Breaking the curse of Sisyphus: an empirical analysis of post-conflict economic transitions.
Cevik, Serhan ; Rahmati, Mohammad
INTRODUCTION
Since World War II, intra-state armed conflicts have become the
most common type of aggression across the world according the UCDP/PRIO
Armed Conflict Dataset (Figure l). (1) Countries emerging from such a
conflict struggle to break the curse of Sisyphus, with 20% relapsing
into a subsequent conflict in the first year and 40% within 5 years
after the end of conflict. Hence, understanding the causes and
consequences of civil conflict remains an important objective in the
quest to achieve sustainable sociopolitical reconciliation and economic
development. This paper makes a novel contribution to the literature by
estimating a forward-looking measure of conflict recurrence risk and
including it as an explanatory variable in analyzing post-conflict
growth dynamics. We adopt a logistic regression approach and model the
probability of conflict recurrence with the latest available information
in each period, while controlling for unobserved fixed effects in a
non-linear probability model for the first time in the conflict
literature.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
According to the UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset covering 146
episodes of civil conflict in 94 countries over the period 1960-2010,
real GDP per capita growth accelerated after the end of a conflict, with
an average of 1.5% a year over the subsequent 5 years, and shows
significant cross-country variation, ranging from--10% in Liberia to 20%
in Bosnia and Herzegovina. Our empirical model explains these variations
in post-conflict growth through a broad set of explanatory variables
including the estimated risk of conflict recurrence, duration and
intensity of the conflict, demographic characteristics, measures of
human capital, geographic variables and natural resource endowments,
macroeconomic conditions, external factors, and measures of political
regime and governance quality. The key empirical finding presented in
this paper is that the estimated risk of conflict recurrence has a
statistically significant and economically large effect on post-conflict
growth dynamics. A 1% increase in the probability of conflict recurrence
in the subsequent period is associated with lower real GDP per capita
growth by 10%.
The other main findings are broadly in line with the literature.
Human capital and institutions have positive and statistically
significant effects on post-conflict growth, while natural resource
dependence appears to cause a double curse of higher risk of conflict
recurrence and lower growth, compared with other countries with a more
diversified economic structure. Ethnic fractionalization is another
significant factor with negative influence on the strength of
post-conflict growth. Global economic conditions matter for
post-conflict recovery, especially for countries that are more open and
integrated with the rest of the world. Finally, contrary to popular
expectations, we do not find UN peacekeeping operations, foreign aid and
IMF-supported economic programs to have significant effect on
post-conflict growth. Altogether, the empirical results presented in
this paper call for a framework centered on three main pillars,
implementing growth-enhancing policies, reforming dysfunctional
institutions, and addressing urgent needs, to reduce the risk of
conflict recurrence and pave the way to broad-based, sustainable
economic growth after the end of a conflict.
A BRIEF OVERVIEW OF THE LITERATURE
This paper connects two broad strands of the literature: (1) the
cross-country differences in economic development and (2) the causes and
consequences of civil conflict. The vast literature on the determinants
of economic growth concludes that there is no single cause of
cross-country variations in growth performance. Instead, a wide spectrum
of factors, from geography to factors of production to natural resources
to institutions, and the interactions between various factors influence
economic growth. In particular, Knack and Keefer (1995), Hall and Jones
(1999), Engerman and Sokoloff (2000), Acemoglu et al. (2001), Acemoglu
et al. (2004), and Acemoglu and Johnson (2005), among other scholars,
demonstrate that institutions are one of the most important sources of
cross-country differences in economic growth. However, while the quality
of institutional arrangements is among the fundamental determinants of
cross-country differences in macroeconomic performance, institutions may
well be shaped by a broad range of factors including geographic
conditions, demographic composition, and the structure of factor
endowments. A number of studies, led by Sachs and Warner (1997) and
Gallup et al. (1998), take into account geographic variables and find
that countries located in the tropics tend to grow at a slower pace than
those in more temperate climates.
The theoretical literature has focused mainly on the pivotal
question of why civil conflict occurs in spite of the prohibitively high
cost of rebellion, and draws attention to explanations like information
asymmetries and the absence of the rule of law (Grossman, 1991;
Skaperdas, 1992; Hirshleifer, 1995; Sandler, 2000; Sambanis, 2001;
Fearon and Laitin, 2003; Collier and Hoeffler, 2004). On the empirical
side, a burgeoning range of studies has aimed to discover the causes of
civil conflict that have persistent and damaging effects on economic
development, mainly through the destruction of institutional and
physical infrastructure, the loss of human capital, and heightened
uncertainty making investment riskier (Collier, 1999; Nafzinger et al,
2000; Addison et al, 2002; Collier and Hoeffler, 2002; Elbadawi et al,
2008).
There is also a large literature on the relationship between
political institutions and civil conflict. Sambanis (2001), Hegre et al.
(2001) and Reynal-Querol (2002, 2005), for example, find that partial
democracies are more prone to civil conflict than are full democracies
and autocracies. Ethnic fractionalization is also considered to be an
important factor in explaining the cross-country differences in growth
as well as the variation in social tensions heightening the risk of
conflict. While Fearon and Laitin (2003) argue that ethnic, or
religious, heterogeneity has no bearing on the incidence of civil
conflict, after controlling for per capita income, Esteban et al (2012)
show that measures of ethnic and social fragmentation are significant
correlates of the occurrence of civil conflict. These issues are also
intimately connected to the issue of trust and its impact on
post-conflict economic activity (Cassar et al, 2013; Grosjean, 2014). On
the whole, the literature links the incidence of civil conflict to low
levels of income with a skewed distribution, slow and volatile growth,
dysfunctional institutions, ethnic fragmentation, and demographic and
geographic conditions. (2)
DATA OVERVIEW
The empirical analysis utilizes a comprehensive set of conflict
data--encompassing 146 cases of civil conflict in 94 countries across
the world over the period 1960-2010--extracted from the latest version
of the UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset. The UCDP/PRIO dataset
characterizes four different types of conflicts according to location
and participants: (1) extra-systemic armed conflicts, (2) inter-state
armed conflicts, (3) intra-state armed conflicts, and (4)
internationalized intra-state armed conflicts. In this paper, we
concentrate on episodes of internal armed conflict including all three
categories based on the level of intensity: low-intensity conflict with
at least 25 battle-related deaths a year and fewer than 1,000
battle-related deaths during the course of the conflict; cumulatively
high-intensity conflict with an accumulated total of at least 1,000
battle-related deaths, but fewer than 1,000 in any given year; and high
intensity conflict with at least 1,000 battle-related deaths a year.
Although low-intensity conflicts may not necessarily have a measurable
impact on economic activity, we still include such episodes in the
sample to develop a broader understanding of civil conflicts.
In addition to our estimated measure of the risk of conflict
recurrence, the growth regressions consider a broad range of variables:
these include the initial level of real GDP per capita at the end of the
conflict; human capital as measured by educational attainments;
demographic variables such as population density, the size of the youth
bulge, and ethnic fractionalization; geographic variables and climatic
conditions; natural resource dependence; terms of trade; global real GDP
growth; degree of trade openness; international factors such as foreign
aid, IMF-supported programs, and UN peacekeeping operations; and
institutional variables such as the type of political regime and the
number of cabinet changes.
The majority of the tests for unit root or stationarity in panel
data that are widely used in the empirical literature assume a balanced
panel dataset (Levin et al, 2002; and Im et al, 2003). In our study,
however, the panel dataset of post-conflict growth episodes is
unbalanced because of frequent occurrences of civil conflict, making
most of these tests for unit root in panel data inapplicable. One
prominent exception is the approach proposed by Choi (2001) that
introduce a Fisher-type unit root test for even unbalanced panel
datasets. The results, available upon request, show that there is no
evidence for non-stationarity in our panel dataset.
EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY AND RESULTS
To avoid the potential endogeneity of the explanatory variables and
unobserved country-specific effects, Holz-Eakin et al. (1988) and
Arellano and Bond (1991) developed the generalized method of moments
(GMM) estimator for dynamic panel regressions using the lagged levels of
the regressors as instruments for the equation in differences. This
approach, however, suffers from small sample bias when the time series
is short and exhibits high persistency over time, which makes the lagged
levels weak instruments for subsequent differences. These shortcomings
of the difference-GMM estimator--documented by Arellano and Bover (1995)
and Blundell and Bond (1998)--are more pronounced when a approaches one
and/or [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] high.
