首页    期刊浏览 2025年06月17日 星期二
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Decomposition of ethnic heterogeneity on growth.
  • 作者:Yamamura, Eiji ; Shin, Inyong
  • 期刊名称:Comparative Economic Studies
  • 印刷版ISSN:0888-7233
  • 出版年度:2013
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Association for Comparative Economic Studies
  • 摘要:Since the 1990s, there has been growing interest among economic researchers in the relationship between ethnic diversity and economic performance (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2005). Easterly and Levine (1997) showed a negative association between ethnic heterogeneity and economic growth. (1) Ethnic heterogeneity is thought to influence economic growth through several channels. First, ethnic heterogeneity has been found to reduce investment (Mauro, 1995; Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2005a, b), thus reducing public and private capital formation and economic growth. (2) Second, ethnic heterogeneity has been shown to be positively associated with the probability of conflict (Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2005a, b) and it is negatively related to trust (Dincer, 2011). (3) Trust plays a key role in reducing transaction costs in the market (Zak and Knack, 2001). Thus, we predict that ethnic heterogeneity impedes not only market transactions but also information spillovers including learning from others. This inevitably hinders economic growth. However, the effect of ethnic heterogeneity on growth is open for discussion because heterogeneity also appears to have a contrasting effect: social diversity, which seems to be captured partly by ethnic heterogeneity, is thought to promote innovation (Jacobs, 1969, 1984). If this is true, then heterogeneity may enhance economic growth. In the analysis used in this paper, technological progress, regarded as a proxy for innovation, is exogenously determined. Hence, this paper does not examine the influence of ethnic heterogeneity on growth through enhanced innovation.
  • 关键词:Economic efficiency;Economic growth;Ethnicity;Industrial efficiency;Information management

Decomposition of ethnic heterogeneity on growth.


Yamamura, Eiji ; Shin, Inyong


INTRODUCTION

Since the 1990s, there has been growing interest among economic researchers in the relationship between ethnic diversity and economic performance (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2005). Easterly and Levine (1997) showed a negative association between ethnic heterogeneity and economic growth. (1) Ethnic heterogeneity is thought to influence economic growth through several channels. First, ethnic heterogeneity has been found to reduce investment (Mauro, 1995; Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2005a, b), thus reducing public and private capital formation and economic growth. (2) Second, ethnic heterogeneity has been shown to be positively associated with the probability of conflict (Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2005a, b) and it is negatively related to trust (Dincer, 2011). (3) Trust plays a key role in reducing transaction costs in the market (Zak and Knack, 2001). Thus, we predict that ethnic heterogeneity impedes not only market transactions but also information spillovers including learning from others. This inevitably hinders economic growth. However, the effect of ethnic heterogeneity on growth is open for discussion because heterogeneity also appears to have a contrasting effect: social diversity, which seems to be captured partly by ethnic heterogeneity, is thought to promote innovation (Jacobs, 1969, 1984). If this is true, then heterogeneity may enhance economic growth. In the analysis used in this paper, technological progress, regarded as a proxy for innovation, is exogenously determined. Hence, this paper does not examine the influence of ethnic heterogeneity on growth through enhanced innovation.

Data envelopment analysis, hereafter DEA, enables us to analyze how ethnic diversity influences economic growth. We use DEA analysis to construct a world production frontier, and then decompose labor productivity growth into three components: technological catch-up, capital deepening, and technological change (Kumar and Russell, 2002). (4) Alternatively, we have used regression analysis to examine how initial outputs per worker influence these components (Yamamura and Shin, 2007a, b, 2008; Yamamura, 2011).

This paper aims to examine the influence of heterogeneity on growth and therefore provide new empirical evidence by analyzing the channels through which ethnic heterogeneity affects growth. The key finding is that heterogeneity has a negative effect on efficiency improvements, which impedes growth. The rest of this paper is organized as follows: two testable hypotheses are proposed in the next section; the subsequent section describes the data and estimation strategy; the penultimate section presents the estimation results; and the final section concludes.

