The low-interest-rate environment, global liquidity spillovers and challenges for monetary policy ahead.
Belke, Ansgar ; Verheyen, Florian
INTRODUCTION
Since July 2013, ECB President Mario Draghi has stated at each
press conference following the central bank's interest rate
decision that 'The Governing Council expects the key ECB interest
rates to remain at present or lower levels for an extended period of
time' (ECB, 2013a). This so-called 'forward guidance provides
an outlook on monetary policy for the upcoming years. The ECB
projections show that this low-interest-rate environment in the euro
area, almost hitting the zero lower bound, is in line with the
ECB's medium-term inflation target of below but close to 2% HICP
inflation. Inflation pressures in the euro zone remain subdued owing to
severe weaknesses in the real economy. Similar and even more rapid
interest rate decisions have been taken by other leading central banks
all around the globe--which in turn poses severe challenges for global
financial stability in the post-crisis environment.
The impact of global banking on financial stability and the
post-crisis challenges connected with the former have been
under-researched before the crisis. In our contribution, we decided to
interpret 'global banking' as 'global central
banking' and thus complement the other contributions to this
special issue from a macro-prudential perspective which are rather
focusing on 'global commercial banking' from a
macro-prudential perspective. Our core messages are important for the
conference theme as, for instance, sustained monetary accommodation
through international monetary policies and global liquidity hampers
comprehensive bank balance sheet repair. As recent experiences in the
euro area show this might have an impact on the degree of cross-border
banking as well. These few examples show that 'global banking'
and 'global central banking' are clear counterparts.
In this contribution, we thus focus on the role of international
monetary policies and global liquidity for financial stability and
thoroughly assess several main challenges emerging in this context. We
show that it is crucial to cope with the challenges identified by us in
order to return to and ensure global financial stability in the future.
This paper assesses and comments on several aspects of the implied
low-interest-rate environment, focusing in particular on spillover
effects. We also look at the post-crisis challenges lying ahead for
central banks. In the next few years, ultra-expansionary monetary policy
has to be driven back, which might give rise to repercussions within the
global macroeconomy if the policy exit is conducted without coordination
among the major central banks. For example, unilateral exits on one side
of the Atlantic might intensify the discussion and threats of currency
wars, since a trigger of capital flows would be followed by a
corresponding revaluation of exchange rates--which we actually saw when
the Fed began its tapering. Of course, this will be a balancing act
between tightening too early and exiting too late. Accordingly,
policymakers have to monitor carefully whether the huge increase in
central bank money feeds through into a boost in money and credit
growth. Thus, considerable challenges for policymakers in assuring
financial stability will remain in the future.
The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. The next section
begins with some general considerations of the current low-interest-rate
environment as it approaches the zero bound in advanced economies,
involving also negative real interest rates. The subsequent section
deals with potential and already manifest conflicts between monetary
policy and financial stability in a low-interest-rate environment. We
introduce and elucidate the monetary policy dilemma stemming from the
co-existence of low interest rates in major advanced economies and huge
capital inflows into emerging markets. We argue that sustained monetary
accommodation hampers comprehensive balance sheet repair. Moreover, we
infer that global monetary liquidity and its spillovers represent
important risks for global price and financial stability. Subsequently,
we assess whether and how central banks committed to safeguarding the
low-interest-rate environment may be risking their
independence--operationally and financially. Finally, we provide an
outlook on the inevitable monetary policy exit and its economic and
political implications. The final section concludes.
GENERAL CONSIDERATIONS
The current situation of negative real interest rates
One distinct feature of the 'new normal' economy seems to
be that interest rates are negative in real terms (after accounting for
inflation) and are expected by some to stay at that level. Such a
pattern of negative real interest rates has historical precedents: among
other things, real rates were negative after World War II and again in
the 1970s, with much higher inflation rates than those prevailing today
(Belke and Polleit, 2010b).
The probability distribution of expected inflation rates in the
euro area tells us that both the number of analysts who expect inflation
to go beyond the target and those predicting deflation are shrinking
steadily (Bundesbank, 2012, pp. 44I.). (1) Therefore, with inflation in
the euro area well anchored and short rates close to zero for a
prolonged period, as communicated by central bankers, real rates will
remain negative for a while. A similar analysis seems to apply to
long-term rates, with sovereign bond yields now falling below 2% in
Germany, the US and the United Kingdom. (2) The respective central banks
are targeting an inflation rate of 2% (only recently also in the case of
the Fed). (3) It directly follows that bond investors now expect to lose
money in real terms, whereas, for instance, the stepwise increase in
inflation that took place in the 1970s came quite unexpectedly.
Theoretical considerations regarding the zero lower bound
In the economic literature, the zero bound on nominal interest
rates is seen as a major constraint on monetary policy that wants to
keep the economy--via a change in the short-term interest rate--at full
employment (Belke and Polled, 2010b). This view rests on the notion that
the short-term interest rate is the key variable for monetary policy. As
a result, the zero bound is seen as a problem when nominal interest
rates are low (which, in turn, is typically the case when long-term
inflation is low (Johnson et al, 1999)). This is because a decline in
inflation could then push the real short-term interest rate above the
level compatible with keeping the economy at full employment.
For example, if economic activity is weak, and short-term interest
rates hit the zero bound, a dangerous dynamic might be set in motion.
With actual output falling below potential, inflation might slow down
further, increasing the real rate of interest. If the resulting real
interest rate is higher than the real interest rate needed for keeping
the economy at full employment, a downward deflationary spiral might be
set in motion: declining output, falling prices and an increase in the
real interest rate. The issue of the zero bound is in great part related
to the experience of the US in the Great Depression and came to the
surface again with unanticipated force at the beginning of 2009 in the
wake of the financial crisis. The debate gained momentum in the late
1990s, when economic growth in many countries was weak and, at the same
time, CPI inflation reached rather low levels by historical standards
(Belke and Polled, 2010b).
The risk ascribed to hitting the zero bound--and the severity of
the consequences --is usually assessed on the basis of empirical
analysis. Detailed studies of the US economy by Fuhrer and Madigan
(1997), Orphanides and Wieland (1998), Tetlow and Williams (1998) and
Reifschneider and Williams (1999) suggest that the risk associated with
zero inflation may be significant, but that an inflation of l%-3% p.a.
should be sufficient to alleviate most of that risk (Fuhrer and
Sniderman, 2000). (4)
If the central bank promises to keep inflation at, say, 2% p.a.,
then zero nominal market interest rates would suggest that the central
bank's inflation promise is not credible. Creating positive
inflation expectations, however, should be an easy undertaking under a
government-controlled paper money regime: there should be hardly any
doubt that the central bank can, if it wishes, increase the stock of
money at any time in any quantity desired. The zero bound is therefore a
rather unlikely steady-state phenomenon, even in today's monetary
environment. The same is valid for a deflation scenario, against which
there will be a prohibitively high political resistance, and the ECB
is--if this is demanded by politics--capable of extending the monetary
base by any preferred amount at any time. The bank could initially buy
sovereign and bank bonds and pay with freshly created central bank
money. From this perspective, for instance, a negative deposit rate
would be too complex and risky a measure for the more or less
hypothetical deflation problem. (5)
It does appear, after all, that the alleged zero bound nominal
interest rate problem is perhaps no problem at all, as Ben S. Bernanke
noted in 2002: 'Indeed, under a fiat (that is, paper) money system,
a government (in practice, the central bank in cooperation with other
agencies) should always be able to generate increased nominal spending
and inflation, even when the short-term nominal interest rate is at
zero'.