Although using multiple-year intervals or averages has become a standard
procedure in the empirical literature, this reduces the number of
observations and does not effectively mitigate persistency in the data.
Furthermore, if the variance of country-specific characteristics
increases relative to transitory shocks, the standard method produces
weak results. Because of the dominant impact of unobserved
heterogeneities in growth during and after a conflict, it is likely that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] will be greater than
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. In addition,
post-conflict data are relatively short, partly because of a series of
conflict recurrences.
As the difference-GMM estimator is not a suitable approach to
studying post-conflict economic growth, we follow the system-GMM
approach proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond
(1998), which brings together the equation in differences and the
equation in levels in a system of equations and utilizes both lagged
levels and differences of the regressors as instruments. Accordingly,
the system-GMM estimator performs better with highly persistent data and
allows us to obtain more precise estimates. We operationalize a modified
version of the standard neoclassical growth model in the following form:
[DELTA][y.sub.it] = [g.sub.it] = [alpha][g.sub.it-1] +
[beta]C[R.sub.it] + [gamma][Z.sub.it] + [[eta].sub.i] +
[[epsilon].sub.it] (1)
where [DELTA][y.sub.it] is the growth rate of real GDP per capita
for country i and t periods after the end of the conflict (ie time t = 0
denotes the end of conflict); [g.sub.i,t-1] lis the lagged growth rate
at the time t--1; C[R.sub.it] is the risk of conflict recurrence over
the subsequent period after the end of the conflict, which we estimate
according the below-outlined approach; [Z.sub.it] represents a vector of
variables; [[eta].sub.i] are unobserved country-specific effects; and
[[epsilon].sub.it] is the error term. The empirical method used in this
paper makes following assumptions:
E[[[eta].sub.i]] = 0, E[[[epsilon].sub.it]] = 0,
E[[[eta].sub.i][[epsilon].sub.it]] = 0 (2)
We also assume that transitory shocks are serially uncorrelated (ie
E[[[epsilon].sub.it][[epsilon].sub.i,s]] = 0 for all s[not equal to]t)
and initial conditions are predetermined (ie
E[[g.sub.i1][[epsilon].sub.it]] = 0). These assumptions, in turn,
provide L= (T-l)(T-2)/2 moments conditions to estimate Equation 1:
E[[g.sub.i,t-s][DELTA][[epsilon].sub.it]] = O for t = 3, ..., T and
s [greater than or equal to] 2 (3)
The assumption of E([u.sub.i3][DELTA][g.sub.i2]) = 0 improves the
performance of the estimator. Using the standard GMM assumption, this
condition can be reduced to E([[eta].sub.i] [DELTA][g.sub.i2])--0, which
is satisfied for stationary series as long as
E([g.sub.iI]\[[eta].sub.i]) = [c.sub.i]. This implies that deviations
from the initial conditions are uncorrelated with [c.sub.i], itself.
Although Bond et al. (2001), among others, employ this methodology to
estimate the level of GDP, assuming E([[eta].sub.i][DELTA][y.sub.i2]) =
0, we believe this condition may be violated in estimating post-conflict
growth dynamics, as it implies that the initial rate of growth
([DELTA][y.sub.i2]) is unrelated to unobserved fixed effects. On the
other hand, assuming the change in post-conflict growth is orthogonal to
[[eta].sub.i] provides a weaker assumption for post-conflict recoveries.
We therefore use the above-outlined moment conditions and employ the
system-GMM methodology to reduce the potential bias in estimation and
generate consistent and efficient parameter estimates.
ESTIMATING THE RISK OF CONFLICT RECURRENCE
The principal contribution of this paper is the estimation of a
forward-looking measure of conflict recurrence risk and its use as an
explanatory variable in estimating the determinants of post-conflict
economic performance. Quantifying the relationship between the
probability of conflict recurrence and the strength of post-conflict
growth is a challenge. There are different modeling approaches in the
early warning/leading indicators literature; these include linear
regression and limited dependent variable probit/ logit techniques
developed to test the statistical significance of various indicators in
determining the incidence of an event risk. (3) In this paper, we adopt
a logistic regression approach and model the risk of conflict recurrence
with the latest available information in each period, while controlling
for unobserved fixed effects in a nonlinear probability model for the
first time in the literature.
The risk of an event at time t+1 can be measured by estimating its
distribution given the available information at time t. Measuring the
risk of conflict recurrence over the subsequent years by using proxy
variables would yield biased estimates mainly because there is no good
proxy to convey forward-looking risk expectations, especially in many
developing and low-income countries that have experienced episodes of
civil conflict. Therefore, we model the risk of conflict recurrence with
the latest available information in each period by imposing more
structure on a general model of conflict and defining risk as the
probability of conflict recurrence in the next period. Assuming conflict
is a latent variable, the model of hostility in country i at time t
([h.sub.it]) becomes as a function of:
[h.sub.it] = [phi][X.sub.it] + [v.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.it] (4)
where [X.sub.it] is a set of independent variables contributing to
the level of enmity at time t in country i and [v.sub.i] represents
fixed effects for country i. Although the level of hostility is
unobservable, we can still estimate Equation 6 since conflict incidence
is an observable variable, assuming that it happens when the level of
hostility passes a certain threshold: (4)
[cr.sub.it] = 1 if [h.sub.it] > 0 and [cr.sub.it] = 0 if
[h.sub.it]<0 (5)
If [epsilon] has a distribution of [DELTA], a conflict occurs with
the probability of 1-[DELTA] ([phi][X.sub.it]+[v.sub.i]). These binary
observations provide enough variation to estimate [beta] in Equation 1 -
a well-established exercise in the literature for characterizing the
causes of civil conflict. At the same time, the forward-looking
probability of conflict recurrence can be defined as:
E[[r.sub.it]] = probability ([cr.sub.i,t+1] = 1|[X.sub.it]: [phi],
[v.sub.i]) (6)
On the basis of this framework, the perceived risk of conflict
recurrence can be calculated as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
Therefore, risk can be measured by the probability of a conflict at
the next period given the information set available at time t in country
i ([X.sub.it]), and the above equation can be estimated by using the
following likelihood estimator:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
One major advantage of our method, compared to earlier studies, is
that we control for unobserved fixed effects ([v.sub.i]) and therefore
deal with unobserved variables that may contribute to the incidence of
relapsing into subsequent conflict. Following Wooldridge (2005),
assuming that the distribution of unobserved fixed effects [v.sub.i] is
by a distribution [OMEGA](.;[pi]) the likelihood estimator becomes a
function of:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
For this exercise, we assume [bar.[DELTA]] has the logistic
functional form as exp ([phi][X.sub.it] + [[upsilon].sub.i])/1 +
exp([phi][X.sub.it] + [[upsilon].sub.i]) and [[upsilon].sub.i] is
distributed N(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[upsilon]]). It is worth mentioning
that a significant and economically large [[sigma].sub.v] shows that
ignoring these unobserved fixed effects may lead to biased results.
Our baseline model for the risk of conflict recurrence utilizes the
level and growth rate of real GDP per capita and whether the country had
a civil conflict before. The estimated coefficients for Equation 9,
presented in the first column of Table 1, indicate that the variance of
unobserved fixed effects ([[sigma].sub.[upsilon]) is significant in all
cases. In other words, country-specific effects are crucial in measuring
conflict recurrence risk. Another important conceptual distinction
between this paper and earlier studies is the timing of the model, as we
infer the risk of conflict recurrence at time t+1 by using the available
information set at time t, which is an abstraction and not burdened by
the problem of endogeneity often present in conflict regressions. To
check the robustness of our estimations, we develop an alternative
measure of conflict recurrence risk without relying on the level and
growth of domestic per capita income, presented in the second column of
Table 1, and find that the estimated risk of conflict recurrence remains
robust.
According to the baseline model, the coefficients on the level and
growth rate of real GDP per capita are -0.32 and -1.72, respectively,
which are equivalent to the marginal effects of -0.02 and -0.11. In
other words, a 1% increase in the level of real GDP per capita or in its
rate of growth would lower the probability of conflict recurrence in the
subsequent period by 2 % and 11%, respectively, in that country. One of
the key factors in determining the risk of conflict recurrence, however,
is whether the country had a conflict before. The coefficient on the
'had conflict' variable is statistically significant across
all specifications. The marginal effect of having a history of conflict
increases the probability of conflict recurrence in the subsequent
period by 35%. (5)
The impact of human capital on conflict recurrence risk is
statistically significant and exhibits a non-linear behavior. The
squared term of secondary school enrollment rate indicates that the risk
of conflict recurrence starts to increase once a country reaches a
certain threshold in human capital. (6) In other words, raising
educational attainments from a low base has a stabilizing effect, as it
helps to increase the productivity of labor and lower the opportunity
cost of rebellion. But when a country is relatively well-endowed with
human capital, further gains would add to labor market pressures in a
fragile post-conflict economy and consequently increase the risk of
conflict recurrence.
