首页    期刊浏览 2025年05月26日 星期一
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Intra-regional equalization and growth in Russia.
  • 作者:Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge ; Timofeev, Andrey
  • 期刊名称:Comparative Economic Studies
  • 印刷版ISSN:0888-7233
  • 出版年度:2014
  • 期号:September
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Association for Comparative Economic Studies
  • 摘要:Until 2009, the Russian economy had been enjoying above 5% annual growth since it hit bottom along with oil prices in 1998. At the same time the national poverty headcount dropped from 30% in 1999 to under 14% in 2007. Partially this is explained by the favorable commodity prices enjoyed over this period as illustrated by a close relationship between Russia's economic performance and oil prices depicted in Figure 1. Indeed the two oil price dips of the 1990s coincide with the two financial crises in Russia: the Black Tuesday of 1994 and the Default of 1998. While it has become a commonplace to link Russia's economic performance to oil--and some even go far back to explain the collapse of the Soviet Union (Gaidar, 2007)--oil does not explain everything that happens in Russia. Three-fourths of Russian regions recorded positive growth in 1999 compared to three-fourths of regions showing negative growth a year before. At the same time only one-third of regions produced any oil and the oil price increased only modestly from US$12/barrel in 1998 to US$17/barrel in 1999.
  • 关键词:Economic growth;Local government

Intra-regional equalization and growth in Russia.


Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge ; Timofeev, Andrey


INTRODUCTION

Until 2009, the Russian economy had been enjoying above 5% annual growth since it hit bottom along with oil prices in 1998. At the same time the national poverty headcount dropped from 30% in 1999 to under 14% in 2007. Partially this is explained by the favorable commodity prices enjoyed over this period as illustrated by a close relationship between Russia's economic performance and oil prices depicted in Figure 1. Indeed the two oil price dips of the 1990s coincide with the two financial crises in Russia: the Black Tuesday of 1994 and the Default of 1998. While it has become a commonplace to link Russia's economic performance to oil--and some even go far back to explain the collapse of the Soviet Union (Gaidar, 2007)--oil does not explain everything that happens in Russia. Three-fourths of Russian regions recorded positive growth in 1999 compared to three-fourths of regions showing negative growth a year before. At the same time only one-third of regions produced any oil and the oil price increased only modestly from US$12/barrel in 1998 to US$17/barrel in 1999.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

There is now wide consensus among observers of the Russian economy that the long-term viability of Russia's economic growth hinges on the improvement of productivity in the non-resource-based sectors of the economy. Besides removing barriers for market competition, the most effective government contribution to the productivity growth would be through improving economic infrastructure, especially roads. According to a recent World Bank study, the impact on productivity from bringing the level of infrastructure to the OECD average would be higher than the combined impact of closing the gap in terms of financial development, quality of institutions, and education--in that order of magnitude (World Bank, 2007). It has to be noted that in Russia, sub-national governments are responsible for a considerable part of that infrastructure.

Thus, Russia's economic recovery and long-term growth prospects are more complex than can be suggested by a simple macroeconomic story, such as oil price boost. What interests us in this paper is that the dynamics of economic recovery have been very uneven across Russian regions. Therefore, the determinants of long-term growth need also be sought at the sub-national level. Among those potential determinants we are particularly interested in this paper in the potential role played by fiscal equalization among municipalities within Russian regions.

Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev (2008) find that the vast majority of Russia's regions achieve a larger reduction of within-region fiscal disparities than is the case for between-region disparities being addressed by federal grants. In this paper we are interested in understanding what may be the economic consequences of different degrees of equalization being pursued in Russia's regions.

Fiscal equalization theory predicts economic inefficiency to arise from disparities in local government revenues from source-based taxes and local rents (Albouy, 2012). Therefore, fiscal equalization has the potential to mitigate those disparities and prevent fiscally induced misallocation of mobile economic resources. However, according to the same theoretical models, disparities in residence-based taxes should be equalized only in that part arising from differences in the skill composition of local residents in terms of their income-earning abilities, but not based on their actual income, as for example determined by local income-generating opportunities. However, just like in tax policy, governments might be willing to sacrifice some economic efficiency and growth for more equity by equalizing actual revenues due to inability to observe potential income. As we explain in this paper, during the period covered by our data, most of Russia's regions were equalizing actual revenues of constituent local governments. Not surprisingly we find a negative relationship between intra-regional equalization and regional economic growth.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. First, we survey theoretical links between equalization and economic outcomes conjectured in the traditional fiscal federalism literature. Next we review those past studies that link intergovernmental relations to economic outcomes in Russia. Then we present empirical evidence on the extent of fiscal inequality and equalization between and within Russian regions. Finally, we examine the empirical relationship between the extent of intra-regional equalization and economic growth in Russian regions. In the final section we conclude.

THEORETICAL LINKS BETWEEN EQUALIZATION AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY

In the first-best theory of fiscal federalism there is no place for general-purpose intergovernmental grants and revenue sharing. Local governments are prescribed to engage only in the provision of local public goods financed with benefit taxation. When the benefits of local public goods spill over the jurisdiction border, the central government is supposed to internalize these benefits through conditional matching grants to local governments. However, in the second-best world it might not be feasible for local governments to rely exclusively on benefit taxation. (1) At the same time non-benefit taxation necessary to make up the difference would be associated with a larger deadweight loss when undertaken at the local level due to mobility of economic agents across local jurisdictions.