But only recently, in his speech at the IMF's Economic Forum
on 8 November 2013, Larry Summers invoked the old theories of secular
stagnation and argued that the Asian savings glut and a low price of
capital (computers are cheap) have in the recent past combined to imply
that the equilibrium real interest rate is smaller than zero. Monetary
policy, he said, cannot push the economy any further unless it risks
enormous asset price bubbles. In other words, excessive money growth
will in the end cause inflation--although in the short-to-medium run
money growth is for a couple of reasons not synonymous with inflation.
Instead, fiscal policy is preferred at least for the US because this
country is able to borrow at a 3 % rate in the long run, using a
currency which it is able to print.
However, his view has not been without criticism. Discussions
during the 2014 World Economic Forum in Davos were no exception in this
respect. Admittedly, '... the equilibrium long-run real interest
rate in the high-income countries has been ultra-low and the equilibrium
real short rate has been negative.... This was an obvious indicator of
sustained and chronic weakness of demand. ... Second, the main
instrument we have used to deal with this condition has been
hyper-aggressive monetary policy. But this creates substantial problems
it distributes income towards both the financial sector and the rich,
while also generating bubbles' (Wolf, 2014). Edmund Phelps also
argued in Davos that structural flaws on the supply side of the Western
economies are mainly responsible for the weakness in growth. The
innovation rate has gone down, a problem which cannot be solved by the
governments because they cannot serve as true innovators. (6)
Macroeconomic implications of a low-interest-rate environment
The level of interest rates can be viewed as the price that
equilibrates investment demand and the desire to save. From this point
of view, temporarily negative real rates that currently prevail in
almost all industrialized countries may simply indicate that savers are
generally cautious in times of uncertainty, and that entrepreneurs are
rather reluctant to invest in new projects. Central banks try to
influence this price by setting 'base' rates at which they
will supply liquidity to banks. They have also been employing
'quantitative easing'--that is, using freshly created central
bank money to purchase bonds--especially in the Anglo-Saxon countries
and in Japan with the intention of curbing longer-term yields. Their
intervention has had some impact, usually measured in terms of a real
interest rate equivalent (Belke, 2012a).
What exactly is the macroeconomic impact of a low-interest-rate
environment? The first thing that comes to mind is that the level of
real interest rates should be linked to economic growth, but not via the
trivial but often suggested transmission mechanism from lower rates to
higher growth. As the example of the currently distressed euro area
member countries clearly shows, you simply cannot, by definition, grow
out of a current account deficit, especially if you try to rekindle
growth through lower interest rates (Belke, 2013b).
Generally speaking, the realized level of the real interest rate
defines a threshold against which profitable projects should be
assessed. In order to avoid the danger of capital misallocation, the
interest rate must not be kept at too low a level that is not backed by
its fundamental drivers, for too long a period. Market participants will
then feel tempted to feed speculative real estate price trends instead
of financing the erection of new production facilities. The functioning
of a market economy and the realization of significant economic growth
thus decisively hinge on offering a positive return of capital to
suppliers (Belke and Polleit, 2010b; The Economist, 2012).
CONFLICTS BETWEEN MONETARY POLICY AND FINANCIAL STABILITY IN A
LOW-INTEREST-RATE ENVIRONMENT
To begin with, we introduce and elucidate the monetary policy
dilemma stemming from the co-existence of low interest rates in major
advanced economies and huge capital inflows into emerging markets
(section The monetary policy dilemma'). Closely related to these
issues, we infer that global monetary liquidity and its spillovers
represent important risks for global price and financial stability
(section 'Global monetary liquidity and its spillovers: the risks
for global price and financial stability'). Moreover, this paper
argues that sustained monetary accommodation hampers comprehensive
balance sheet repair (section 'Sustained monetary accommodation
hampers comprehensive balance sheet repair or maintains incentives to
damage balance sheets'). We also discuss why central banks
committed to safeguarding the low-interest-rate environment are risking
their independence--operationally and financially (section 'Central
banks are risking their independence--operationally and
financially'). Finally, additional risks stemming from the exit
from unconventional monetary policies are described (section
'Additional risks when conducting the exit').
The monetary policy dilemma
In order to gauge potential conflict between monetary policy and
financial stability, one should first take into account the co-existence
of low interest rates in major advanced economies and huge capital
inflows into emerging markets. This represents a dilemma for monetary
policy actors in emerging and advanced economies alike. Either they go
for low interest rates--a strategy which will obviously not curb a
credit boom--or they head for high interest rates--a safe way to attract
global financial or monetary liquidity anew. This may run counter to the
interests of those advanced countries planning their exit from
unconventional monetary policies or those of emerging market economies
which see their domestic credit boom even fuelled. (7) Emerging market
economies have traditionally shied away from the second alternative in
favor of the first. A potential way out of the dilemma might be to flank
higher interest rates with macro-prudential measures such as, for
example, higher capital ratios or tighter loan-to-value ratios. At the
least, this toolbox should strengthen a financial system against the
impacts of a credit bust (BIS, 2012), given that emerging
economies' monetary policies tend to be structurally too lax, as
measured by the difference between actual base rates and normative rates
such as those implied by the Taylor rule (BIS, 2012, Graph IV.6; Taylor,
2013).
In the same vein, the monetary policy strategy of inflation
targeting (IT), which has become popular on a worldwide scale, has
suffered from a couple of heavy setbacks, beginning in September 2008.
At that time it became obvious that those central banks relying on IT
strategies had not been cautious enough or had not paid enough attention
to asset price bubbles (Frankel, 2012). Instead, central bankers
continually argued that it would be sufficient to heed developments in
housing and equity prices in the sense that they convey information
about consumer price inflation. Moreover, they regularly contended that
there was no need for explicit monetary policy coordination among the
G-20 because it would best serve the interests of all if each country
kept 'its own house in order' (as reported by Belke et al,
2002, and recently stressed again by Taylor, 2013).