We also include a measure of the youth bulge and find that it is a
significant factor in explaining the risk of conflict recurrence.
The magnitude of natural resource dependence has a significant
effect on the risk of conflict recurrence, in line with previous studies
(Collier and Hoeffler, 2004; Ross, 2006). In other words, the larger the
extent of natural resource rents in a country, the higher the risk of
conflict recurrence after the cessation of violence. (7) We also include
the squared term of natural resource rents, which is weakly significant
only in one specification but still provides evidence that an increase
in natural resource rents reduces the probability of future conflicts in
higher-income countries. Likewise, external factors, such as changes in
the terms of trade, appear to have a significant influence on the risk
of conflict recurrence.
The type of political regime has a weakly significant effect that
tends to increase the risk of conflict recurrence in democratic
countries, but the relationship is not linear. The negative coefficient
on the squared term of political regime type indicates that a
competitive election process and executive constraints reduce the
probability of conflict recurrence in more democratic societies, while a
high degree of institutionalized autocracy would also lower the risk of
conflict recurrence. In other words, countries in the middle of the
political regime spectrum appear to have a higher perceived risk of
conflict recurrence. On the other hand, the coefficient on the number of
cabinet changes is negative and highly significant, implying that
frequent changes in government contribute to a higher risk of conflict
recurrence.
Using a binary variable for UN peacekeeping operations, we identify
a positive and statistically significant relation with the risk of
conflict recurrence. In other words, the presence of UN peacekeeping
forces appears to increase the risk of conflict recurrence. This finding
remains robust even if alternative measures of UN interventions, such as
the number of UN troops in the country, are included instead of a binary
variable. Although, it appears to be counterintuitive, this result can
be explained by the endogeneity of peacekeeping operations: the UN
initiates an operation when risk is apparent in generating chaos in an
attempt to support the development of an environment of economic and
political stability and social cohesion, confirming the perceived risk
of conflict recurrence. We therefore exclude this variable from the
benchmark model, since the endogeneity problem can result in biased
estimates. Finally, we include decade dummies to capture shifting
political relationships between countries during and after the Cold War,
and find that decade dummies, except for the 1960s, are statistically
significant in most specifications of the model.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
According to our estimations, the probability of recurrence exceeds
20% in the first year after the end of conflict and exceeds 40% in the
5-year period. While the risk of relapsing into conflict declines with a
lasting peace, it is remains higher in the subsequent years than the
pre-conflict probability. As shown in the right panel of Figure 2, the
cumulative distribution of conflict recurrence by region indicates
extensive heterogeneity among countries and highlights the importance of
taking into account country-specific effects in the empirical analysis.
In addition, there is a systematically higher risk of conflict
recurrence in Africa, Asia, and the Middle East than in the Americas and
Europe. In particular, African and Asian countries start peace with a
significantly higher risk of relapsing into conflict, although the
probability declines over time with a lasting peace. In contrast,
however, countries in the Middle East appear to suffer from a high risk
of conflict recurrence without much decline over subsequent years.
In Figure 3, the average risk of conflict occurrence in countries
with at least one conflict (left panel) and no history of civil conflict
(right panel) across the world is depicted. The probability of civil
conflict peaked for all countries in the 1990s, increasing from an
average of 4% in the 1960s to 10% in the 1970s, 15% in the 1980s, and
16% in the 1990s. (8) However, the risk of civil conflict incidence is
more than 100 times greater in countries with at least one past episode
of civil conflict: it was 22% in the 1990s for countries with a history
of civil conflict versus 0.06% for countries with no history of civil
conflict. Although, the risk of conflict occurrence declined over the
past decade for all countries across the world, the probability of
relapsing into a new bout of conflict remains elevated for countries
with a history of conflict. As illustrated in Figure 4, the average risk
of conflict recurrence in the 2000s is highly correlated with that in
the 1960s, indicating a highly persistent risk of conflict recurrence in
countries with a history of conflict.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
ESTIMATING POST-CONFLICT ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
We present the results of the cross-country growth regressions in
Table 2 for the baseline model and in Table 3 for the model with the
alternative definition of conflict recurrence risk, which is discussed
in detail in assessing the robustness of the results. Our findings show
that the risk of conflict recurrence has a statistically significant and
economically large effect on post-conflict growth. According to our
estimations, a 1% increase in the probability of conflict recurrence
would lower real GDP per capita growth by 10%. (9) The magnitude of this
effect is substantial, especially considering that a country with a
history of conflict would be 30% riskier than a country with no history
of conflict. Similarly, alternative specifications of the risk of
conflict recurrence, presented in the second column of Table 1, also
have a negative effect of the same magnitude on post-conflict growth.
Conflict duration has a significant negative effect on
post-conflict growth, which may reflect an amalgamation of interacting
factors. On the one hand, a long conflict tends to destroy the stocks of
human and physical capital, the restoration of which would lead to rapid
recovery because of higher marginal productivity of capital. On the
other, a long-lasting conflict can damage the institutional
infrastructure and undermine post-conflict recovery. The results support
the latter hypothesis. That is, a long conflict, controlling for
conflict recurrence risk, undermines post-conflict growth. (10)
Human capital has a positive effect on post-conflict growth, but
secondary school enrollment is not significant in all specifications.
With the alternative definition of conflict recurrence risk as presented
in the second column of Table 1, the impact of secondary school
enrollment rates becomes statistically insignificant. This may be
because of the asymmetric destruction of different types of capital
during a conflict. If the conflict destroys the stocks of human capital
more than that of physical capital, then, in the aftermath of the
conflict, human capital becomes scarce compared with other factors of
production. The lower the ratio of human to physical capital, the higher
the marginal product of investing in human capital, and consequently the
higher the growth.
Institutional measures, such as the type of political regime and
the number of cabinet changes in a given year, have the expected signs,
but do not appear to be robustly significant, when the risk of conflict
recurrence is included in the model. However, we are reluctant to draw
definite conclusions about the relationship between growth and
institutional variables. First, the analysis covers post-conflict
periods, which may be too short for institutional change to have a
meaningful impact on growth dynamics. Second, depending on the
definition of conflict recurrence risk or other factors included as
explanatory variables, the significance of institution variables varies
across model specifications. When the estimation is conducted using a
broader set of observations that includes non-conflict countries,
institutional factors indeed become statistically and economically
highly significant with the expected signs. In our opinion, this
reflects numerous institutional similarities among conflict-prone
countries; therefore, excluding observations from non-conflict countries
makes the empirical identification of the impact of institutional
variables on post-conflict growth weaker.
Natural resource dependence has an economically large negative
effect on post-conflict growth. Post-conflict countries with a high
degree of dependence on natural resources suffer from a 'double
curse' of higher risk of conflict and lower growth, compared with
other post-conflict countries with a more diversified economic
structure. While climatic conditions, measured by temperature
variability, do not appear to be a significant factor, ethnic
fractionalization has a statistically significant negative effect on the
pace of post-conflict growth. Moreover, the impact of ethnic
fractionalization remains statistically significant and economically
meaningful, even when we control for the risk of conflict recurrence.
International economic factors such as global growth and net per
capita FDI are statistically significant and have an economically large
positive impact on the post-conflict growth process. Although, we find a
negative coefficient for trade openness, interaction terms relating
trade openness to the size of the domestic economy and global real GDP
growth are highly statistically significant. In other words, as
expected, more open conflict-prone economies tend to more sensitive to
global developments. Foreign aid, on the other hand, does not appear to
be important. This may reflect the pattern experienced in many
post-conflict countries: foreign aid surges after the cessation of
hostilities but abates thereafter. Moreover, as Collier and Hoeffler
(2002) argue, post-conflict countries tend to have low capacity to
absorb foreign aid because of political and administrative constraints;
although, Suhrke et al. (2005) challenge these findings. (11)
Contrary to popular expectations, UN peacekeeping operations do not
appear to be a significant factor in determining the strength of
post-conflict growth. This, we believe, is related to the relationship
between the risk of conflict recurrence and international peacekeeping
operations, which may signal a greater level of risk, which in turn
depresses economic activity. As a 11 result, the coefficient of UN
peacekeeping operations becomes sensitive to the definition of conflict
recurrence risk and makes it difficult to disentangle these linkages and
their impact on growth. We also test the impact of IMF-supported
economic programs on post-conflict growth dynamics. Although, the
empirical evidence does not support a positive relationship between IMF
engagement and real GDP per capita growth after the cessation of
violence, such lending arrangements do not necessarily deal with the
underlying fragilities that remain a drag on post-conflict growth.