In practice, unconditional grants constitute a prevalent form of intergovernmental transfers in many countries. Thus England's Grants in Aid go as far back as 1830 (Webb, 1920). Moreover, the notion of 'fiscal equity' has been the prime goal for grant schemes in many countries since the beginning of the twentieth century, when the notion of a 'national minimum' level of services for all citizens entered the policy debate. This is attributed to the switch of local governments from protective to social services thus moving further away from benefit taxation (Buchanan, 1950). Federal countries with more recent constitutions often have a constitutional requirement of equalization payments to federating units. (2)

The traditional fiscal federalism literature does not provide clear-cut implications of inter-jurisdictional equalization for economic growth. Theoretically, equalization grants can be used to improve economic efficiency by reducing horizontal inequities that otherwise would lead to inefficient allocation of resources. Such efficiency case for equalization was first articulated by Buchanan (1950, p. 585), arguing that, if equals are 'pressed more in one area than in another [through higher taxation and/or lower value of public services], there will be provided an incentive for migration of both human and non-human resources into the areas of least fiscal pressures'.

Furthermore, subsequent elaboration of this argument in the literature concluded that differences in the value of public services among different jurisdictions are determined by the differences in the composition of residents in those jurisdictions in terms of income-earning abilities and availability of revenue from local rents (see Boadway, 2004 for a comprehensive review). Because the inefficient migration of labor due to fiscal disparities is caused by differences in jurisdiction characteristics (ie composition of labor force, local rents), in order to induce efficient migration patterns, it suffices to provide corrective subsidies to local governments rather than to individual local residents. Note, however, that according to these models, equalization grants should compensate a locality that has a higher proportion of low-ability labor but not for the cross-jurisdictional differences in wages of the same ability type of labor. (3)

Similar to the case of equalization of revenue capacity, compensating for disparities in demand for government services or the costs of those services does not have clear-cut efficiency implications. The issue of higher demand for government services, for example stemming from a larger number of children per household, is analogous to equalization of per capita fiscal capacity discussed above. Instead of equalizing per capita fiscal capacity, here we need to consider disparities per eligible resident (eg, per school-age child). (4) Thus efficiency would improve from preventing fiscally induced migration to localities where per child tax price of education is cheaper due to access of the local government to some rent revenue, such as natural resource royalties. While no theoretical model has been developed in the literature to examine the efficiency implications of equalization of service needs, Boadway (2004) suggests that efficiency-inducing grants should take into account the composition of residents in terms of eligibility for public services similar to the composition in terms of income-earning abilities accounted for when equalizing revenue capacity. However, compensating for differentials in unit costs of public services, for example due to economies of scale, might impede efficiency enhancing migration and thus prevent achieving the optimal scale of producing government services (eg, the optimal school size).

To our knowledge, only one theoretical study has formally modeled differences in the unit costs of a public service provision in addition to differences in the levels of its congestion. In his model, Albouy (2012) allows the unit cost of the public good provision to vary among regions due to differences in productivity. Thus per capita costs of the public service provision are equal to pG/N, where p is the marginal rate of transformation of the private good (a numeraire) into a public good. At the same time per capita benefit g from the public good output G is a function of population size N: g = G/[N.sup.a], as in the previous literature. Then the equalization grant term accounting for expenditure needs looks like (1-a) x ([p.sub.1][G.sub.1]/[N.sub.1]-[p.sub.2][G.sub.2]/[N.sub.2]). Thus, it appears that efficiency-enhancing grants should take into account differences in the local costs of producing the public good. However, the derived equalization grant takes into account per capita costs of the local public goods provided at the levels that are optimal from the social planner's perspective. As Boadway (2004) conjectures that it would be optimal to have a lower level of public service provision in a high-cost region, then assessed expenditure needs [P.sub.i][G.sub.i]/[N.sub.i] can be higher or lower in a high-cost region depending on the interplay of [p.sub.i] and [G.sub.i]. Albouy (2012) concludes that variations in the costs of private or public goods due to production efficiency or factors costs ought to be ignored in equalization formulas.

Economic performance of Russian regions

Figure 2 shows the disparities in economic growth among Russia's regions over the period 2001-2007. Over this period, the median regional growth rate fluctuated between 3.9% and 8.2%, but with wide disparities in the growth rate across regions. In any year the inter-quartile range of regional growth rates was in excess of 2 percentage points and the coefficient of variation was above 0.5.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

Overall, the dynamics of the 1999-2008 growth streak had been very uneven across Russian regions. The question is what may account for that. According to Matheson (2005), sub-national public investments in Russia are affected by fiscal equalization. The transition literature has also identified tax revenue retention as an important fiscal incentive for local governments to promote development of the private sector in their localities (see Desai et al, 2005, and Jin et al., 2005). In Russia, less equalization is achieved in regions that allow localities to retain a larger share of tax revenue at the point of collection (Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev, 2008). This is suggestive of tradeoff between equity and growth as being hypothesized in the literature (Qiao et al., 2008).

In the literature there is a discussion on the determinants and outcomes of regional-local transfers in Russia. As until recently only a few regions used explicit formulae for transfer allocation, most studies had to analyze regional policies implicitly revealed through the incidence of grants. For instance, Zhuravskaya (2000) finds that regional governments offset completely changes in localities' own revenues with changes in transfers. She also finds that claw-backing of local revenues by regional authorities is negatively related to the creation of new businesses in the region. However, Alexeev and Kurlyandskaya (2003) argue that a rational regional government that is averse to transfers would never want to completely compensate a locality for a fall in local revenues as long as local authorities' efforts affect local revenues. Using data for localities of one region, they find no evidence that regional transfers tend to completely offset changes in local revenues during the fiscal year. They do find, however, evidence of the ratchet principle in a multi-year framework, that is an increase in own revenue relative to the previous year is associated with a decrease in transfers. Equity considerations might explain such divergence of regional government policies from the efficiency rationale.