But it turned out that asset price developments warranted much more
than indirect attention, although there was no significant rise in
inflation before or after the financial crisis hit, indicating that
monetary policy was in fact much too lax in the years 2003-2005
(Frankel, 2012; Taylor, 2013). Also on a more general level, the main
lesson from the recent decade is that protracted monetary easing may
lead to significant asset price hikes and accelerating credit growth,
even in the absence of consumer price inflation (for the exact pattern
see Belke et al, 2010). Such a scenario might become relevant again in
the next few years. Although the ECB has lent out money for
unconventionally long periods, with its 3-year refinancing operations,
an economic recovery could stimulate money growth. Thus, the build-up of
(asset) price bubbles is a possible scenario for the future.
Hence, our experience of the financial crisis tells us that common
monetary policy strategies, including inflation targeting, must be
overhauled and that this overhaul should attach sufficient consideration
to the risks connected with the emergence of financial imbalances, even
if inflation remains moderate and invariable. In particular, the
monitoring of general financial conditions, such as volumes and prices
on specific asset markets, is of overall importance. Another important
conclusion is that the scope for, and the limitations of, a prolonged
monetary easing must be carefully weighed against each other. By
contrast, in the spirit of Milton Friedman and so often persuasively
explained by Ben Bernanke, forceful and determined action by central
banks in the wake of the global financial crisis could be well defended
in order to avoid the devastating consequences of monetary policy
abstinence and financial meltdown as experienced during and after the
Great Depression (BIS, 2012, Graph IV.8). Nevertheless, the following
discussion shows that the risks of extended easy monetary conditions are
more on the downside.
Global monetary liquidity and its spillovers: the risks for global
price and financial stability
Recent research on the impact of global monetary liquidity confirms
suggestions that low interest rates in advanced economies may well lead
to spillover effects in emerging markets, leading to upward pressure on
exchange rates in the latter countries, causing credit and asset bubbles
in emerging markets (such as Chinese property bubble) and, until
recently, inflated commodity prices (Belke et al, 2013; BIS, 2012,
Chapter III; The Economist, 2012). As a result, these countries can no
longer pursue their domestic stabilization objectives. Moreover,
financial imbalances similar to those in advanced economies in the
run-up to the crisis (and--with an eye on the growing importance of
these countries in international investment portfolios--the same
negative global repercussions in the case of unwinding) may arise.
A key drawback of a too easy global monetary policy is that it also
causes rises in commodity prices (Belke et al, 2013; BIS, 2012, Graph
IV.9, left-hand panel). Although commodity price inflation has taken
place particularly in emerging markets, it might feed into the inflation
of advanced economies because emerging market economies are increasingly
important in global supply chains. Commodity prices are determined on
global auction markets and depend on conditions of global demand, which
are in turn shaped by global monetary balances in the hands of investors
(for details see Belke et al, 2010). The increasing role of financial
investors in commodity markets ('financialization') has surely
kindled the sensitivity of prices to international monetary conditions
and global financial liquidity which is closely correlated with global
monetary liquidity (ECB, 2012; BIS, 2011, Box IV.B.).
The fact that monetary policy spillovers are becoming increasingly
significant forces central banks to attach more importance to the global
implications of their policies. To attain lasting price and financial
stability in times of ever greater financial globalization, monetary
policy should have a global perspective. It seems that it is no longer
sufficient simply to keep one's own house in order and disregard
external developments. Instead, a macroprudential framework has to be
created (Borio, 2011). Otherwise, we will find ourselves in a world in
which depreciations thought of as a 'beggar thy neighbor'
policy (currency wars) can no longer be excluded. (8) As a stylized
fact, policy makers in a few developed economies such as Japan are
currently expressing their concerns about competitive devaluations due
to monetary policies by the Fed and the ECB and have announced monetary
easing to a degree previously unseen.
This insight is also impressively backed up by recent empirical
studies such as those by Taylor (2013) and Hofmann and Bogdanova (2012).
These show that in the years 2003-2005 monetary policies worldwide found
themselves in a 'bad equilibrium'. This means that in many
industrialized countries, and also in emerging market economies, nominal
interest rates were below those levels implied by historical Taylor
rules. Policy interest rates fell below the Taylor rule in close
synchronization across countries. Thus, monetary policy was too
accommodative and perhaps contributed to the build-up of financial
market imbalances prior to the crisis. One explanation they provide for
this unsustainable equilibrium is that there is a lower equilibrium real
interest rate. Another is that central banks decided on policy rates no
longer in an independent way. Although interest rates have been set
according to national conditions up to the turn of the century, policy
reactions are increasingly affected by the international environment.
Hence, the deviations might indicate a substantial shift in the monetary
policy regime. Among others, Kim (2000) has demonstrated that US
monetary policy shocks can affect other countries. Belke and Gros (2005)
provided evidence that the ECB followed the Fed in their interest rate
decisions. In fact, low domestic interest rates can increase risk taking
in other countries, and one way to react is to lower interest rates also
abroad; see Bruno and Shin (2012). In addition, central banks tend to
resist large appreciations of their currencies, and adjust their
interest rates according to the behavior of other central banks.
Deviations of policy rates from the Taylor rule may strengthen due to
international spillovers (Taylor, 2013). Most importantly, the actions
of the Federal Reserve Bank (Fed) have been amplified due to the
responses of other central banks (Gray, 2012).
Sustained monetary accommodation hampers comprehensive balance
sheet repair or maintains incentives to damage balance sheets
It has become obvious during the crisis that sustained monetary
accommodation has been hampering comprehensive balance sheet repair or
maintaining incentives to damage balance sheets both for the private and
the public sector, but also for sovereigns to restructure their
financial sectors and to implement reforms to secure sustainable debt
burdens. The main drivers of this nexus are the following.
The decrease in interest rates lowers financing costs and, hence,
may cause borrowers to simply ignore the problems still inherent in
their balance sheets. As a consequence, balance sheets remain weak and
credit misallocated. These problems then tend to become structural and
any reversion to normal interest rate levels in the future might cause
great damage to these institutions. (9) Hence, an exit from
unconventional monetary policies becomes an even more remote option and
the current policy stance might become self-sustaining and
path-dependent (Belke, 2012b; The Economist, 2012).