ROBUSTNESS CHECKS
One important concern about the empirical findings presented in
this paper is related to the definition of conflict recurrence risk. The
baseline model is estimated with a set of variables including the level
and growth rate of real GDP per capita, which are also included in
analyzing post-conflict growth dynamics. Consequently, there may be a
potential problem of endogeneity. One possible way to deal with this
econometric predicament is to implement an instrumental variable
approach for a linear probability model, similar to the methodology
outlined by Miguel et al. (2004). However, a shortcoming of this
methodology is that the linear prediction for the probability of an
event risk produces many negative risk observations in the growth
regression and may result in biased estimates. Furthermore, while Miguel
et al. (2004) use rainfall as an instrumental variable in a limited
geographic scope of African countries, our sample includes a broader set
of countries, making instrumental variables such as rainfall a weak
option for the analysis.
Instead, we estimate alternative measures of conflict recurrence
risk using a variety of variables such as a country's history of
civil conflict, the level and growth rate of global real GDP, the
frequency of cabinet changes, and the degree of ethnic
fractionalization, without including the level and growth of domestic
per capita income in the model. The results indicate that having a
history of conflict is a robust factor in explaining the recurrence of
intra-state wars. Furthermore, other variables such as the youth bulge,
the duration of the last conflict, and the frequency of cabinet changes
contribute significantly to measuring the time-varying risk of conflict
recurrence. The growth regression based on this alternative
specification of conflict recurrence risk, presented in Table 3, yields
similar results coinciding with the benchmark model, except for foreign
aid, which appears to reduce post-conflict growth. Furthermore, though
slightly weaker because of the loss of valuable information related to
post-conflict growth, these results, based on the alternative
specification of conflict recurrence risk, have no potential problem of
endogeneity or reverse causality, as the level and growth rate of per
capita income are excluded in the estimation.
To check the robustness of our empirical findings based on the
sample covering the entire period 1960-2010, we estimate the
post-conflict growth model for different time regimes (1970-1989 and
1990-2010). The risk of conflict recurrence remains a statistically
important factor with a negative coefficient across different time
specifications, as shown in Table 4, although data limitations appear to
reduce the level of significance. We also test whether the statistical
significance of our results is independent of geographical factors by
running regressions that exclude one region at a time. For example, the
first column of Table 5 shows the results when European countries are
excluded from the growth regression: both the benchmark and alternative
definitions of conflict recurrence risk have a statistically significant
and economically large negative effect on post-conflict real GDP per
capita growth. Other geographic specifications yield similar results,
supporting the validity of the findings based on our benchmark model.
CONCLUSION
The number of civil conflicts has declined over the past decade,
but countries emerging from a conflict still struggle to break the curse
of Sisyphus, with 20% relapsing into a new bout of conflict in the first
year and 40% within 5 years after the end of conflict. Hence,
understanding the causes and consequences of civil conflict remains an
important objective in the quest to achieve sustainable sociopolitical
reconciliation and economic development. This paper makes a novel
contribution to the literature by estimating a forward-looking measure
of conflict recurrence risk and including as an explanatory variable in
analyzing post-conflict growth dynamics. We adopt a logistic regression
approach and model the probability of conflict recurrence with the
latest available information in each period, while controlling for
unobserved fixed effects in a non-linear probability model for the first
time in the conflict literature.
Using a panel dataset covering 146 episodes of civil conflict in 94
countries from 1960 to 2010, we find that the estimated risk of conflict
recurrence has a statistically significant and economically large effect
on post-conflict growth. A 1 % increase in the probability of conflict
recurrence in the subsequent period is found to lower real GDP per
capita growth by 10%. The rest of our main empirical results are broadly
in line with the existing literature. Human capital and institutional
factors have significant positive effects on post-conflict growth, while
natural resource dependence appears to cause a 'double curse'
of higher risk of conflict recurrence and lower growth, compared with
other countries with a more diversified economic structure. Ethnic
fractionalization is another significant factor with negative influence
on the strength of post-conflict growth. Global growth and capital flows
matter for post-conflict recovery, especially for countries that are
more open and integrated with the rest of the world. Finally, contrary
to popular expectations, we do not find UN peacekeeping operations,
foreign aid and IMF-supported economic programs to have significant
effect on post-conflict growth.
The empirical results presented in this paper call for a framework
centered on three main pillars, implementing growth-enhancing policies,
reforming dysfunctional institutions, and addressing urgent needs, to
reduce the risk of conflict recurrence and pave the way for broad-based,
sustainable economic growth after the end of a conflict. While sound
macroeconomic management is important for success, helping to sustain
the pace of recovery and avoid a relapse into conflict, strengthening
institutions is critical for addressing longstanding grievances and
raising the economy's growth potential. Moreover, the challenge
facing post-conflict countries is not just to make economic growth
stronger, but also more inclusive to ensure that the benefits of
increased prosperity are shared more evenly across society, especially
considering the possibility that pre-conflict policies and institutional
arrangements may have contributed to the outbreak of civil conflict by
discriminating against particular ethnic, religious or social segments.
Last but not the least, in the particular case of natural
resource-dependent countries, the need for economic diversification is
not just a long-term objective, but an urgent undertaking in order to
break the 'double curse' of higher conflict recurrence risk
and lower post-conflict growth.
The principal contribution of this paper is to take a first pass at
quantifying the impact of the forward-looking risk of conflict
recurrence on post-conflict economic transitions. Accordingly, a
valuable extension would be an investigation of the dynamic process of
how economic agents assess the risk of conflict recurrence and its
evolution over time using a Bayesian methodology. Similarly, the
geographic diffusion of conflict risk within and between countries is an
interesting empirical question.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank Josef Brada, Carlos Caceres, Paul
Cashin, Victor Davies, Selim Elekdag, Samiei Hossein, Padamja
Khandelwal, Tidiane Kinda, Zijun Luo, Lawrence McDonough, Kia Penso,
Katerina Teksoz, Fatih Yilmaz, and two anonymous referees for their
insightful comments and suggestions. The views expressed herein are
those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its
executive Board, or its management.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D, Johnson, S and Robinson, J. 2001: The colonial origins
of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American
Economic Review 91(5): 1369-1401.
Acemoglu, D, Johnson, S and Robinson, J. 2004: Institutions as the
Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth. NBER Working Paper No. 10481,
National Bureau for Economic Research: Cambridge, MA.
Acemoglu, D and Johnson, S. 2005: Unbundling institutions. Journal
of Political Economy 113(5): 949-995.
Addison, T, Chowdhury, A and Murshed, S. 2002: By How Much Does
Conflict Reduce Financial Development? WIDER Discussion Paper No.
2002/48, United Nations University World Institute for Development
Economics Research: Helsinki.
Arellano, M and Bond, S. 1991: Some tests of specification for
panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment
equations. Review of Economic Studies 58(2): 277-297.
Arellano, M and Bover, O. 1995: Another look at the instrumental
variables estimation of error components models. Journal of Econometrics
68(1): 29-51.
Blattman, C and Miguel, E. 2010: Civil war. Journal of Economic
Literature 48(1): 3-57.
Blundell, R and Bond, S. 1998: Initial conditions and moment
restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics
87(1): 115-143.
Bond, S, Hoeffler, A and Temple, J. 2001: GMM Estimation of
Empirical Growth Models. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3048, Center for
Economic Policy Research: London.
Cassar, A, Grosjean, P and Whitt, S. 2013: Legacies of violence:
Trust and market development. Journal of Economic Growth 18(3): 285-318.
Choi, I. 2001: Unit root tests for panel data. Journal of
International Money and Finance 20(2): 249-272.
Collier, P. 1999: On the economic consequences of civil war. Oxford
Economic Papers 51(1): 168-183.
