represented by Equation 4. Figure 6 shows a selection of impulse
response functions based on the FAVAR model. Figure 6 uses the observed
ECB policy as the observable monetary policy variable. (17) There are
several interesting findings from the impulse responses. First, there is
some persistence in both factors and in the policy rate. This is to be
expected as most macro factors are slow moving. Second, improvements in
real economic conditions (ie, the real factor) results in an improvement
of financial conditions. (18) Next, we see that neither real nor
financial conditions respond to changes in the policy rate. This
reflects the apparent deterioration in the usual channel of monetary
policy that led the ECB, as did other central banks, to rely on
unconventional means to influence the stance of monetary policy.
Nevertheless, it is also the case that deteriorating financial
conditions is positively associated with a rise in the ECB's policy
rate. This suggests that monetary policy did not react appropriately to
changing financial conditions. Whether this result reflects the
criticism levelled at the ECB during 2011 when the policy rate was
increased together with its gradual reduction until the zero lower bound
is reached in mid-2014 (see Figure 1) is, of course, unclear.
Nevertheless this is a plausible interpretation. Together, the above
results make a strong case for an explicit recognition of financial
conditions in a macroeconomic model.
CONCLUSIONS
By exploring how real and financial shocks from in the euro zone
impacted real economic growth in the single currency area the present
study highlights that models which fail to explicitly account for
changing credit conditions miss an important channel through which
aggregate economic conditions can change.
The present study offers some estimates of these effects. A small
macroeconomic model for the eurozone that explicitly incorporates
financial sector influences is estimated. Absent changes in the
regulatory or general economic environment, together with present day
limitations on the ability to offset shocks through fiscal or
conventional monetary policy instruments, policymakers can only hope to
rely on more effective use of 'guidance' to manage
expectations. Although some have argued that guidance is useful only in
'exceptional' times (eg, Carney, 2012) there is no reason, a
priori, why should be the case. Whether times are normal or not, the
central bank must explain itself. What it must avoid is to fall into the
trap of sticking to an inflexible rule. Some of the results presented
above suggest that it is possible that in 2011- 2012 the ECB made
financial conditions worse by not only raising the policy rate but
thanks to a very gradual reduction in monetary conditions over the next
2 years.
Of course, the estimates shown above also face a number of
challenges before they can be considered definitive. First, the sample
considered is relatively short. Second, the preferred proxy for credit
conditions, namely data from the ECB's Bank Lending Survey is not
only available for a fairly short sample (a little over a decade for the
core Eurozone economies) it is incomplete as there is no published data
for several Eurozone member countries. Finally, even though a variety of
specifications were considered the sample is simply too brief to
reliably test for structural breaks or sub-sample estimation. These
considerations must await future developments and research.
Acknowledgements
Comments and suggestions by conference participants and an
anonymous referee are gratefully acknowledged.
REFERENCES
Baker, SR, Bloom, N and Davis, SJ. 2013: Measuring economic policy
uncertainty. Working paper, Stanford University: Stanford, Calif, May.
Berg, J, van Rixtel, A, Ferrando, A, de Bondt, G and Scopel, S.
2005: The Bank Lending Survey for the Euro Area. Occasional paper no.
23, February, European Central Bank: ECB, Frankfurt.
Bemanke, B. 2012: The Economic Recovery and Economic Policy. New
York Economic Club, 20 November, available at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20121120a.htm.
Bemanke, B. 2012a: Monetary Policy Since the Onset of the Crisis.
Remarks delivered at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium,
Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 31 August, Federal Reserve bank of Kansas City,
Kansas City.
Bernanke, BS and Blinder, AS. 1992: The federal funds rate and the
channels of monetary transmission. American Economic Review 83.4(1992):
901-921.
Blanchard, OJ and Fischer, S. 1989: Lectures on macroeconomics. The
MIT Press: Cambridge.
Blinder, A and Stiglitz, J. 1983: Money, credit constraints and
economic activity. American Economic Review 73(May): 297-302.
Carney, M. 2012: Guidance. Remarks at the CFA Society, Toronto, 11
December, available at http://
www.bankofcanada.ca/wp-content/uploads/2012/12/remarks-111212.pdf.
De Bondt, G, Maddaloni, A, Peydro, J-L and Scopel, S. 2010: The
euro area bank lending survey matters: Empirical evidence for credit and
output growth. ECB working paper 1160, February, ECB, Frankfurt.
Draghi, M. 2014: Introductory remarks at the EP's Economic and
Monetary Affairs Committee, 22 September, European Central Bank,
Frankfurt, https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/
2014/html/sp140922.en.html.