What is more, owing to an impaired financial system and
over-indebted economic agents who are not at all inclined to borrow for
spending, one needs an even higher degree of monetary accommodation than
before the financial crisis in order to rekindle growth (a footprint of
the 'new normal'). This higher monetary stimulus, in turn,
will once more lower the incentives for commercial banks to repair their
balance sheets and for sovereigns to strive to restructure their
financial sectors and to conduct reforms to secure sustainable debt
burdens (IMF, 2012; Bundesbank, 2014; and Belke et al, 2006). The recent
euro area crisis has clearly shown how intertwined banking and sovereign
crises are and thus how dependent financial stability is on a risk-free
status of government debt (Belke, 2013a, b; BIS, 2012, Chapter V). (10)
Admittedly, monetary policy easing, metaphorically speaking, like a
bazooka gives banks and governments ample time for balance sheet repair
and thus avoids disorderly deleveraging and defaults. Moreover, in the
short run it is able to lift asset prices and, thus, output and labor
market performance on a higher level. But in order to be forced to
repair their balance sheets, commercial banks should receive a bold and
credible signal from the central banks that their policies of very low
interest rates will be put to an end in the near future. This is
especially valid, considering the fact that commercial banks, above all
in Europe, are heavily dependent on central bank funding (Belke, 2012c;
BIS, 2012, Chapter VI). Unfortunately, the opposite is happening right
now: central banks such as the US-Fed and the BoJ commit themselves to
perpetuating monetary policy easing and the ECB stresses also that
interest rates will be kept low for a protracted period of time. To
overcome this situation of delaying balance sheet adjustments, the ECB
has begun an asset quality review (AQR) to evaluate the balance sheets
of some 130 European banks. This should be an incentive for commercial
banks to repair their balance sheets because a negative evaluation would
probably lead to severe funding problems (Mersch, 2014). There is also
some first empirical evidence of deferred repair because rates are so
low. (11)
What is more, commercial banks are prompted to overestimate the
repayment capacity of their borrowers in a low-interest-rate environment
because of the perceived low opportunity cost of carrying non-performing
loans (Albertazzi and Marchetti, 2010; Caballero et al, 2008; Peek and
Rosengren, 2003 for Italy and Japan). At least, this is indicated by the
fact that US private households deleverage by taking up fewer new loans
instead of writing off unsustainable debt such as mortgage loans (BIS,
2012, Chapter III), and that subdued market-to-book ratios for
commercial banks have coexisted with loan loss provisions that are
depressed even though macroeconomic conditions still appear weak (BIS,
2012, Table VI. 1).
The flip side of the coin is that commercial banks tend to become
overly optimistic about the ability of borrowers to repay, and thus do
not adequately provide for bad debts. Moreover, they receive a public
subsidy since they are able to make 'easy money' just by
borrowing short term from the central bank and lending long term to the
Government (The Economist, 2012). Quite naturally then, the question
emerges of for how long this subsidy can be considered legitimate from a
welfare-maximizing point of view. This may also be seen as an indirect
way of financing sovereign debt by the printing press (Gros et al,
2012), which is actually prohibited for the ECB and the US, according to
the treaties.
Protracted monetary accommodation may also systematically curb the
profitability of commercial banks (Albertazzi and Gambacorta, 2009). If
the yield curves flatten because the low short-term interest rates are
anticipated to prevail also in the future (an effect that is intended by
the Fed's 'Operation Twist), this will ultimately lead to an
erosion of the banks' interest income because returns from maturity
transformation will shrink (BIS, 2012). (12)
Furthermore, protracted low interest rates may contribute to a
build-up of financial vulnerabilities by 'triggering a search for
yield in unwelcome segments' (BIS, 2012). In this sense, monetary
expansion was useful in the beginning to counter excessive risk
aversion, but any overshooting of this effect (expressing itself in
trading losses by some financial institutions) should be avoided.
Empirical evidence supports the relevance of this channel as one driving
force of the recent financial crisis (Altunbas et al., 2012; Maddaloni
and Peydro, 2011).
In addition, low policy rates and protracted unconventional
monetary policies, in particular aggressive variants of monetary
accommodation, may have distortionary side effects on financial and
capital markets (Belke, 2012a). They have altered the dynamics of
overnight money markets, an effect which in itself is hampering any exit
from these aggressive policies (BIS, 2012, Box IV.B, p. 46). Moreover,
they have dampened market signals by lowering long-term interest rates
and financial market risk spreads as well as the price of sound assets
which are not 'subsidized' by them. Since long-term yields on
sovereign bonds, as a key benchmark for financial intermediation, are
pushed to exceptionally low levels (BIS, 2012, Graph IV.4), financial
mispricing has become possible on a more general level. As an immediate
consequence of this, the inter-temporal and inter-sectoral allocation of
resources may no longer be effective.
Central banks are risking their independence--operationally and
financially
As stated above, the probability distribution of expected inflation
rates in the major advanced and emerging market economies tells us that,
as things stand, long-term inflation expectations appear to be
well-anchored. However, this should not make us too complacent and tempt
us to interpret it as ample room for additional monetary policy easing.
The reason is simply that the credibility of central banks in advanced
economies must not be jeopardized in view of the potentially growing
public pressure to do more if, for instance, the euro area is successful
in solving its structural problems and the economy, especially in the
periphery, remains weak (Belke, 2013a, b; Belke et al., 2012).
'A vicious circle can develop, with a widening gap between
what central banks are expected to deliver and what they can actually
deliver. This would make the eventual exit from monetary accommodation
harder and may ultimately threaten central banks'
credibility', warns the BIS (2012, p. 48), thus adding to our
path-dependence argument, as developed above, against a timely exit from
unconventional monetary policies. If, in addition, emerging market
economies do continuously stick to export-led growth and their foreign
exchange interventions to enhance their international competitiveness,
markets will feel legitimized to put the central banks'
determination to pursue price stability under close scrutiny. This is
because, among others, an undervalued currency increases the costs of
imports such as commodities. Both the tendencies of central banks'
fiscal involvement in advanced economies and the strategies of
undervalued currencies in emerging economies, taken together, finally
have the potential to slowly unfasten inflation expectations on a global
scale.
Longer-term inflation fears stemming from the enduring
low-interest-rate environment are reinforced by steadily increasing
risks on the political economy side--just to mention the notions of
'fiscal dominance' (13) and 'financial repression'
(14) in combination with the regulatory preference for investment in
sovereign bonds. Bundesbank President Jens Weidmann was not the first to
observe that central banks' unconventional monetary policies
working via its balance sheet have clearly blurred the line between
monetary and fiscal policy (Jens Weidmann in FAZ, 2012). As evidence of
'fiscal dominance' and 'financial repression'
becomes ever stronger, an increasing reliance on quantitatively and
qualitatively extraordinary monetary policy measures raises concerns
about a decline in the operational and financial autonomy of the central
banks. Dangers emerge because 'fiscal dominance' implies a
bias among leading central banks toward fiscal policy considerations.