Collier, P and Hoeffler, A. 2002: On the incidence of civil war in
Africa. Journal of Conflict Resolution 46(1): 13-28.
Collier, P and Hoeffler, A. 2004: Greed and grievance in civil war.
Oxford Economic Papers 56(4): 563-595.
Elbadawi, I, Hegre, H and Milante, G. 2008: The aftermath of civil
war. Journal of Peace Research 45(4): 451-459.
Eichengreen, B, Rose, A and Wyplosz, C. 1995: Exchange rate Mayhem:
The antecedents and aftermath of speculative attacks. Economic Policy 21
(10): 249-312.
Engerman, S and Sokoloff, K. 2000: Institutions, factor endowments,
and paths of development in the new world. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 14(3): 217-232.
Esteban, J, Mayoral, L and Ray, D. 2012: Ethnicity and conflict: An
empirical study. American Economic Review 102(4): 1310-1342.
Estrella, A and Mishkin, F. 1998: Predicting U.S. Recessions:
Financial variables as leading indicators. Review of Economics and
Statistics 85(3): 629-644.
Fearon, J and Laitin, D. 2003: Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil
war. American Political Science Review 97(1): 75-90.
Frankel, J and Rose, A. 1996: Currency crashes in emerging markets:
An empirical treatment. Journal of International Economics 41(3):
351-366.
Gallup, J, Sachs, J and Mellinger, A. 1998: Geography and economic
development. International Regional Science Review 22(2): 179-232.
Grosjean, P. 2014: Conflict and social and political preferences:
Evidence from world war II and civil conflict in 35 European countries.
Comparative Economic Studies 56(3): 424-451.
Grossman, H. 1991: A general equilibrium model of insurrections.
American Economic Review 81(4): 912-921.
Hall, R and Jones, C. 1999: Why do some countries produce so much
more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics
114(1): 83-116.
Hegre, H, Ellingsen, T, Gates, S and Gledish, N. 2001: Towards a
democratic civil peace? Democracy, political change, and civil war,
1816-1992. American Political Science Review 95(1): 22-45.
Hirshleifer, J. 1995: Theorizing about Conflict. In Handbook of
Defense Economics Hartley, K and Sandler, T (eds) Elsevier Science:
Amsterdam.
Holz-Eakin, D, Newey, W and Rosen, H. 1988: Estimating vector
autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica 56(6): 1371-1395.
Humphreys, M. 2005: Natural resources, conflict, and conflict
resolution: Uncovering the mechanisms. Journal of Conflict Resolution
49(4): 508-537.
Im, K, Pesaran, M and Shin, Y. 2003: Testing for unit roots in
heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics 115(1): 53-74.
Knack, S and Keefer, P. 1995: Institutions and economic
performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional
measures. Economics and Politics 7(3): 207-227.
Levin, A, Lin, CF and Chu, CS. 2002: Unit root tests in panel data:
Asymptotic and finite-sample properties. Journal of Econometrics 108(1):
1-24.
Miguel, E, Satyanath, S and Sergenti, E. 2004: Economic shocks and
civil conflict: An instrumental variables approach. Journal of Political
Economy 112(4): 725-753.
Nafzinger, E, Stewart, F and Vayrynen, R. 2000: War, Hunger, and
Displacement: The Origin of Humanitarian Emergencies. Oxford University
Press: New York.
Reynal-Querol, M. 2002: Political systems, stability and civil
wars. Defense and Peace Economics 13(6): 465-483.
Reynal-Querol, M. 2005: Does democracy preempt civil wars? European
Journal of Political Economy 21(2): 445-465.
Ross, M. 2006: A closer look at oil, diamonds and civil war. Annual
Review of Political Science 9(1): 265-300.
Sachs, J and Warner, A. 1997: Sources of slow growth in African
economies. Journal of African Economies 6(3): 335-376.
Sambanis, N. 2001: Do ethnic and non-ethnic civil wars have the
same causes? A Theoretical and empirical enquiry. Journal of Conflict
Resolution 45(3): 259-282.
Sandler, T. 2000: Economic analysis of conflict. Journal of
Conflict Resolution 44(6): 723-729.
Skaperdas, S. 1992: Cooperation, conflict, and power in the absence
of property rights. American Economic Review 82(4): 720-739.
Suhrke, A, Villanger, E and Woodward, S. 2005: Economic Aid to
Post-Conflict Countries: A Methodological Critique of Collier and
Hoeffler. CMI Working Papers No. 2005:4, Chr. Michelsen Institute:
Bergen, Norway.
Wooldridge, J. 2005: Fixed-effects and related estimators for
correlated random-coefficient and treatment-effect. Panel Data Models
87(2): 385-390.
(1) This database is a joint project of the Uppsala Conflict Data
Program (UCDP) at the Department of Peace and Conflict Research, Uppsala
University and the Center for the Study of Civil War at the
International Peace Research Institute in Oslo (PRIO).
(2) Humphreys (2005) and Blattman and Miguel (2010) provide
extensive reviews of the literature on the causes and consequences of
civil conflicts.
(3) There is a vast and growing literature on early warning
indicators and prediction methods, led by, among others, Eichengreen et
al. (1995) and Frankel and Rose (1996) on forecasting currency crises
and Estrella and Mishkin (1998) on predicting economic recessions.
(4) Without loss of generality, the threshold can be 0.
(5) While the 'had conflict' variable may arguably
capture country characteristics, there is no test available to address
this question directly. It is also worth noting that country fixed
effects are modeled separately in our estimation, based on the logit
random-effect framework. Also, including a range of other explanatory
variables shows that the marginal impact of having a conflict before
never drops below 25 %.
(6) We test other measures of human capital such as primary,
tertiary, and total school enrollment rates, which show the same
pattern, but are statistically insignificant. In our view, this is
because conflict has a greater effect on secondary school enrollment,
causing a higher degree of volatility compared with other variables.
(7) Additional regressions show that hydrocarbon production is not
significant for the occurrence of civil conflict. We also consider two
other time dummies for the discovery of hydrocarbon reserves and the
start of production, which are insignificant when the 'had
conflict' variable is included in the regression.
(8) These simple averages, not weighted by population or GDP,
better highlight the global level of conflict recurrence risk. First, as
the GDP and population have a direct effect on conflict risk, averaging
according to these weights can lead to biased results. Second, the
sample of countries is changing over time in both panels.
(9) An important feature of this result is that we use an abstract
measurement of risk in our calculation (the first column of Table 1). If
we include other variables, the impact of the risk of conflict
recurrence would be larger.
(10) This conclusion should be treated with caution, because the
direction of causality is unclear as weak institutions may also
contribute to conflict duration and to slower growth afterwards. In this
paper, while we do not explicitly deal with this issue, we reason that
the impact of institutional factors beyond what is incorporated in our
growth model is captured by fixed effects and therefore should not
distort the key empirical findings.
(11) An important problem with the analysis of aid effectiveness is
identification when all types of aid are bundled together. For example,
humanitarian or military aid should not be expected to have the same
effect on economic growth as aid adding to a country's productive
capacity. Lacking disaggregated data on foreign aid, this study, too,
relies on total foreign aid as measured by the OECD Development
Assistance Committee.
SERHAN CEVIK [1] & MOHAMMAD RAHMATI [2]
[1] International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street, NW, Washington
DC, 20431, USA. E-mail: scevik@imf.org
[2] Sharif University of Technology, Azadi Street, 1458889694,
Tehran, Iran.