Forbes, K. 2012: The big 'C': Identifying and mitigating
contagion, in the Changing Policy Landscape, Proceedings of the 2012
Jackson Hole Symposium, Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City, pp. 23-87.
Fuerst, TS. 1994: The availability doctrine. Journal of Monetary
Economics 34: 429-443.
Jaffee, D and Stiglitz, JE. 1990: Credit rationing. In: Friedman,
BM and Hahn, FH (eds). Handbook of Monetary Economics: Volume Two. North
Holland: Amsterdam, pp. 838-888.
Lown, C, Morgan, DP and Rohatgi, S. 2000: 'Listening to loan
officers: The impact of commercial credit standards on lending and
output.' Federal reserve bank of New York. Economic Policy Review
6(2): 1-16.
Lown, C and Morgan, DP. 2006: The credit cycle and the business
cycle: New findings using the loan officer opinion survey. Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking 38(6): 1575-1597.
Murray, J. 2012: Monetary Policy Decision-Making at the Bank of
Canada, available at http://www
.bankofcanada.ca/2012/05/speeches/monetary-policy-decision-making/,
accessed 22 January 2015.
Owens, RE and Schreft, SL. 1991: Survey evidence of tighter credit
conditions: What does it mean? Economic Review 77(2): 29-34.
Roosa, RV. 1951: Interest rates and the central bank. In: Money,
Trade and Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of J. H. Williams. Palgrave
Macmillan: New York, pp. 207-295.
Siklos, PL. 2014: The 111-Wind That Blows from the Eurozone:
Implications for Canada's Economy. C.D. Howe Institute Commentary
No. 402, March, Toronto.
Siklos, PL and Lavender, B. 2015: The credit cycle and the business
cycle in Canada and the US: Two solitudes? Canadian Public Policy, in
press.
Stiglitz, JE and Weiss, A. 1981: Credit rationing in markets with
imperfect information. American Economic Review 71(3): 393-410.
Taylor, JB. 2012: Monetary policy rules work and discretion
doesn't: A tale of two eras. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking
44(September): 1017-1032.
PIERRE L SIKLOS
Department of Economics, Wilfrid Laurier University, 75 University
Ave., Waterloo, ON, Canada N2L 3C5.
Table 1: Correlations: Loan surveys, demand,
supply, and GDP growth forecasts
A. Pairwise correlations of lending standards
with germany and within the eurozone
Economy Demand Supply
Austria 0.35 * 0.61 *
Spain 0.43 * 0.46 *
France 0.20 0.49 *
Ireland 0.24 0.52 *
Italy 0.39 * 0.57 *
Netherlands 0.28 (+) 0.70 *
Portugal 0.14 0.38 *
Eurozone-wide (a) 0.68 * -0.26+
B. Correlations between real GDP growth forecasts
and BLS Survey
Country Demand Supply
Germany 0.40 * -0.31 *
Austria 0.62 * -0.46 *
Spain 0.57 * -0.12
France 0.41 * -0.18
Ireland 0.47 * -0.18
Italy 0.57 * -0.27 (+)
Netherlands 0.68 * -0.42 *
Portugal 0.15 -0.31 *
(a) correlation is between Eurozone-wide lending standards
and real GDP growth forecasts (proxy for expected future
economic conditions).
Notes: Simple correlation coefficient. Loan Survey, 3 months
forward for enterprises, GDP growth forecast is the one year
forecast for real GDP growth in the respective economies
considered. * Means statistically significant at least at
the 5% level of significance (+, 10% level).
Table 2: Factor loadings for principal components analysis
A. Demand and supply loan standards
Country Demand Supply
standards standards
Austria 0.72 0.62
Germany 0.46 0.90
Spain 0.90 0.84
France 0.56 0.91
Ireland 0.75 0.60
Italy 0.47 0.68
Netherlands 0.65 0.64
Portugal 0.34 0.74
B. Real and financial factors
Observable Real Financial
factor factor
Real GDP growth 0.77 0.08
Inflation 0.28 0.46
Oil prices 0.37 -0.05
Policy rate 0.76 0.62
Real GDP growth 0.99 0.01
forecasts
Volume of bank loans 0.15 0.75
Term spread -0.46 -0.84
Policy uncertainty -0.30 -0.49
Note: The top table shows the factor loadings for the first
principal component for the demand and supply standards
series, respectively. The series in the bottom table are
used to extract the first 2 principal components. Figure 5
plots the resulting real and financial factors.