What is more, 'financial repression' of the Northern euro area
members may, for example, mean fuelling the conflict between the North
and the South within the euro area. Financial repression' could, in
the case of the US Fed, be tantamount to an orientation of monetary
policy towards financially repressing the rest of the world in order to
lower the real value of US debt in the interest of the US Government
(Reinhart, 2012; Reinhart and Sbrancia, 2011). Both channels put central
banks such as the ECB under pressure and at risk of more or less
directly financing public debt. This is especially so because public
debt is still on an unsustainable path in many countries and inflation
and the inflation tax are, from a political economy point of view,
easier ways out of the mess than budget consolidation or default (Burda
and Wyplosz, 2012; BIS, 2012, Chapter V). In other words, the main
incentive problem is that accommodative monetary policy tends to
alleviate the pressure on politicians to reform. The impression must at
all costs be avoided that central banks stand ready at any time to
employ their balance sheets to come up with solutions to economic and
financial problems {The Economist, 2012).
The continuously rising financial exposure in the overstretched
central banks' balance sheets (such as, eg, the interest rate risk
of the Fed and the credit risk of the ECB) may furthermore impede their
financial independence. Financial losses do not per se have a negative
bearing on central banks operational capabilities, since a 'fiscal
backing' is available from their governments --with a slight
complication in the euro area, where national governments provide the
backing of the ESCB (Belke and Polleit, 2010a). But it is the very
existence of this fiscal backing which could undermine operational
autonomy, as soon as the central bank is not capable of pursuing its
main monetary policy objectives without taking recourse to financial
help from the Government (Stella, 2010; Belke and Polleit, 2010a).
All in all, it seems fair to say that the current stability of
long-term inflation expectations cannot be taken for granted. In the
case of an erosion of the central banks' credibility and a steady
rise in inflation expectations, it would be very costly in terms of the
necessary adjustment recession to restore price stability, as is
impressively shown by the experience of the 1970s (Belke and Polleit,
2010b).
Additional risks when conducting the exit
Although, from today's perspective, it seems as if a return to
the interest rate levels seen before the financial crisis will take
considerable time, we will nevertheless sketch some implications and
risks which might emerge in such an exit scenario. (15) Generally, as
nearly all major central banks in the world currently operate at or
close to the zero lower bound, interest rate levels are very much alike
across the industrialized economies. Nevertheless, a timely exit is
necessary because any delay could again lead to capital misallocation,
speculation with the emergence of new bubbles and, of course, inflation.
In addition, a delayed exit would lead to a destabilization of inflation
expectations.
In general, recovery from the recession could well differ across
regions. For example, the euro zone with its sovereign debt crisis faces
a different macroeconomic situation, which somehow limits the ECB to
act, as compared with the US or Japan. Furthermore, varying objective
functions of the central banks contribute to these differences. Of
course, these asymmetries will complicate any exit from the expansionary
monetary policy of the last years.
Any uncoordinated exit or an exit at a different pace may intensify
tensions regarding the international exchange rate configuration,
especially if it is not well communicated by a truly committed forward
guidance. In one scenario, the exit may be quicker in the euro area than
in the US, which through euro appreciation might hamper the necessary
economic recovery of the euro area. In another currently more probable,
scenario, the Fed exits first. (16) Here, the risk is a
'growth-driven exit with complications' (IMF, 2013a).
Long-term interest rates in the US are no longer well anchored, and
uncertainty indicators, 'investors' fear gauges' and,
finally, also the interest rate premium leap up as monetary policy is
tightened. The fact that rates keep their level for quite a while
amplifies capital outflows from the remaining countries. These effects
relate primarily to high-risk countries. Except for countries with very
strong trade links with the US, the outcome in terms of output would
worsen.
Note that, in this scenario, it is not primarily the presumed
exchange rate effect (if it manifests itself) which might cause the
trouble (Belke, 2013a). The starting point of any simulation exercise
(better: the IMF's) concerning the Fed's exit is that US
monetary policy should become more restrictive as soon as the US economy
is back on track. Both items--a more restrictive monetary policy and
higher US growth--trigger capital flows into the US and an increase in
interest rates across the world, which per se slow down world economic
activity. (17) But higher US growth and exchange rate depreciation
vis-a-vis the US dollar should ceteris paribus let other countries
profit, especially countries such as those in the euro area with
significant exports to the US and equity markets that are closely
correlated with US equities. Hence, the relative significance of each
transmission channel and some idiosyncratic country conditions determine
the net outcome for an economy such as the euro area (IMF, 2013a). But
that means also that the scenario of an exit without growth' (IMF,
2013a) cannot be fully excluded. This is a scenario in which any growth
momentum is absent and exit is initiated prematurely, with an eye on
increasingly pressing financial risks. In this case, the impact of
tapering on output may be negative worldwide. However, these effects may
be less unpalatable than allowing bubbles to emerge and then burst (IMF,
2013a, b, p. 16).
Fears of currency wars and claims of foreign exchange market
interventions have thus been voiced in recent times and could be
reinforced in the future. Unilateral interest rate increases could be
one reason and may heat up this debate, bringing additional tension into
the international monetary system. Capital controls or interventions in
foreign exchange markets could gain momentum (Taylor, 2013).
Furthermore, a unilateral exit would probably be less effective. Rising
interest rates would trigger liquidity inflows which would counteract
the exit (Belke et al, 2014). Policymakers might be tempted to preclude
these inflows by capital controls.
Policymakers in the euro zone in particular should therefore be
mindful of this exit. Assuming that the European debt crisis will
continue for several years, an exit in the Anglo-Saxon countries might
start before the macroeconomic environment allows for it in the euro
area. Accordingly, capital flows to the US might lead to a depreciation
of the euro. Superficially, this might be seen as a welcome effect in
many countries in Europe which suffer from deficits of international
competitiveness. However, all the countries of the monetary union will
benefit from a euro's devaluation. Thus, Germany or the
Netherlands, which are competitive on international markets, could
increase their current account position. In effect, the intra-EMU
current account imbalances could widen. Considering that Germany will
achieve a record surplus in its current account in 2013, further
political problems may appear on the agenda. Ambitions for an adjustment
mechanism to restrict current account surpluses within the euro zone
could arise.
Thus, it seems that it is no longer enough for central bankers to
focus merely on national interests. To cope with a return to more normal
interest rate levels, a coordination of monetary policies across the
globe is necessary (Taylor, 2013). Angeloni et al. (2010) even state
that the exit will be more complicated to handle than the measures taken
in response to the crisis. Apart from the need for international
coordination, national interests will still have to be taken into
account. Just think of the interplay between fiscal and monetary policy.
Every rise in interest rates comes at the price of increasing costs in
debt service. But, on the other hand, fiscal reforms and a return to
(more) sustainable public finances provide central bankers with more
leeway to raise interest rates, as macroeconomic indicators should--at
least in the medium term--improve with fiscal consolidation (Angeloni et
al, 2010). However, coordination between monetary and fiscal authorities
undermines the independence of central banks. Thus, in this regard it
will be a tightrope walk to find the right amount of coordination.