Since 2000, more studies have been examining regional growth in Russia. (5) In particular, Desai et al. (2005) link regional economic recovery and structural adjustments to differences in tax revenue retention by the regions interacted with their dependence on federal transfers and natural resources. They find that revenue retention and availability of grants and natural resources have a positive association with economic recovery; however, the presence of federal transfers and natural resources inhibit the positive effect of revenue retention.

FISCAL DISPARITY AND EQUALIZATION BETWEEN AND WITHIN RUSSIAN REGIONS

For the measures of inequality and equalization between and within Russian regions we draw on Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev (2008), who find a wide variation in local governments' per capita revenue from their own taxes and from federal and regional tax sharing sources in 2001. In this paper, we use fiscal data from the same source, which is a survey of sub-national budget reports for fiscal years 1999 and 2001. The survey was conducted by the Center for Fiscal Policy (Moscow) by requesting from individual regional governments the annual budget report for the regional government and constituent local governments. In 1999 and 2001, the number of responding regions totaled about 70 out of a total 89 regions of Russia, with about 1,900 out of total 2,500 local governments. In regions with two-tier local governments, municipal data are aggregated at the top tier.

We use two indices of inequality belonging to the class of general entropy measures: square coefficient of variation ([I.sub.2]) and mean log deviation ([I.sub.0]), also known as Theil's second measure. These measures have a number of useful properties. In particular, these indexes allow us to quantify relative contributions of between-region and within-region disparities to the nation-wide level of inequality. In addition, these two measures nicely complement each other as [I.sub.0] gives more weight to disparities in the lower tail and [I.sub.2] gives more weight to disparities in the upper tail of the distribution (Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev 2008).

Table 1 reports values of the two inequality measures for per capita fiscal resources (before and after cumulatively adding the three main categories of intergovernmental revenues to the own-source revenues) among local governments of the 70 regions of Russia (1,953 localities in total) for 1999. The different categories of revenues are discussed in Martinez-Vazquez et al. (2006), who find that the share of own-source revenue in local budgets increased from 12% in 1999 to 14% in 2001. However, in 1999 the bulk of own-source revenues was accounted for by a gross sales tax ('Housing maintenance tax') while in 2001 it was replaced by a local surtax on the federal Corporate Income Tax (CIT). The category of 'assigned sources' of revenue refers to legislated long-term entitlements to (a share of) the yield from tax instruments over which local officials have no discretion. The category of 'regulated revenue' refers to tax-revenue sharing at variable rates determined by the higher-level government as part of the annual budget process. The final category of intergovernmental grants compiles all discretionary transfers to local governments whether formula-based or completely discretionary.

Table 1 reveals that the coefficient of variation in own-source and assigned revenue stands at a rather high level of 1.55 (which is a square root of the I2 measure, equal to 2.4 as reported in column 3). This disparity is somewhat lessened after the allocation of regulated tax revenues among localities, so that the coefficient of variation decreases from 1.55 to 1.41. However, considerable equalization is achieved only after the distribution of regional-local grants, after which the coefficient of variation drops to 1.13.

The true extent of cross-jurisdictional equalization achieved with the allocation of regulated tax revenue and grants is somewhat disguised in the descriptive statistics computed over the sample pooling localities from different regions. Decomposition of the square coefficient of variation ([I.sub.2]) reveals that the between-region disparity in local fiscal outcomes is actually larger mainly due to the counter-equalizing effect of assigned revenue - than it was for the initial between-region disparity in own-source revenue (see the top panel in Table 1). For both [I.sub.0] and [I.sub.2] measures most of the reduction in total variation should be attributed to narrowing disparities within regions. This is evident from the reduced share of the within-region inequality in the total inequality compared to the respective share before equalization.

The same story holds if we adjust per capita resources of local governments for the region-wide index of cost of living (see the bottom panel of Table 1). (6) Generally, because of the differences in input prices and socioeconomic environment, local governments differ in the amount of money they must spend to achieve a given quality of public services. For example, in the Northern territories, inputs to public provision are likely to be more expensive due to high transportation costs. In addition, the harsh climate might require more inputs (eg, heating fuel) to achieve the same outcome of public provision. While accounting for inter-regional cost differences reduces total variation, it nevertheless undergoes a similar transformation at each stage of resource allocation as the inequality in nominal per capita resources.

We can consider one additional stage of resource allocation, which is constituted by direct expenditures undertaken by regional governments. Assuming, for the sake of argument, that expenditures from the regional budget uniformly benefit residents of all constituent localities, we can add a per capita amount of regional expenditures to the per capita amount of local expenditures. In particular, such imputation will account for the different extent of local governments' involvement in the provision of public services in different regions, that is, expenditure decentralization within regions.

Inclusion of regional expenditures into local fiscal outcomes considerably decreases within-region disparities as shown in the last column of Table 1. However, this equalizing effect hinges on our assumption of uniform distribution of benefits from regional expenditures. Thus, this imputation marks the range of the extent of equalization when considered alongside the estimates produced under the opposite assumption of no equalizing effect of direct regional spending. At the same time, the measures of between-region disparities increase with the inclusion of regional expenditures, regardless of the assumptions about the intra-region incidence of the direct spending of regional governments. This suggests that between-region disparity in local fiscal resources is mostly determined by the total tax yield in the region rather than the local share of that yield proportional to the scope of expenditure responsibilities devolved to the local level.

When adjusted for differences in the cost of public services and the scope of local government responsibilities, the local budget data can reveal disparities in the level of public services among Russia's localities. The next question we explore is whether these disparities result from the failure of the higher-level government to assign adequate sources of revenue to the local level or the failure of local governments to fully utilize those resources. (7) To answer this question, we transform the 1999 actual tax collections into a measure of revenue capacity by adjusting for the local level of tax effort. (8) The measure of revenue capacity captures the ability of the jurisdiction to raise revenue for public spending given the level of economic activity within its boundaries and the devolved authority to translate this economic activity into public revenues.