HYPOTHESES

The engine of economic growth seems to stem from information spillovers (Marshall, 1920). Positive externalities brought about by information spillovers among various firms and groups are expected to arise if face-to-face interaction among workers occurs. (5) Information spillovers are thought to enhance efficiency improvement, resulting in economic growth. However, most workers, including experts, are less likely to interact if the workforce is ethnically polarized. This is consistent with the argument that information flows are weaker in a heterogeneous population, which prevents individuals from learning about their neighbors' experiences (Munshi, 2004). If this holds true, heterogeneity has a detrimental influence on information spillovers. Furthermore, there appears to be an additional mechanism. It is argued that trust contributes to economic growth (eg, Beugelsdijk et al., 2004; Beugelsdijk and van Schaik, 2005; Zak and Knack, 2001). This is in part because trust reduces the transaction costs among agents. However, Dincer (2011) finds that ethnic heterogeneity is negatively associated with the level of trust. If this is true, then heterogeneity reduces trust, and therefore increases transaction costs. Inevitably, the market functions less well, which in turn reduces positive externalities such as information spillovers. Accordingly, economic growth is hindered. This argument leads us to postulate Hypothesis 1. (6)

Hypothesis 1: Racial heterogeneity impedes efficiency improvements, which hampers economic growth.

Ethnic heterogeneity increases the number of interest groups because the interests of each ethnic group may be different from, and in conflict with, those of other groups. A rent-seeking model shows that resources spent by each group to obtain political power can be considered a social cost (Mueller, 2005). In this model, resources are allocated to nonproductive behavior and not into productive investments. It is also possible that ethnic heterogeneity increases the likelihood of political conflict, creating an unstable and uncertain political situation in a country. As a consequence, investment is reduced due to this greater uncertainty (Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2005a, b). (7) Considering the arguments above, we propose Hypothesis 2.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Hypothesis 2: Racial heterogeneity impedes capital accumulation, which hampers economic growth.

DATA AND ESTIMATION STRATEGY

Kumar and Russell (2002) used DEA to construct a cross-country data set by decomposing labor productivity growth into three components. They then estimated a simple OLS regression model. In that model, the dependent variables were the percentage changes between 1965 and 1990 for output per worker, technological change, the efficiency index, and the capital accumulation index. Output per worker in 1965 was an independent variable. In their estimations, both unobservable individual and time effects were ignored. However, as suggested by Yamamura and Shin (2007a), this can lead to estimation bias.

Following Kumar and Russell (2002), this paper also uses DEA to construct a panel data set for 57 countries, from 1965 to 1990, using the Penn World Tables. (8) In Figures 1 and 2 the vertical and horizontal axes indicate output per worker and capital stock per worker, respectively. Figure 1 illustrates the frontier line and location of each country in 1960, whereas Figure 2 illustrates the frontier line and location of each country in 1990. In the Appendix, Table A1 shows the codes for the countries used in each figure, matched with the name of country. Compared with 1960, the frontier line for 1990 in Figure 2 has shifted upward, suggesting significant improvement in technology. Furthermore, in 1990 there are greater differences in output and capital stock among countries.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

To assess the effects of ethnic heterogeneity on growth, we constructed panel data for the countries included in our DEA analysis. With this data set, we used random-effects estimations to reduce omitted variable bias caused by the time-invariant features of the various countries. (9) We also incorporated year dummies into this model to capture individually invariant time-specific effects. The estimated function takes the following form:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)

where [Gr.sub.jT-t0] represents labor productivity growth and the change in any of the two dependent variables (ie, Efficiency and Capital) in country j from each base year t0 to next year T (t0 = 1965, ..., 1989 and T = 1966, ..., 1990). Technological progress, as measured by the outward shift in the frontier, is determined exogenously by a world production frontier. Hence, the characteristics of each country do not influence technological progress. To put it differently, technological progress is exogenously determined for all countries and thus cannot be used as a dependent variable. The estimation model basically follows the model of Kumar and Russell (2002) and therefore Ln(Output), the log of GDP per capita, is included to capture the level of economic development. (10) The dependent variables and Ln(Output) are from the Penn World Tables (PWT 5.6). (11) In equation 1, [alpha] represents the regression parameters, [epsilon] is the time-invariant individual effect for each country, v represents the year-specific effects, and u is an error term. As stated earlier, [epsilon] and v are controlled. The key independent variable that captures ethnic heterogeneity is the ethnic polarization index, which has been extensively used to capture ethnic heterogeneity (Mauro, 1995; Easterly and Levine, 1997). The index for some country j is defined as:

Fractionalization = 1 - [n.summation over (i=1)] [[pi].sup.2.sub.i]

where [[pi].sub.i] is the proportion of the population who profess to belong to a given ethnic group i. Basically, this indicator can be interpreted as measuring the probability that two randomly selected individuals in a country will belong to different groups.