CONCLUSION
Recent monetary policy easing due to the financial and economic
crisis has led to a situation where nominal interest rates have reached
the zero lower bound. As inflation rates and expectations remain
positive, real interest rates have in effect become negative. This paper
has sketched some of the challenges and implications that arise in this
low-interest-rate environment. It has turned out that low interest rates
hamper balance sheet consolidation, and ample liquidity leads to
spillover effects which endanger price and financial stability.
Furthermore, central banks are becoming more and more involved in
quasi-fiscal policies which limit their independence. All this shows
that the current monetary policy alignment gives cause for concern. In
effect, monetary policy has to carefully monitor whether and when a
turnaround of ultra-expansionary monetary policies is possible.
Unfortunately, an exit from the current policy stance will not be an
easy undertaking. This is corroborated, for example, by the fact that
the mere announcement that the Fed might scale down its unconventional
monetary policy operations has recently induced capital flight, that is,
a sudden stop in capital inflows, from emerging markets (Gros, 2013).
At first sight, fears arising from these capital flow reversals
appear to be well founded and the imposition of capital outflow controls
looms on the G-20 agenda (IMF, 2013a, b). The external values of many
emerging market currencies have been plummeting, and their central banks
have been actively tightening their policies, aiming at stabilizing
their economies' financial markets (Gros, 2013). Central banks in
India, Brazil, South Africa and Turkey have felt forced to take action
to shore up their currencies, in some cases with significant interest
rate increases. However, we view the permanence of these recent events
with caution. Future research should check whether the US Fed or even
the euro zone's austerity measures and its weak internal demand are
to blame for this state of affairs (Gros, 2013).
In this context, however, Fed-style 'forward guidance'
tends to further stimulate the inclination of investors to take more
risks. Excess monetary liquidity may spill over to other economies and
cause stability risks there. At the 2013 Jackson Hole Conference, even
the bon mot 'zero interest rates make risk taking cheap; forward
guidance makes it free (by eliminating all roll over risk on short term
funding positions)' (Landau, 2013, p. 9) did the round. Without any
doubt, the Woodford (2008) variant of forward guidance which seems to be
followed by the Fed creates massive incentives to enlarge and even
overstretch open positions. As the strong movements of the world's
stock markets after Ben Bernanke's now-famous statements in May
2013 have clearly shown, the Fed has by its efforts to calm down the
markets harvested the contrary, higher volatility (Lauricella and Burne,
2013). This clearly reminds us of the 'liquidity spirals'
described in the model developed by Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009).
Uncoordinated action then will be accompanied by additional problems.
Thus, considerable post-crisis challenges for monetary policy remain in
the years to come. It seems crucial to cope with the challenges
identified by us in order to return to and ensure global financial
stability in the future. We feel legitimized to argue that careful
global coordination of monetary policies and a well-communicated exit
from unconventional monetary policies may represent means to avoid a
back-to-back crisis. Any uncoordinated exit from unconventional monetary
policy measures might provoke further disruption and tensions on
international financial markets.
Acknowledgements
This paper is based on an internal briefing paper prepared by the
author for presentation at the Committee on Economic and Monetary
Affairs of the European Parliament for the quarterly dialogue with the
President of the European Central Bank, February 2013, in Brussels. The
authors are grateful for valuable comments received from Paul Wachtel
and other participants at the 2012 Symposium 'Global Banking,
Financial Stability, and Post-Crisis Policy Challenges' in
Maastricht, NL.
REFERENCES
Albertazzi, U and Gambacorta, L. 2009: Bank profitability and the
business cycle. Journal of Financial Stability 5(4): 393-409.
Albertazzi, U and Marchetti, D. 2010: Credit supply, flight to
quality and evergreening: an analysis of bank-firm relationships after
Lehman. Bank of Italy, Temi di Discussione (Working Papers), No. 756,
April.
Altunbas, Y, Gambacorta, L and Marques, D. 2012: Do bank
characteristics influence the effect of monetary policy on bank risk?
Economic Letters 117(1): 220-222.
Angeloni, I, Faia, E and Winkler, R. 2010: Exit strategies. CFS
Working Paper no. 2010/25.
Bank for International Settlements. 2011: 81st Annual Report,
Basle, June.
Bank for International Settlements. 2012: 82nd Annual Report,
Basle, June.
Belke, A. 2012a: ECB and Fed crisis policies at the
zero-lower-bound--An empirical assessment based on modified reaction
functions. Briefing paper prepared for presentation at the Committee on
Economic and Monetary Affairs of the European Parliament for the
quarterly dialogue with the President of the European Central Bank,
July, Brussels.
Belke, A. 2012b: A more effective eurozone monetary policy
tool--Gold-backed sovereign debt. Briefing paper prepared for
presentation at the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs of the
European Parliament for the quarterly dialogue with the President of the
European Central Bank, September, Brussels.
Belke, A. 2012c: 3-year LTROs--A first assessment of a non-standard
policy measure. Briefing paper prepared for presentation at the
Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs of the European Parliament
for the quarterly dialogue with the President of the European Central
Bank, March, Brussels.
Belke, A. 2013a: Exit strategies and their impact on the euro
area--A model based view. Briefing paper prepared for presentation at
the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs of the European
Parliament for the quarterly dialogue with the President of the European
Central Bank, December, Brussels.
Belke, A. 2013b: The eurozone crisis--a tale of north and south.
The Statesman's Yearbook. Palgrave Macmillan: Houndmills,
Basingstoke.
Belke, A and Gros, D. 2005: Asymmetries in trans-atlantic monetary
policy making: does the ECB follow the Fed? Journal of Common Market
Studies 43(5): 921-946.
Belke, A and Polleit, T. 2010a: How much fiscal backing must the
ECB have? The euro area is not the Philippines. Economie Internationale
124(4): 5-30.
Belke, A and Polleit, T. 2010b: Monetary economics in globalised
financial markets. Springer: Berlin. Belke, A, Bordon, I and Hendricks,
T. 2010: Global liquidity and commodity prices--A co-integrated VAR
approach for OECD countries. Applied Financial Economics 20(3): 227-242.
Belke, A, Bordon, I and Volz, U. 2013: Effects of global liquidity
on commodity and food prices. World Development 44 (April): 31-43.
Belke, A, Beckmann, J and Czudaj, R. 2014: The importance of global
shocks for national policymakers--Rising challenges for sustainable
monetary policies, The World Economy, forthcoming, doi:
10.1111/twec.l2127.
Belke, A, Herz, B and Vogel, L. 2006: Reforms, exchange rates and
monetary commitment: A panel analysis for OECD countries. Open Economies
Review 18(3): 369-388.
Belke, A, Orth, W and Setzer, R. 2010: Liquidity and the dynamic
pattern of asset price adjustment: A global view. Journal of Banking and
Finance 34(8): 1933-1945.