The constructed measure of revenue-raising capacity is estimated for a sum of taxes that are commonly retained by local governments and on average account for 75% of their pre-transfer revenue. These taxes include: personal income tax, CIT, retail sales tax, property taxes, land taxes, and a number of minor local taxes. To estimate tax yields in specific localities, figures for local government receipts from each tax were adjusted for the regionally set retention rates to derive the amount of total collections for each tax in the locality. Information on tax revenue retention rates derives from regional budget laws for the year 1999.

Out of several potential proxies for local taxable bases, the best explanatory power was shown by the combination of manufacturing output and average wages, jointly explaining over 60% of variation in local government own-source revenue in 1999. We use the obtained estimates to impute revenue capacity of local governments in 1999. Because municipal-level statistical data are not available for some regions, the adjustments for tax effort can be only performed for a somewhat smaller sample comprised of 1,602 localities in 59 regions. In this smaller sample, the inequality in nominal and price-adjusted per capita resources (top and middle panels of Table 2) undergoes a similar transformation at each stage of resource allocation to the inequality measures computed for the larger sample (Table 1).

Adjusting for the local tax effort produced slightly larger measures of inequality but still following the same pattern at each stage of resource allocation (see the bottom panel of Table 2). Overall, if we account for differences in costs and tax capacity, the impact of equalization on the between-region variation appears somewhat stronger. However, the degree of between-region equalization is still short of what we observe for within-region equalization as manifested in a smaller share of the total inequality of fiscal outcomes accounted for by the within-region inequality when compared to the respective share before equalization.

Finally, we note a dramatic increase in fiscal inequality that occurred between 1999 and 2001, as is evident from Table 3. This is due to the reshuffling of tax assignments between the levels of government. In particular to compensate municipalities for the loss of revenue from the Housing Maintenance Tax (up to 1.5% of enterprise gross sales, accounting for 14% of local pre-transfer revenues in 1999), in 2001 local governments were allowed to 'piggy-back' on the federal CIT by introducing a local surtax of up to a maximum of 5%. To create fiscal space for the local CIT surtax, the ceiling on the regional CIT surtax was lowered and the requirement for regions to share CIT revenue with municipalities was lifted.

As the gross sales tax had had a more evenly distributed tax base than the CIT, concentrated in the (mainly urban) places of incorporation, the within-region variation accounts for a larger share of the total inequality in 2001 than in 1999.

FISCAL EQUALIZATION AND GROWTH

We now set out to examine how these cross-regional differences in the extent of inequality and equalization translate into differences in economic performance. Following Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev (2008), we measure the extent of equalization by regional governments as the ratio of the inequality indexes (either [I.sub.2] or [I.sub.0]) before and after equalization. Moreover, the extent of equalization is measured separately first, in the narrow definition and second, in the broader definition inclusive of direct regional spending. Because the scope of own sources in local revenues changed between 1999 and 2001, resulting in incomparable values for the inequality and equalization measures, in our growth regressions we perform separate estimation on data for 1999 and 2001. (9) Furthermore, for 1999 we also attempt to perform estimation for the equalization measure computed on figures adjusted for local tax effort in addition to the estimation with the equalization measure computed on nominal figures. However, the equalization measure computed on figures adjusted for local tax effort turns out to be insignificant in explaining regional growth and therefore we do not report the results of those estimations.

Because the fiscal equity theory hinges on the mobility of individuals across local jurisdictions, in an alternative specification we allow for an interaction between fiscal equalization and migration. (10) For each region, migration is measured as the fraction of regional population who moved in, out, or within the region in a given year.

As control variables we have considered regressors commonly used in growth equations (eg Qiao et al., 2008; Desai et al., 2005): population growth, capital accumulation, education attainment, foreign trade, ethno-linguistic fractionalization, urbanization, etc. In addition, we tried other control variables identified in previous studies of regional economic performance in Russia. The real per capita economic product is included to control for regional income convergence. Regional tax effort is included to isolate the equalization effect from tax policy effects. Following Desai et al. (2005), we also include tax revenue retention by localities, dependence on federal transfers and revenues from natural resources, and the interaction among those variables. Finally, following Brown et al. (2009), we include the number of civil servants per capita to control for the interference by state actors, or alternatively institutional support for private economic activity. To address possible endogeneity, all regressors are lagged by 1 year relative to the beginning of the period over which economic growth is computed as the dependent variable.

Locality-level information on non-fiscal indicators derives from a survey of regional statistical offices conducted by the federal statistical office in 1999. Region-level non-fiscal data derive from the 2007 Russian Statistical Yearbook. Information on the region-wide tax effort is taken from the 2001 calculations of federal grants. Descriptive statistics for our explanatory variables are reported in Appendix A.

RESULTS

Table 4 reports the estimation results for the 2000-2004 average growth rate of the Gross Regional Product (GRP) as the dependent variable and the 1999 inequality and equalization measures as the main explanatory variables.

The top panel of Table 4 reports regressions using [I.sub.0] indices while in bottom panel the regressions utilize [I.sub.2] indices. Many of the control variables turned out to be of little statistical significance and thus were omitted from the final regressions without substantial impact on the fit of the model or the estimates of the impact of remaining variables. According to our estimates, inequality in own-source revenue in 1999 is associated with higher average growth rate in the next 5 years. At the same time equalization through shared taxes and grants in 1999 is associated with lower average growth rate in the next 5 years. The effect of equalization through centralization of resources to the regional budget is not statistically significant.