Table 1: Determinants of the risk of conflict recurrence:
random-effect logistic panel model
Models
Variables 1 Baseline 2 3
Alternative
Log [(real GDP per -0.363 *** -0.275 **
capita).sub.t] (-3.11) (-2.25)
Real GDP per capita -1.639 ** -1.667 **
[growth.sub.t] (-2.22) (-2.24)
Had [conflict.sub.t] 5.383 *** 2.619 *** 5.238 ***
(9.57) (3.49) (9.35)
Log [(global 1.443
real GDP).sub.t] (0.87)
Global real GDP -4.703
[growth.sub.t] (-0.90)
Duration of 0.044 ***
[conflict.sub.t] (3.33)
Terms of [trade.sub.t]
Natural resource
[rent.sub.t]
Natural [resource
rent.sup.2.sub.t]
Secondary school
enrollment [rate.sub.t]
Secondary school
enrollment [rate.sub.t]
Ethnic fractionalization 0.675 1.677 **
(0.87) (2.18)
Youth [bulge.sub.t] 0.121 ***
(3.93)
Frequency of cabinet 0.352 ***
[changes.sub.t] (3.62)
Type of political
[regime.sub.t]
Type of political
[regime.sup.2.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
1960s -0.920 *** -0.866 ***
(-4.62) (-4.33)
1970s -0.196 0.103 -0.159
(-1.21) (0.16) (-0.98)
1980s 0.423 *** 0.551 0.452 ***
(2.84) (1.24) (3.01)
1990s 0.531 *** 0.309 0.515 ***
(3.83) (1.13) (3.68)
Constant -4.782 *** -21.707 -6.038 ***
(-4.63) (-1.53) (-5.00)
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.v] 1.202 *** 1.086 *** 1.156 ***
(6.79) (5.25) (6.45)
Log Likelihood -1469 -1060 -1449
[chi square] 184.9 86.17 179.7
Number of observations 7,087 2,848 6,795
Number of countries 195 105 184
Models
Variables 4 5 6
Log [(real GDP per -0.087 -0.507 *** -0.399 ***
capita).sub.t] (-0.70) (-3.20) (-3.08)
Real GDP per capita -1.834 ** -2.687 ** -1.988 **
[growth.sub.t] (-2.23) (-2.57) (-2.44)
Had [conflict.sub.t] 4.932 *** 5.627 *** 5.407 ***
(8.57) (7.70) (8.50)
Log [(global 1.724
real GDP).sub.t] (1.05)
Global real GDP -3.813
[growth.sub.t] (-0.68)
Duration of
[conflict.sub.t]
Terms of [trade.sub.t] -4.630 **
(-2.55)
Natural resource 4.294 ***
[rent.sub.t] (2.72)
Natural [resource -3.134
rent.sup.2.sub.t] (-1.49)
Secondary school
enrollment [rate.sub.t]
Secondary school
enrollment [rate.sub.t]
Ethnic fractionalization
Youth [bulge.sub.t]
Frequency of cabinet 0.190 ** 0.293 ***
[changes.sub.t] (2.17) (2.89)
Type of political 0.013
[regime.sub.t] (1.05)
Type of political -0.016 ***
[regime.sup.2.sub.t] (-6.63)
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
1960s -0.625 ***
(-2.83)
1970s 0.167 0.708 -0.060
(0.87) (1.03) (-0.35)
1980s 0.691 *** 1.215 ** 0.525 ***
(3.94) (2.55) (3.37)
1990s 0.626 *** 0.866 *** 0.621 ***
(4.08) (3.27) (4.26)
Constant -5.734 *** -18.662 -4.996 ***
(-5.28) (-1.33) (-4.39)
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.v] 1.163 *** 1.443 *** 1.292 ***
(6.40) (7.26) (7.01)
Log Likelihood -1323 -1028 -1254
[chi square] 205.5 133.2 134.4
Number of observations 5,409 4,564 5,340
Number of countries 159 165 168
Models
Variables 7 8 9
Log [(real GDP per -0.457 *** -0.260 ** -0.282 **
capita).sub.t] (-3.03) (-2.03) (-2.39)
Real GDP per capita -3.397 *** -2.305 *** -1.766 **
[growth.sub.t] (-3.30) (-2.87) (-2.38)
Had [conflict.sub.t] 5.606 *** 5.292 *** 5.428 ***
(7.54) (9.30) (9.56)
Log [(global
real GDP).sub.t]
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
Duration of
[conflict.sub.t]
Terms of [trade.sub.t] -4.890 ***
(-2.92)
Natural resource 6.847 ***
[rent.sub.t] (3.69)
Natural [resource -5.235 **
rent.sup.2.sub.t] (-1.97)
Secondary school -11.822 *
enrollment [rate.sub.t] (-1.82)
Secondary school 76.206 **
enrollment [rate.sub.t] (2.26)
Ethnic fractionalization
Youth [bulge.sub.t]
Frequency of cabinet
[changes.sub.t]
Type of political
[regime.sub.t]
Type of political
[regime.sup.2.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping 0.931 ***
[operations.sub.t] (3.55)
1960s -0.877 *** -0.824 ***
(-3.31) (-4.10)
1970s 0.066 -0.153 -0.103
(0.35) (-0.75) (-0.62)
1980s 0.779 *** 0.521*** 0.494 ***
(4.52) (3.15) (3.26)
1990s 0.752 *** 0.633*** 0.558 ***
(4.76) (4.24) (3.99)
Constant -4.559 *** -5.190 *** -5.473 ***
(-3.40) (-4.85) (-5.11)
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.v] 1.440 *** 1.182 *** 1.210 ***
(7.45) (6.58) (6.85)
Log Likelihood -1098 -1387 -1463
[chi square] 138.1 177.0 197.5
Number of observations 4,646 6,303 7,087
Number of countries 153 184 195
Note: The dependent variable is a dummy for the recurrence
of a conflict at the next period; the coefficients are
estimated with a random-effect logit panel model for the
sample period 1960-2010. z-statistics are reported in
parentheses, with *, **, and *** indicating statistical
significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Source: Authors' estimations
Table 2: Determinants of post-conflict real GDP
per capita growth: system-gmm dynamic panel
1 2 3
Real GDP per capita 0.289 *** 0.291 *** 0.241 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (14.44) (14.57) (11.26)
Log real GDP per -0.030 *** -0.033 *** -0.028 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-6.82) (-7.14) (-5.87)
Risk of conflict -0.089 ** -0.087 ** -0.093 **
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.33) (-2.27) (-2.47)
Duration of -0.011 -0.012 **
[conflict.sub.t] (-1.42) (-2.00)
Time since the end of 0.004 ***
[conflict.sub.t] (3.02)
Depth of contraction -0.056
during [conflict.sub.t] (-1.03)
Terms of [trade.sub.t]
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
[FDI.sub.t]
Landlocked
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t]
Trade
Openness*[GDP.sub.t]
Constant 0.253 *** 0.253 *** 0.239 ***
(6.91) (7.30) (6.11)
Number of observations 1,916 1,916 1,563
Number of countries 89 89 83
Sargan Test 1943 1943 1605
[chi square] 333.0 343.3 206.5
4 5 6
Real GDP per capita 0.168 *** 0.286 *** 0.150 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (7.82) (13.51) (6.27)
Log real GDP per -0.021 *** -0.022 *** -0.025 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-5.38) (-5.69) (-5.89)
Risk of conflict -0.121 *** -0.103 *** -0.079 **
[recurrence.sub.t] (-3.19) (-2.59) (-1.97)
Duration of -0.002 0.012 0.002
[conflict.sub.t] (-0.11) (-1.25) (-0.02)
Time since the end of
[conflict.sub.t]
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Terms of [trade.sub.t] 0.043
(0.92)
Temperature 0.001
[variability.sub.t] (0.85)
[FDI.sub.t] 0.007 ***
(5.31)
Landlocked
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t]
Trade
Openness*[GDP.sub.t]
Constant 0.182 *** 0.178 *** 0.216 ***
(5.40) (5.34) (6.25)
Number of observations 1,618 1,617 1,166
Number of countries 83 78 81
Sargan Test 1696 1667 1247
[chi square] 119.9 272.7 108.3
7 8
Real GDP per capita 0.296 *** 0.256 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (14.65) (12.31)
Log real GDP per -0.037 *** -0.035 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-7.67) (-7.12)
Risk of conflict -0.083 ** -0.112 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.14) (-2.73)
Duration of -0.003 -0.002
[conflict.sub.t] (-0.91) (-0.71)
Time since the end of
[conflict.sub.t]
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Terms of [trade.sub.t]
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
[FDI.sub.t]
Landlocked -0.093 ***
(-4.17)
Global real GDP 0.481 ***
[growth.sub.t] (5.83)
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t]
Trade
Openness*[GDP.sub.t]
Constant 0.311 *** 0.276 ***
(7.79) (6.88)
Number of observations 1,856 1,748
Number of countries 84 89
Sargan Test 1865 1744
[chi square] 370.4 331.6
9 10