Belke, A, Freytag, A, Keil, J and Schneider, F. 2012: The
credibility of monetary policy announcements: Empirical evidence for
OECD countries since the 1960s. DIW Discussion Paper No. 1225/2012,
Deutsches Institut fur Wirtschaftsforschung, Berlin.
Belke, A, Koesters, W, Leschke, M and Polleit, T. 2002:
International coordination of monetary policy, ECB Observer--Analyses of
the Monetary Policy of the European System of Central Banks, No. 4,
Frankfurt/Main, 19 December.
Bernanke, BS. 21 November 2002: Deflation: making sure
'it' doesn't happen here. Remarks by the Governor before
the national economists club, Washington, DC,
http://www.federalreserve.gov/
boardDocs/speeches/2002/20021121/default.htm, accessed 1 March 2014.
Braunberger, G. 2013: Die Zinsen steigen,
http://www.faz.net/aktueU/finanzen/fonds-mehr/
staatsanleihen-die-zinsen-steigen-12561500.html, accessed 1 March 2014.
Borio, C. 2011: Central banking post-crisis: what compass for
uncharted watersl BIS Working Papers No. 353, Basle.
Bruno, V and Shin, HS. 2012: Capital flows and the risk-taking
channel of monetary policy. Paper presented at the 11th BIS Annual
Conference, Basle.
Brunnermeier, MK and Pedersen, LH. 2009: Market liquidity and
funding liquidity. The Review of Financial Studies 22(6): 2201-2238.
Bundesbank. 2012: Monthly Bulletin, Frankfurt/Main, November.
Bundesbank. 2014: Private debt--status quo, need for adjustment and
policy implications. Monthly Bulletin, Frankfurt/Main, pp. 53-65,
January.
Burda, M and Wyplosz, C. 2012: Macroeconomics--a European text, 6th
Edition. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Caballero, R, Hoshi, T and Kashyap, A. 2008: Zombie lending and
depressed restructuring in Japan. American Economic Review 98(5):
1943-1977.
Danske Bank. 2013: Negative deposit rates: the Danish experience,
http://danskeanalyse.danskebank.dk/
abo/NegativeratesinDKNovember2013/$file/Negative_rates_in_DK_November_2013.pdf, accessed 1 March 2014.
European Central Bank. 2012: Global liquidity: concepts, measures
and implications from a monetary policy perspective. Monthly Bulletin,
October, Frankfurt/Main: European Central Bank, pp. 55-68.
European Central Bank. 2013a: Introductory statement to the press
conference, Frankfurt/Main, 4 July,
http://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pressconf/2013/html/isl30704.en.html,
accessed 1 March 2014.
European Central Bank. 2013b: Financial Stability Review,
Frankfurt/Main, November.
Frankel, J. 2012: The death of inflation targeting.
ProjectSyndicate, 16 May.
Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung. 2012: Bundesbankprasident Weidmann
Die Ursachen der Krise sind noch lange nicht beseitigt', 29
December.
Fuhrer, J and Madigan, BF. 1997: Monetary policy when interest
rates are bounded at zero. The Review of Economics and Statistics 74(4):
573-585.
Fuhrer, J and Sniderman, M. 2000, November: Monetary policy in a
low-inflation environment: conference summary, in: Fuhrer, J and
Schneiderman, M (eds). Monetary policy in a low-inflation environment.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32(4): 845-869.
Gray, C. 2012: Responding to a monetary superpower--Investigating
the behavioral spillovers of US monetary policy. Atlantic Economic
Journal 41 (2): 173-184.
Gros, D. 2013: Emerging markets' Euro nemesis, CEPS
Commentaries, Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS), Brussels, 9
September.
Gros, D, Alcidi, C and Giovanni, A. 2012: Central banks in times of
crisis: The FED vs. the ECB. CEPS Policy Brief No. 276.
Hofmann, B and Bogdanova, B. 2012: Taylor rules and monetary
policy: A global great deviation? BIS Quarterly Review (September).
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2012: Restoring confidence and
progressing on reforms. Global Financial Stability Report, World
Economic and Financial Surveys, Washington/DC, October.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2013a: IMF multilateral issues
report--Spillover report. International Monetary Fund: Washington/DC,
August.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2013b: Global Financial
Stability Report. Old risks--new challenges, Chapter 3: Do central bank
policies since the crisis carry risks to financial stability?
Washington/DC, April.
Johnson, K, Small, D and Tyron, R. 1999: Monetary policy and price
stability. International Economics and Finance Discussion Paper, 641,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Washington, DC.
Kim, S. 2000: International transmission of US monetary policy
shocks: Evidence from VARs. Journal of Monetary Economics 48(2):
339-372.
Landau, JP. 2013: Global liquidity: Public and private. Economic
Symposium on 'Global dimensions of unconventional monetary
policy', Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 22-24 August.
Lauricella, T and Burne, K. 2013: Turmoil exposes global risks. The
Wall Street Journal, 21 June,
http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB100014241278873238935045785568816405027001mg--reno 64-wsj&url=http%3 A%2
F%2Fonline.wsj.com%2Farticle%2FSBl 0001424127887323893504578
556881640502700.html, accessed 1 March 2014.
Maddaloni, A and Peydro, J-L. 2011: Bank risk-taking,
securitization, supervision, and low interest rates: Evidence from the
euro-area and the US lending standards. Review of Financial Studies
24(6). 2121-2165.
Mayer, T. 2014: Larry Summers' interest rate conundrum, CEPS
High Level Brief, Centre for European Policy Studies, Brussels, 16
January.
Mersch, Y. 2014: Reviving growth in the euro area, Speech at the
Institute of International European Affairs, Dublin, 7 February,
https://www.bis.org/review/rl4021 la.htm?ql=l, accessed 1 March 2014.
Orphanides, A and Wieland, V. 1998, August: Price stability and monetary
policy effectiveness when nominal interest rates are bounded at zero.
Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 1998-35,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System: Washington, DC.
Peek, J and Rosengren, ES. 2003: Unnatural selection: Perverse
incentives and the misallocation of credit in Japan. NBER Working Paper
9643, National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA.
Reifschneider, D and Williams, JC. 1999, September: Three lessons
for monetary policy in a low inflation era. Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, Working Paper, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System: Washington, DC.
Reinhart, C-M. 2012: The return of financial repression. CEPR
Discussion Papers Series, 8947, London.
Reinhart, CM and Sbrancia, MB. 2011: The liquidation of government
debt. NBER Working Paper Series 16893: Cambridge, MA.
Sargent, TJ and Wallace, N. 1981: Some unpleasant monetarist
arithmetic. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review
5(Fall): 1-17.
Stella, P. 2010: Minimising monetary policy. BIS Working Papers,
No. 330, Bank for International Settlements, Basle, November.