Table 5 reports the estimation results for the 2002-2006 average growth rate of GRP as the dependent variable and the 2001 inequality and equalization measures as the main explanatory variables, which are computed using [I.sub.0] and [I.sub.2] indices, respectively. The 2001 inequality in own-source revenue is associated with lower average growth rate in the next 5 years. Equalization through shared taxes and grants seems to retard growth while equalization through the centralization of resources to the regional budget is associated with higher average growth rate in the next 5 years.

There are many similarities in results from the two periods of time. Thus, in both time periods our regressions have higher explanatory power when using the [I.sub.0] measures of inequality, which are more sensitive to the disparities in the lower tail. Thus, fiscal incentives faced by poorer localities seem to matter more for regional growth than the treatment of the rich localities. In both time periods, equalization through shared taxes and grants is associated with lower average growth rates. In both time periods, the negative impact of equalization on growth is amplified by higher mobility of population. In fact, according to the 1999 regression, equalization in the upper tail ([I.sub.2]) does not impede growth if the extent of mobility is below the average by more than half a standard deviation.

Despite the aforementioned similarities, the results from the two time periods differ on several accounts. First, subsequent economic growth is positively related to the initial level of inequality in the 1999 own-source revenue dominated by the gross sales tax--while it is negatively related to inequality in the 2001 own-source revenue--dominated by the local surtax on corporate income. Besides pointing out that these are very different revenue sources having different spatial incidence, one can speculate about the fact the CIT surtax is more of a source-based tax on local rents than the gross sales tax is. The CIT tax is collected at the location of corporate headquarters not where the sales (business activities) take place. According to the fiscal equalization theory, disparities in local government revenues from source-based taxes and local rents can cause fiscally induced misallocation of mobile economic resources (Albouy, 2012).

Another difference between the two time periods is that most regressors have higher statistical significance in the 2001 regression than in the 1999 regression. In particular, the positive impact of equalization through the centralization of resources to the regional budget is highly statistically significant in 2001.

The impact of statistically significant control variables suggested in other studies have the expected signs in our analysis: tax burden (negative), dependence on federal transfers (negative), oil extraction (negative), interaction of tax revenue retention with availability of oil and federal grants (opposite to the sign at the uninteracted term).

DISCUSSION

We have found that regional intergovernmental policies dramatically reduce within-region inequality in fiscal outcomes compared to the inequality in own-source revenue. Thus, in a median region the squared coefficient of variation drops by a factor of five after the distribution of regional-local grants and, to a lesser extent, after the allocation of regulated tax revenues among localities. For comparison, in the United States state-local grants reduce between-county inequality only by a factor of 2 (Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev, 2010). As a result the inequality in local expenditures in a median Russian region is only two times higher than the inequality in a median US state while for own-source revenue the inequality in a median Russian region is four times higher than in a median US state.

Overall, our results suggest that intra-regional fiscal equalization have a substantial impact on regional growth in Russia. For example, in 1999, a one standard deviation increase in the measure of regional equalization through shared tax revenues and grants translated into a decrease of subsequent regional growth rate in the magnitude of 0.18 of its standard deviation (0.37 for the [I.sub.2] measure). In 2001, one standard deviation increase in regional equalization through shared tax revenues and grants translated into 0.45 of a standard deviation decline in regional growth rate. Finally, one standard deviation increase in equalization through centralization of resources to the regional budget translated into more than one standard deviation increase in regional growth rate (0.8 for the [I.sub.2] measure).

Notwithstanding the dramatic equalization undertaken by Russian regions, the nation-wide inequality (between--and within-state combined) in fiscal outcomes is still rather high. For international comparison, the squared coefficient of variation for per capita local expenditures in Russia is three times higher than in China (Tsui, 2005) and 10 times higher than in the United States (Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev, 2010). Such relatively high inequality in local fiscal outcomes is mainly due to unmitigated between-region disparities, accounting for 55% of expenditure inequality in Russia. This is comparable to just over half of total inequality accounted for between-state inequality in the United States and 61% of expenditure inequality accounted for by the between-province disparities in China. However, in the initial inequality in own-source revenues, between-state disparities account for less than 40% in Russia compared to 59% in China and 32% in the United States.

The most direct policy implication of our study is that policymakers may face a tradeoff; choices about higher equalization levels can translate in lower rates of economic growth as a result.

CONCLUSION

The purpose of this study has been to explore how cross-regional differences in the extent of fiscal equalization within Russian regions translate into differences in their economic performance. Overall, our results suggest that intra-regional fiscal equalization in Russia has a substantial impact on regional growth. Furthermore, in our regressions, equalization in the lower tail of the distribution has a higher statistical and economic significance, suggesting higher importance of fiscal incentives for less affluent localities in a region.

APPENDIX A

Descriptive statistics

Tables A1 and A2 report descriptive statistics for the explanatory variables for our 2000-2004 and 2002-2006 regressions, respectively.
Table A1: Summary statistics for the 2000-2004 regresssors

                                  Mean     Std. Dev.