Real GDP per capita 0.289 *** 0.206 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (14.44) (8.47)
Log real GDP per -0.030 *** -0.058 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-6.74) (-8.31)
Risk of conflict -0.096 ** -0.115 **
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.48) (-2.29)
Duration of -0.011 -0.020 ***
[conflict.sub.t] (-1.44) (-3.25)
Time since the end of
[conflict.sub.t]
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Terms of [trade.sub.t]
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
[FDI.sub.t]
Landlocked
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping 0.014
[operations.sub.t] (1.04)
Trade [openness.sub.t] -0.120 *
(-1.74)
Trade 0.020 **
Openness*[GDP.sub.t] (2.10)
Constant 0.252 *** 0.470 ***
(6.87) (8.27)
Number of observations 1,916 1,261
Number of countries 89 73
Sargan Test 1942 1279
[chi square] 334.2 205.1
11 12 13
Real GDP per capita 0.226 *** 0.277 *** 0.225 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (8.51) (14.02) (11.16)
Log real GDP per -0.071 *** -0.031 *** -0.036 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-8.64) (-7.15) (-7.88)
Risk of conflict -0.103 * -0.098 *** -0.146 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-1.70) (-2.59) (-3.89)
Duration of -0.020 *** -0.010 -0.012 **
[conflict.sub.t] (-2.99) (-1.44) (-1.97)
Time since the end of
[conflict.sub.t]
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
Landlocked
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t] -0.119 *
(-1.66)
Trade 0.018 *
0penness*[GDP.sub.t] (1.89)
Trade Openness*Global 0.622 **
[growth.sub.t] (2.27)
Foreign aid per -0.001
[capita.sub.t] (-0.39)
Secondary school 0.239 ***
enrollment [rate.sub.t] (2.90)
Ethnic
[fractionalization.sub.t]
Cabinet [Changes.sub.t]
Natural resource
[rent.sub.t]
IMF [Program.sub.t]
Constant 0.562 *** 0.262 *** 0.293 ***
(8.32) (7.28) (7.91)
Number of observations 1,103 1,908 1,761
Number of countries 73 89 89
Sargan Test 1125 1930 1738
[chi square] 234.6 328.3 265.9
14 15 16
Real GDP per capita 0.289 *** 0.240 *** 0.230 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (14.40) (11.47) (10.94)
Log real GDP per -0.032 *** -0.033 *** -0.038 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-6.87) (-7.14) (-8.05)
Risk of conflict -0.091 ** -0.134 *** -0.168 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.38) (-3.43) (-4.24)
Duration of -0.011 -0.012 ** 0.002
[conflict.sub.t] (-1.07) (-2.11) (-0.62)
Time since the end of
[conflict.sub.t]
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
Landlocked
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t]
Trade
0penness*[GDP.sub.t]
Trade Openness*Global
[growth.sub.t]
Foreign aid per
[capita.sub.t]
Secondary school
enrollment [rate.sub.t]
Ethnic -0.036
[fractionalization.sub.t]
(-1.33)
Cabinet [Changes.sub.t] -0.009 ***
(-3.99)
Natural resource -0.048 **
[rent.sub.t] (-2.40)
IMF [Program.sub.t]
Constant 0.278 *** 0.290 *** 0.317 ***
(6.67) (7.56) (8.23)
Number of observations 1,908 1,691 1,767
Number of countries 88 89 89
Sargan Test 1940 1669 1757
[chi square] 334.2 274.2 300.0
17 18
Real GDP per capita 0.289 *** 0.208 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (14.43) (6.47)
Log real GDP per -0.029 *** -0.088 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-6.61) (-8.20)
Risk of conflict -0.087 ** -0.241 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.26) (-3.24)
Duration of 0.010
[conflict.sub.t] (0.68)
Time since the end of 0.013 ***
[conflict.sub.t] (2.62)
Depth of contraction -0.495 ***
during [conflict.sub.t] (-3.64)
Temperature -0.002
[variability.sub.t] (-0.64)
Landlocked -0.059
(-1.60)
Global real GDP 0.014
[growth.sub.t] (0.04)
UN peacekeeping 0.063 *
[operations.sub.t] (1.76)
Trade [openness.sub.t] -0.028
(-0.37)
Trade 0.008
0penness*[GDP.sub.t] (0.76)
Trade Openness*Global 0.011
[growth.sub.t] (0.02)
Foreign aid per -0.013 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-3.28)
Secondary school
enrollment [rate.sub.t]
Ethnic -0.098 **
[fractionalization.sub.t]
(-2.29)
Cabinet [Changes.sub.t] -0.012 ***
(-3.71)
Natural resource 0.010
[rent.sub.t] (0.34)
IMF [Program.sub.t] -0.005 -0.006
(-1.27) (-1.21)
Constant 0.231 *** 0.701 ***
(6.85) (7.69)
Number of observations 1,916 773
Number of countries 89 57
Sargan Test 1942 797.8
[chi square] 332.4 215.0
Notes: The dependent variable is the growth rate
of real GDP per capita at time t, starting with the end of conflict.
The model is estimated with the system-GMM dynamic panel approach
for the sample period 1960-2010.
The sample includes only post-conflict observations.
z-statistics are reported in parentheses, with *, **,
and *** indicating statistical significance at the 1%, 5%,
and 10% levels, respectively.
Source: Authors' estimations
Table 3: Determinants of post-conflict real GDP per capita growth
(with the alternative measure of conflict risk):
System-GMM dynamic panel
Models
Variables 1 2 3
Real GDP per capita 0.272 *** 0.285 *** 0.151 ***
[growths.sub.t-1] (12.13) (11.51) (5.93)
Log (real GDP per -0.059 *** -0.052 *** -0.036 ***
[capita.sub.t]) (-9.16) (-7.35) (-6.43)
Risk of conflict -0.092 *** -0.074 ** -0.132 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.67) (-2.13) (-4.03)
Duration of -0.022 *** -0.030 *** -0.000
[conflict.sub.t] (-2.93) (-2.99) (-0.53)
Depth of contraction -0.167 **
during [conflict.sub.t] (-2.55)
Terms of [trade.sub.t] 0.015
(0.25)
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
[FDI.sub.t]
Landlocked
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t]
Trade openness*
[GDP.sub.t]
Trade openness*global
[growth.sub.t]
Constant 0.486 *** 0.432 *** 0.303 ***
(9.22) (7.39) (6.27)
Number of observations 1,176 976 1,004
Number of countries 79 72 72
Sargan Test 1119 963.0 1006
[chi square] 242.0 182.1 81.15
Models
Variables 4 5 6
Real GDP per capita 0.257 *** 0.138 *** 0.278 ***
[growths.sub.t-1] (10.72) (4.83) (12.31)
Log (real GDP per -0.043 *** -0.026 *** -0.060 ***
[capita.sub.t]) (-7.94) (-4.88) (-9.07)
Risk of conflict -0.123 *** -0.106 *** -0.084 **
[recurrence.sub.t] (-3.53) (-2.79) (-2.41)
Duration of 0.010 0.010 -0.023 ***
[conflict.sub.t] (1.45) (1.43) (-2.74)
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Terms of [trade.sub.t]
Temperature 0.000
[variability.sub.t] (0.08)
[FDI.sub.t] 0.006 ***
(2.94)
Landlocked -0.069 **
(-2.00)
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t]
Trade openness*
[GDP.sub.t]
Trade openness*global
[growth.sub.t]
Constant 0.329 *** 0.217 *** 0.503 ***
(7.18) (4.94) (9.22)
Number of observations 1,056 730 1,150
Number of countries 70 68 76
Sargan Test 1009 766.5 1085
[chi square] 205.9 55.74 264.0
Models
Variables 7 8
Real GDP per capita 0.273 *** 0.270 ***
[growths.sub.t-1] (12.20) (11.83)
Log (real GDP per -0.058 *** -0.059 ***
[capita.sub.t]) (-9.01) (-8.94)
Risk of conflict -0.078 ** -0.092 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.26) (-2.69)
Duration of -0.023 *** -0.022 ***
[conflict.sub.t] (-2.95) (-2.94)
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Terms of [trade.sub.t]
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
[FDI.sub.t]
Landlocked
Global real GDP 0.400 ***
[growth.sub.t] (3.02)
UN peacekeeping -0.007
[operations.sub.t] (-0.35)
Trade [openness.sub.t]
Trade openness*
[GDP.sub.t]
Trade openness*global
[growth.sub.t]
Constant 0.470 *** 0.491 ***
(8.90) (9.00)
Number of observations 1,176 1,176
Number of countries 79 79