Svensson, LEO. 2003: Escaping from a liquidity trap and deflation:
The foolproof way and others. NBER Working Paper No. 10195: Cambridge,
MA.
Taylor, JB. 2013: International monetary coordination and the great
deviation. Paper presented at the Session on International Policy
Coordination, American Economic Association Annual Meetings, San Diego,
CA, January.
Tetlow, R and Williams, JC. 1998, March: Implementing price
stability: Bands, boundaries and inflation targeting. Federal Reserve
Board Staff Working Paper.
The Economist. 2012: The side-effects of low interest rates, 30
June.
Wolf, M. 2014: Davos thoughts: secular stagnation. Financial Times,
24 January.
Woodford, M. 2008: Forward guidance for monetary policy: Is it
still possible? VoxEU, 17 January,
http://www.voxeu.org/article/forward-guidance-monetary-policy-it-still-possible, accessed 1 March 2014.
ANSGAR BELKE [1,2,3] & FLORIAN VERHEYEN [1]
[1] University of Duisburg-Essen, Lehrstuhl fur
VoLkswirtschaftslehre, insbes. Makrookonomik, Universitatsstrasse 12,
Essen D-45117, Germany.
[2] Policy Department A: Economic and Scientific Policy, European
Parliament, B-1047, Brussels.
[3] IZA Bonn, Schaumburg-Lippe-Strasse, 5-953113, Bonn, Germany.
(1) In addition, some important business climate indicators such as
those produced by the European research institutes Ifo, INSEE und ISTAT
are turning upwards and monetary conditions in the euro area are
currently very accommodative.
(2) However, since the end of summer 2013 there seems to have been
some reversal, as interest rates on Government debt, for example in
Germany and the UK, have started increasing again (Braunberger, 2013).
(3) Also more generally, market- and survey-based indicators of
long-term inflation expectations have remained rather stable and are
approaching central banks' inflation goals. See BIS (2012, Graph
IV.10).
(4) At this juncture it should be noted that it is hard to imagine
that an economy's real interest rate should ever reach zero in
equilibrium. As long as human desires are not fully satisfied, there is
always something to gain from investing a part of current income,
thereby increasing future income. As a consequence, there should always
be a positive real interest rate in the medium-to-long run, and this is
what we should basically define as a 'low interest rate
environment'.
(5) Nevertheless, Japan still faces problems of low inflation
rates. The reason why such a massive deflationary scenario could emerge
in Japan is frequently attributed to policy mistakes such as the lack of
an exit strategy that specifies when and how to get back to normal
(Svensson, 2003). Furthermore, negative nominal rates might cause
'unintended consequences'. For example, the Danish experience
of negative nominal rates was that banks increased lending rates to
compensate for these negative rates (Danske Bank, 2013).
(6) See also Mayer (2014) who points out some lack of theoretical
and empirical support of the Summers thesis and offers as an alternative
explanation the fall-out from the recent credit boom-bust cycle.
(7) Here, we refer to the situation before the Fed announced its
tapering, and to a scenario in which this announcement is not
anticipated as credible and sustainable by the markets. For different
scenarios see the section 'Additional risks when conducting the
exit'. For the relationship between monetary and financial market
liquidity, see ECB (2012, p. 57).
(8) The 'beggar thy neighbor' policy must not necessarily
become public immediately. For example, the US sold its QE as a policy,
in essence aiming to lower interest rates within the US economy and thus
foster spending and investment--to stimulate 'aggregate
demand', not least with benefits arguably accruing to the rest of
the world.
(9) However, in the following paragraphs we show in different ways
(eg, alluding to the term structure of interest rates) that the argument
for credit misallocation is significant here, although banks borrow
short.
(10) As sovereign bonds are classified as risk-free, banks do not
have to hold equity capital for these assets. However, if doubts about
the sustainability of public finances emerge, as was the case in several
countries of the EMU, the liquidity of the banking system is threatened.
These (large) banks may then have to be bailed out by governments, which
in turn aggravates government debt levels. In consequence, issuing new
sovereign bonds becomes more costly and banks can no longer purchase
them. Accordingly, there is a need to break this vicious circle of banks
and sovereigns destabilizing each other and to disentangle the fate of
the banks and that of government debt.
(11) See, for instance, IMF (2013a, pp. 109ff.), based on
bank-level data for the US. The required data are available for
relatively few banks in the euro area, Japan and the United Kingdom,
which renders a conclusive analysis more difficult. Earlier studies have
delivered evidence for delays in balance sheet repair in Japan since the
1990s. See Peek and Rosengren (2003) and Caballero et al. (2008). We
discuss these studies briefly in the following. Bundesbank (2014) refers
to the Greek case. And ECB (2013b) mentions an 'unfinished balance
sheet repair' in the UK (p. 20) and an 'ongoing process of
balance sheet repair' in the euro area (p. 26).
(12) Note in this context that the more recent flattening of the
yield curve in the US and in the UK has been accompanied by a drop in
the commercial banks' net interest margin (BIS, 2012, Table VI.1).
(13) The term 'fiscal dominance' refers to a regime where
monetary policy ensures the solvency of the government. Hence, the
traditional tasks are reversed: monetary policy stabilizes real
government debt while inflation is driven by fiscal policy needs. In the
conventional view, fiscal dominance entails the famous 'unpleasant
monetarist arithmetic'. In the words of Sargent and Wallace:
'...the monetary authority ... must try to finance with seigniorage
any discrepancy between the revenue demanded by the fiscal authority and
the amounts of bonds that can be sold to the public' (Sargent and
Wallace 1981).
(14) Under a 'financial repression' regime, governments
aim at reducing the burden of their public debt by repressive measures
aimed at financial markets, steadily high inflation rates and low
nominal interest rates. In the past, such pohcies were widespread in
many countries and have also been seen as a viable option of public debt
reduction due to the high levels of debt accumulated during the European
debt crisis. Although financial repression can result in a significant
reduction of debt levels, it can have severe negative effects on private
savers and investors for whom yields become low or negative and who, due
to legal enforcement, do not have any options of evading financial
repression.
(15) See, for details, Belke (2013a,b). In general, the debate
about when to exit should not be about a precise date but about the
macroeconomic conditions which have to prevail to be able to begin a
removal of unconventional policy measures. These circumstances include
an economic recovery and picking up bank lending. However, particularly
data concerning economic activity becomes available only with a time
lag. Thus, it seems obvious that there will be a vivid discussion about
the right time to phase out the expansionary policy tools.
(16) The Fed has reduced its $85 billion-a-month bond purchase
program by the small amount of $10 billion since the start-of-year 2014,
which implies lower growth of the Fed's balance sheet.
(17) This pattern is employed by the IMF only as a
'scenario' and may not necessarily correspond with actual GDP
growth.