Inequality in own-source         0.083       0.040
  revenue ([I.sub.0])
Equalization ([I.sub.0])         7.020       5.750
Equalization through             20.013     22.011
  centralization ([I.sub.0])
Inequality in own-source         0.435       0.460
  revenue ([I.sub.2])
Equalization ([I.sub.2])         6.921       6.271
Equalization through             19.335     20.221
  centralization ([I.sub.2])
Migration                        0.037       0.034
Tax effort                       1.097       0.537
Local retention of tax           0.576       0.125
  revenue
Dependence on federal grants     0.209       0.183
Oil extraction                   3.553      17.557
GRP per capita                   20.253      7.308
Federal bureaucracy              3.055       1.080
Regional bureaucracy             1.319       0.944
Local bureaucracy                3.659       1.096
Judicial bureaucracy             0.892       0.274
Population growth                -5.843      4.761
Capital growth                   0.038       0.024

                                  Min         Max

Inequality in own-source         0.015       0.262
  revenue ([I.sub.0])
Equalization ([I.sub.0])         1.095      32.222
Equalization through             1.716      134.410
  centralization ([I.sub.0])
Inequality in own-source         0.049       3.686
  revenue ([I.sub.2])
Equalization ([I.sub.2])         0.521      36.933
Equalization through             0.857      112.291
  centralization ([I.sub.2])
Migration                        0.009       0.271
Tax effort                       0.543       5.256
Local retention of tax           0.211       0.851
  revenue
Dependence on federal grants     0.000       0.820
Oil extraction                   0.000      132.035
GRP per capita                   0.000      41.249
Federal bureaucracy              1.545       8.705
Regional bureaucracy             0.203       4.523
Local bureaucracy                1.201       7.079
Judicial bureaucracy             0.240       1.976
Population growth               -14.600      9.200
Capital growth                   0.014       0.167

Table A2: Summary statistics for the 2002-06 regresssors

                                                   Mean     Std. Dev.

Inequality in own-source revenue ([I.sub.0])       0.156        0.189
Equalization ([I.sub.0])                           7.445        5.957
Equalization through centralization ([I.sub.0])   29.418       48.527
Inequality in own-source revenue ([I.sub.2])       1.418        3.949
Equalization ([I.sub.2])                           6.691        5.520
Equalization through centralization ([I.sub.2])   25.539       37.328
Migration                                          0.035        0.032
Tax effort                                         1.005        0.341
Local retention of tax revenue                     0.550        0.109
Dependence on federal grants                       0.329        0.226
Oil extraction                                     3.794       18.253
GRP per capita                                    46.183       43.865
Federal bureaucracy                                3.366        2.291
Regional bureaucracy                               1.664        2.336
Local bureaucracy                                  3.920        2.435
Judicial bureaucracy                               0.974        0.496
Population growth                                 -5.582        5.422
Capital growth                                     0.068        0.043

                                                   Min        Max

Inequality in own-source revenue ([I.sub.0])       0.016      0.929
Equalization ([I.sub.0])                           0.157     23.709
Equalization through centralization ([I.sub.0])    0.291    383.175
Inequality in own-source revenue ([I.sub.2])       0.049     25.254
Equalization ([I.sub.2])                           0.471     23.826
Equalization through centralization ([I.sub.2])    1.145    263.940
Migration                                          0.009      0.201
Tax effort                                         0.545      2.645
Local retention of tax revenue                     0.232      0.831
Dependence on federal grants                       0.007      0.905
Oil extraction                                     0.000    138.535
GRP per capita                                    11.049    303.661
Federal bureaucracy                                1.576     19.333
Regional bureaucracy                               0.207     14.889
Local bureaucracy                                  0.124     20.778
Judicial bureaucracy                               0.244      3.690
Population growth                                -14.900     15.200
Capital growth                                     0.015      0.294


REFERENCES

Albouy, D. 2012: Evaluating the efficiency and equity of federal fiscal equalization. Journal of Public Economics 96(9-10): 824-839.

Alexeev, M and Kurlyandskaya, G. 2003: Fiscal federalism and incentives in a Russian region. Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (1): 20.

Berkowitz, D and DeJong, DN. 2003: Policy reform and growth in post-soviet Russia. European Economic Review 47(2): 337-352.

Berkowitz, D and DeJong, DN. 2005: Entrepreneurship and post-socialist growth. Oxford Bulletin of Economics & Statistics 67(1): 25-46.

Berkowitz, D and DeJong, DN. 2011: Growth in post-soviet Russia: A tale of two transitions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 79(1-2): 133-143.

Boadway, R. 2004: The theory and practice of equalization. CESifo Economic Studies 50(1): 211.

Brown, JD, Earle, JS and Gehlbach, S. 2009: Helping hand or grabbing hand? State bureaucracy and privatization effectiveness. American Political Science Review 103(02): 264-283.

Buchanan, JM. 1950: Federalism and fiscal equity. The American Economic Review 40(4): 583-99.

Desai, RM, Freinkman, L and Goldberg, I. 2005: Fiscal federalism in rentier regions: Evidence from Russia. Journal of Comparative Economics 33(4): 814.

Energy Information Administration. 2009: World crude oil prices, http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/dnav/pet/ pet_pri_wco_k_w.htm, accessed 16 October 2009.

Fisher, RC and Papke, LE. 2000: Local government responses to education grants. National Tax Journal 53(1): 153.

Gaidar, Y. 2007: Collapse of an empire: Lessons for modern Russia, translated by Bouis, AW Brookings Institution Press: Washington DC.

Golubchikov, O. 2007: Re-scaling the debate on Russian economic growth: Regional restructuring and development asynchronies. Europe-Asia Studies 59(2): 191-215.

Goskomstat. 2008: Russian statistical yearbook. Goskomstat: Moscow.

Jin, H, Qian, Y and Weingast, BR. 2005: Regional decentralization and fiscal incentives: Federalism, Chinese style. Journal of Public Economics 89(9-10): 1719.

Martinez-Vazquez, J and Timofeev, A. 2008: Regional-local dimension of Russia's fiscal equalization. Journal of Comparative Economics 36(1): 157.

Martinez-Vazquez, J and Timofeev, A. 2010: 'The long and winding road to local fiscal equity in the United States: A fifty year retrospective'. International Studies Program Working Paper Series, at AYSPS, GSU paperl027, International Studies Program, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University.

Martinez-Vazquez, J, Timofeev, A and Boex, J. 2006: Reforming regional-local finance in Russia. WBI Learning Resources Series. World Bank: Washington DC.