Sargan Test 1118 1119
[chi square] 251.0 242.2
Models
Variables 9 10
Real GDP per capita 0.258 *** 0.258 ***
[growths.sub.t-1] (11.30) (11.38)
Log (real GDP per -0.072 *** -0.071 ***
[capita.sub.t]) (-9.44) (-9.37)
Risk of conflict -0.090 ** -0.077 **
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.53) (-2.14)
Duration of -0.020 *** -0.020 ***
[conflict.sub.t] (-2.68) (-2.75)
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Terms of [trade.sub.t]
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
[FDI.sub.t]
Landlocked
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t] -0.164 ** -0.167 **
(-2.30) (-2.36)
Trade openness* 0.026 *** 0.025 ***
[GDP.sub.t] (2.69) (2.58)
Trade openness*global 0.763 ***
[growth.sub.t] (2.87)
Constant 0.570 *** 0.562 ***
(9.35) (9.25)
Number of observations 1,096 1,096
Number of countries 73 73
Sargan Test 1078 1080
[chi square] 233.6 242.1
Models
Variables 11 12 13
Real GDP per capita 0.266 *** 0.271 *** 0.272 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (11.81) (12.10) (12.13)
Log (real GDP per -0.060 *** -0.059 *** -0.060 ***
[capita.sub.t]) (-9.34) (-9.17) (-8.84)
Risk of conflict -0.093 *** -0.096 *** -0.092 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.71) (-2.78) (-2.69)
Duration of -0.022 *** -0.020 *** -0.020 ***
[conflict.sub.t] (-3.12) (-2.85) (-2.87)
Depth of contraction
during [conflict.sub.t]
Temperature
[variability.sub.t]
[FDI.sub.t]
Landlocked
Global real GDP
[growth.sub.t]
UN peacekeeping
[operations.sub.t]
Trade [openness.sub.t]
Trade openness*
[GDP.sub.t]
Trade openness*global
[growth.sub.t]
Foreign aid per -0.005 **
[capita.sub.t] (-2.12)
Secondary school 0.101
enrollment [rate.sub.t] (0.77)
Ethnic fractionalization -0.015
(-0.41)
Number of cabinet
[changes.sub.t]
Natural resource
[rent.sub.t]
Constant 0.500 *** 0.485 *** 0.498 ***
(9.42) (9.19) (8.27)
Number of observations 1,176 1,175 1,176
Number of countries 79 79 79
Sargan Test 1117 1118 1117
[chi square] 246.1 241.1 241.8
Models
Variables 14 15 16
Real GDP per capita 0.269 *** 0.270 *** 0.259 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (12.08) (11.61) (8.94)
Log (real GDP per -0.060 *** -0.053 *** -0.078 ***
[capita.sub.t]) (-9.40) (-8.32) (-7.91)
Risk of conflict -0.100 *** -0.088 *** -0.100 **
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.93) (-2.59) (-2.54)
Duration of -0.022 *** -0.022 *** 0.000
[conflict.sub.t] (-3.02) (-2.35) -0.37
Depth of contraction -0.586 ***
during [conflict.sub.t] (-4.24)
Temperature -0.002
[variability.sub.t] (-0.91)
[FDI.sub.t]
Landlocked -0.029
(-0.73)
Global real GDP 0.147
[growth.sub.t] (0.45)
UN peacekeeping 0.058
[operations.sub.t] (1.60)
Trade [openness.sub.t] -0.017
(-0.22)
Trade openness* 0.006
[GDP.sub.t] (0.58)
Trade openness*global 0.096
[growth.sub.t] (0.15)
Foreign aid per -0.012 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-3.02)
Secondary school
enrollment [rate.sub.t]
Ethnic fractionalization -0.058
(-1.40)
Number of cabinet -0.013 *** -0.012 ***
[changes.sub.t] (-4.51) (-3.71)
Natural resource -0.062 ** 0.036
[rent.sub.t] (-2.32) (1.22)
Constant 0.504 *** 0.442 *** 0.593 ***
(9.59) (8.48) (7.41)
Number of observations 1,176 1,172 757
Number of countries 79 79 57
Sargan Test 1112 1098 785.0
[chi square] 262.7 254.5 209.5
Notes: The dependent variable is the growth rate of real GDP
per capita at time t, starting with the end of conflict.
The model is estimated with the system-GMM dynamic panel
approach for the sample period 1960-2010.
The sample includes only post-conflict observations.
z-statistics are reported in parentheses, with *, **, and
*** indicating statistical significance at the 1%, 5%,
and 10% levels, respectively.
Source: Authors' estimations
Table 4: Estimation of different time regimes: System-GMM dynamic
panel
1960-1989
Variables Baseline Alternative
Real GDP per capita [growth.sub.t-1] 0.021 0.041
(0.58) (1.16)
Log real GDP per [capita.sub.t] -0.065 *** -0.085 ***
(-8.45) (-10.20)
Risk of conflict [recurrence.sub.t] -0.247 ** -0.315 ***
(-2.32) (-6.50)
Constant 0.503 *** 0.679 ***
(9.13) (10.72)
Number of observations 570 544
Number of countries 49 49
1990-2010
Variables Baseline Alternative
Real GDP per capita [growth.sub.t-1] 0.303 *** 0.337 ***
(6.76) (11.00)
Log real GDP per [capita.sub.t] -0.028 *** -0.053 ***
(-3.05) (-5.15)
Risk of conflict [recurrence.sub.t] -0.003 -0.197 **
(-0.02) (-2.16)
Constant 0.210 *** 0.409 ***
(2.71) (5.15)
Number of observations 1,172 597
Number of countries 86 75
Notes: The dependent variable is the growth rate of real GDP
per capita at time t, starting with the end of conflict.
The model is estimated with the system-GMM dynamic
panel approach for the sample period 1960-2010.
z-statistics are reported in parenthesis, with *, **,
and *** indicating statistical significance at the 1%,
5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
The sample includes only post-conflict data.
Source: Authors' estimations
Table 5: Estimation of different geographic specifications:
System-GMM dynamic panel
Variables Benchmark Model
excluding
Europe Middle East Asia
Real GDP per capita 0.197 *** 0.235 *** 0.238 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (8.21) (10.17) (10.27)
Log real GDP per -0.039 *** -0.037 *** -0.041 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-7.39) (-7.41) (-7.75)
Risk of conflict -0.126 *** -0.178 *** -0.200 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-2.72) (-3.79) (-3.85)
Constant 0.306 *** 0.298 *** 0.335 ***
(7.35) (7.55) (7.80)
Number of 1,582 1,620 1,539
observations
Number of 78 82 76
countries
Variables Benchmark Model
excluding
Africa Americas
Real GDP per capita 0.258 *** 0.224 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (9.41) (8.89)
Log real GDP per -0.025 *** -0.045 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-5.79) (-7.73)
Risk of conflict -0.144 *** -0.119 **
[recurrence.sub.t] (-4.27) (-2.28)
Constant 0.222 *** 0.341 ***
(6.46) (7.47)
Number of 1,141 1,291
observations
Number of 54 72
countries
Variables Alternative Model
excluding
Europe Middle East Asia
Real GDP per capita 0.224 *** 0.291 *** 0.270 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (9.14) (12.39) (11.23)
Log real GDP per -0.056 *** -0.043 *** -0.054 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-8.43) (-7.02) (-8.49)
Risk of conflict -0.157 *** -0.064 * -0.205 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-4.48) (-1.94) (-4.75)
Constant 0.433 *** 0.324 *** 0.437 ***
(8.63) (7.07) (8.76)
Number of 1,065 1,071 1,013
observations
Number of 69 71 66
countries
Variables Alternative Model
excluding
Africa Americas
Real GDP per capita 0.269 *** 0.252 ***
[growth.sub.t-1] (10.29) (9.57)
Log real GDP per -0.028 *** -0.068 ***
[capita.sub.t] (-5.00) (-9.04)
Risk of conflict -0.090 *** -0.140 ***
[recurrence.sub.t] (-3.07) (-3.83)
Constant 0.246 *** 0.513 ***
(5.46) (9.08)
Number of 768 834
observations
Number of 51 61
countries
Notes: The dependent variable is the growth rate of real GDP
per capita at time t, starting with the end of conflict.
The model is estimated with the system-GMM dynamic panel
approach for the sample period 1960-2010.
z-statistics are reported in parentheses, with *, **,
and *** indicating statistical significance at the 1%,
5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
The sample includes only post-conflict data.
Source: Authors' estimations