Matheson, T. 2005: Does fiscal redistribution discourage local public investment? Evidence from transitional Russia. Economics of Transition 13(1): 139.

Qiao, B, Martinez-Vazquez, J and Xu, Y. 2008: The tradeoff between growth and equity in decentralization policy: China's experience. Journal of Development Economics 86(1): 112.

Tresch, RW. 2002: Public finance: A normative theory. Elsevier Science, Academic Press: San Diego, CA and London.

Tsui, K. 2005: Local tax system, intergovernmental transfers China's local fiscal disparities. Journal of Comparative Economics 33(1): 173.

Webb, S. 1920: Grants in aid: A criticism and a proposal. Longmans, Green and co: London, New York.

World Bank. 2007: Russian Economic Report #15. November 2007. The World Bank Group.

Zhuravskaya, EV. 2000: Incentives to provide local public goods: Fiscal federalism, Russian style. Journal of Public Economics 76(3): 337-368.

JORGE MARTINEZ-VAZQUEZ & ANDREY TIMOFEEV

International Center for Public Policy, Georgia State University, PO Box 3992, Atlanta, 30302-3992, USA.

E-mail: atimofeev@gsu.edu

(1) There are many practical constraints to the implementation of benefit taxation. Theoretically, with decreasing costs, benefit taxation would not be sufficient to cover total costs with marginal costs being below average costs (Tresch, 2002, p. 844).

(2) For example, Section 36 of Canada's Constitution Act of 1982. Other examples include Germany, Spain, and South Africa.

(3) Cross-jurisdictional differences in wages for the same type of labor can arise due to differences in the costs of local public goods as a result of congestion (Boadway, 2004). Given these differences in the level of local public goods, the same type of labor will have different wages in different regions. Because of the concavity of the utility function, different types of labor will require different amounts of wage adjustment to compensate for the same difference in the local-level public good provision. In the special case of a pure public good and constant migration costs, the productivity of labor (wages) and the optimal level of service provision will be the same in both regions.

(4) Indeed, in the USA court-mandated schemes of state-wide equalization of education finances are often set up in terms of taxable property value per student (Fisher and Papke, 2000).

(5) These include Berkowitz and DeJong (2003); Berkowitz and DeJong (2005); Golubchikov (2007), and Berkowitz and DeJong (2011) to name just a few.

(6) Unfortunately, for the time period in our sample, there are no municipal-level data that would allow us to make adjustments for differences in relative prices across localities. Adjustments using the region-level price index will not affect our measures of within-region equalization, which is the main focus of this study. However, regional-level adjustments help strengthen our finding of weak between-region equalization reveled by between-region inequality measures.

(7) We are indebted to Vladimir Popov for this point.

(8) We do not have municipal-level non-fiscal data to estimate tax effort and revenue capacity for 2001.

(9) As we have explained, these data derive from a one-off survey of sub-national budget reports for fiscal years 1999 and 2001 and therefore are not available for other years. While this constraints our analysis to cross-sectional estimations, it provides unique insights into intergovernmental relations within Russian regions.

(10) We are indebted to an anonymous referee for pointing out the importance of controlling for interaction with factor mobility.
Table 1: Disparities in per capita revenue of local governments within
and between regions, 1999

                                      Own       Plus        Plus
                                    source    assigned    regulated

Nominal fiscal resources

Square coefficient of variation      1.238      2.395       1.99
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                     0.640      1.162       0.722
  Between regions                    0.597      1.233       1.268
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])       0.154      0.163       0.155
  Within regions                     0.083      0.076       0.067
  Between regions                    0.070      0.086       0.087

Fiscal resources adjusted for the price level
Square coefficient of variation
([I.sub.2])                          0.833      1.286       1.147
  Within regions                     0.528      0.735       0.558
  Between regions                    0.305      0.551       0.588
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])       0.134      0.136       0.127
  Within regions                     0.083      0.076       0.067
  Between regions                    0.050      0.059       0.060

                                     Plus     Plus regional
                                    grants     expenditures

Nominal fiscal resources

Square coefficient of variation      1.276        1.201
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                     0.310        0.121
  Between regions                    0.966        1.080
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])       0.084        0.117
  Within regions                     0.016        0.007
  Between regions                    0.067        0.110

Fiscal resources adjusted for the price level
Square coefficient of variation
([I.sub.2])                          0.655        0.599
  Within regions                     0.232        0.089
  Between regions                    0.423        0.510
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])       0.059        0.061
  Within regions                     0.016        0.007
  Between regions                    0.042        0.053

Note: The sample includes 1,953 localities in 70 regions (covering
population of 108,399) for which fiscal data are available.

Source: Authors' calculation based on data from the Center for Fiscal
Policy, Moscow

Table 2: Disparities in per capita revenue of local governments within
and between regions, 1999

                                       Own       Plus       Plus
                                     source    assigned   regulated

Nominal fiscal resources
Square coefficient of variation       1.343     2.282       2.273
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                      0.625     0.998       0.813
  Between regions                     0.718     1.284       1.459
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])        0.156     0.163       0.162
  Within regions                      0.079     0.075       0.068
  Between regions                     0.076     0.088       0.094

Fiscal resources adjusted for the price level
Square coefficient of variation       0.845     1.286       1.317
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                      0.484     0.684       0.632
  Between regions                     0.361     0.601       0.684
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])        0.132     0.134       0.129
  Within regions                      0.079     0.075       0.068
  Between regions                     0.052     0.059       0.061

Fiscal resources adjusted for the local tax effort and price level
Square coefficient of variation       0.971     1.213       1.071
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                      0.599     0.707       0.540
  Between regions                     0.372     0.505       0.531
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])        0.170     0.170       0.159
  Within regions                      0.110     0.107       0.100
  Between regions                     0.059     0.063       0.058

                                       Plus     Plus regional
                                      grants    expenditures

Nominal fiscal resources
Square coefficient of variation       1.449         1.344
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                      0.349         0.140
  Between regions                     1.099         1.204
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])        0.091         0.100
  Within regions                      0.016         0.007
  Between regions                     0.074         0.092

Fiscal resources adjusted for the price level
Square coefficient of variation       0.746         0.647
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                      0.261         0.102
  Between regions                     0.485         0.545
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])        0.061         0.059
  Within regions                      0.016         0.007
  Between regions                     0.045         0.052

Fiscal resources adjusted for the local tax effort and price level
Square coefficient of variation       0.660         0.589
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                      0.258         0.108
  Between regions                     0.402         0.481
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])        0.070         0.063
  Within regions                      0.027         0.013
  Between regions                     0.043         0.050

Note: The sample includes 1,602 localities in 59 regions for which
statistical data are available to estimate the tax effort.

Source: Authors' calculation based on data from the Center for Fiscal
Policy, Moscow

Table 3: Disparities in per capita revenue of local governments within
and between regions, 1999 and 2001

                                      Own        Plus         Plus
                                    source     assigned    regulated

Nominal fiscal resources in 1999
Square coefficient of variation      1.148      2.373        1.886
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                     0.575      1.075        0.624
  Between regions                    0.572      1.297        1.261
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])       0.152      0.161        0.151
  Within regions                     0.082      0.076        0.066
  Between regions                    0.069      0.084        0.084

Nominal fiscal resources in 2001
Square coefficient of variation      3.209      4.082        3.068
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                     1.936      2.129        1.474
  Between regions                    1.272      1.953        1.594
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])       0.261      0.257        0.218
  Within regions                     0.160      0.143        0.120
  Between regions                    0.100      0.113        0.097

                                     Plus     Plus regional
                                    grants    expenditures

Nominal fiscal resources in 1999
Square coefficient of variation      1.154        0.976
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                     0.311        0.120
  Between regions                    0.842        0.856
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])       0.077        0.130
  Within regions                     0.016        0.007
  Between regions                    0.061        0.123

Nominal fiscal resources in 2001
Square coefficient of variation      1.894        1.691
([I.sub.2])
  Within regions                     0.858        0.477
  Between regions                    1.036        1.214
Mean log deviation ([I.sub.0])       0.124        0.103
  Within regions                     0.057        0.031
  Between regions                    0.067        0.072

Note: The 2001 sample includes 1,688 localities in 62 regions
(covering population of 95.5 million) for which fiscal data are
available. The 1999 sample includes 1,693 localities in 62 regions
(covering population of 95.1 million) for which fiscal data are
available.

Source: Authors' calculation based on data from the Center for Fiscal
Policy, Moscow

Table 4: OLS regression of 2000-2004 regional growth

LHS: Average growth rate 2000-04           (1)           (2)

[I.sub.0] measure

Inequality in own-source revenue       36.701 ***    43.533 ***
                                         (8.457)       (8.468)
Equalization                            -0.205 *       -0.228
                                         (0.110)       (0.303)
Equalization through centralization       0.018         0.025
                                         (0.034)       (0.039)
Migration                                  --          -30.988
                                                      (65.174)
Migration x Equalization                   --          -1.083
                                                       (9.137)
[R.sup.2]                                 0.63          0.67
# of regions                               64            64

[T.sub.2] measure

Inequality in own-source revenue          0.745       4.590 ***
                                         (0.997)       (1.098)
Equalization                             -0.153        0.269 *
                                         (0.110)       (0.149)
Equalization through centralization       0.013         0.019
                                         (0.041)       (0.040)
Migration                                  --         55.065 **
                                                      (24.639)
Migration x Equalization                   --        -17.697 ***
                                                       (4.424)
[R.sup.2]                                 0.56          0.65
# of regions                               64            64

Note: Robust standard errors are provided in parentheses: *
statistically significant at 10%; ** statistically significant at 5%;
*** statistically significant at 1%. Federal district dummies included
in all specifications. In addition to the shown variables of interest,
the regressions also include control variables: Tax effort; Local
retention of tax revenue; Dependence on federal grants; Oil
extraction; Oil extraction x Tax retention; Grants x Tax retention;
GRP per capita; Local bureaucracy; Judicial bureaucracy; Other
bureaucracy; Population growth; Capital growth.

Table 5: OLS regression of 2002-2006 regional growth

LHS: Average growth rate 2002-06            (1)            (2)

[I.sub.0] measure
Inequality in own-source revenue         -3.427 ***     -3.362 **
                                          (1.285)        (1.305)
Equalization                             -0.239 ***       -0.190
                                          (0.076)        (0.133)
Equalization through centralization      0.079 ***      0.077 ***
                                          (0.026)        (0.027)
Migration                                    --           1.788
                                                         -19.824
Migration x Equalization                     --           -1.422
                                                          -3.645
[R.sup.2]                                   0.64           0.65
# of regions                                 69             69

[I.sub.2] measure
Inequality in own-source revenue         -0.104 **      -0.100 **
                                          (0.042)        (0.040)
Equalization                             -0.243 ***       -0.085
                                          (0.082)        (0.152)
Equalization through centralization       0.070 **       0.064 **
                                          (0.030)        (0.031)
Migration                                    --           6.848
                                                         (12.597)
Migration x Equalization                     --           -4.446
                                                         (3.226)
[R.sup.2]                                   0.62           0.64
# of regions                                 69             69

Note: Robust standard errors are provided in parentheses: **
statistically significant at 5%; *** statistically significant at 1%.
Federal district dummies included in all specifications.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有