In addition to the ethnic fractionalization index, an ethnic polarization index has been developed and used as an alternative measure (Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2005a, b; Reynal-Querol, 2002). The ethnic polarization index can be defined as:

Polarization = 1 - [n.summation over (i=1)] [(0.5 - [[pi].sub.i]/0.5).sup.2] [[pi].sub.i]

This index measures the normalized distance of a particular distribution of ethnic groups within a bimodal distribution. Here, ethnic group is represented as i for country j. The index can be calculated for each country.

To check the robustness of the estimation results, we used both ethnic fractionalization and ethnic polarization as proxy variables for ethnic heterogeneity. (12) Ethnic heterogeneity is expected to result in conflict, hampering the cooperation and communication required to enhance technology diffusion, and therefore efficiency improvements. Proxies for ethnic heterogeneity hold time-invariant features. Hence, their effects cannot be estimated when a fixed-effects model is used. To examine these effects, a random-effects model is used in this paper. If the coefficients of the proxies take the negative sign when efficiency improvement or capital accumulation is a dependent variable, then Hypothesis 1 or 2, as is applicable, is supported.

The other independent variables used in this model include the values of the dependent variable in the base year, t0. Natural disasters are considered to influence economic growth (Skidmore and Toya, 2002). To capture this effect, the number of natural disasters that have occurred in each sample country is included. (13) We investigate how a natural disaster occurring in year t0 affects growth rates between t0 and t1. For instance, we examine the effect of the number of natural disasters in 1965 on growth rates from 1965 to 1966. (14) As suggested by Yamamura (2011), government size hinders capital accumulation and thus hampers economic growth. Hence, government size is included as an independent variable. Government size is measured by a country's general government final consumption expenditure as a percentage of GDP, sourced from the World Bank (2006). To capture the human capital effect, the number of years of schooling is incorporated, as used by Easterly and Levine (1997). (15)

Institutional factors appear to play an important role in determining economic growth. A number of previous works have shown that legal origin is profoundly associated with incentives for economic agents, and therefore with economic performance (eg, La Porta et al., 1997, 1998, 1999, 2008). Better-developed financial systems contribute to growth in capital-intensive sectors (Rajan and Zingales, 1998). Further, Levine (1998) argued that legal origin exogenously determined the degree of financial development that promoted economic growth. La Porta et al. (1998) asserted that French civil-law countries offer the weakest legal protection to investors while British common-law countries offer the strongest. French and British legal origin dummies are incorporated to capture these effects. (16) Apart from institutional factors, geographical factors such as latitude and land size are incorporated as independent variables to capture the existence of natural resources and climate.

The source of each variable is presented in Table A2. Table 1 shows the summary statistics for each variable used in the estimation (mean value, standard deviation, maximum value, and minimum value). Furthermore, Table 2 presents a correlation matrix of the variables. Table 2 shows that the proxies for ethnic heterogeneity are negatively correlated with labor productivity growth, both efficiency improvement and capital accumulation. Further, the correlation between them is statistically significant at the 1% level. This is consistent with our expectations. However, for a more detailed examination, the regression results must also be examined. (17)

RESULTS

The estimation results of the random-effects model with year dummy variables from 1966 to 1990 are reported in Tables 3-5. The results based on all observations available for the estimation are exhibited in columns (1) and (3) of each table. However, it is well known that DEA frontier estimates are strongly influenced by outliers. Hence, we also conducted an estimation where outliers were excluded to see how sensitive the estimates are to their removal. As shown in Figures 1 and 2, there are countries located on the frontier, such as the United States (USA), Luxemburg (LUX), and Hong Kong (HKG). Other countries, such as Canada (CAN), Switzerland (CHL) and Norway (NOR), are farther away. These countries can be considered as outliers, and, therefore, excluded. The excluded countries are included in columns (1) and (3), but not in columns (2) and (4) in Tables 3, 4, and 5. There were 1,312 observations used in the estimations for columns (1) and (3), whereas 1,187 were used for columns (2) and (4}. Hence, excluding outliers reduced the sample size by 9.5 %. Table 3 presents the results when labor-productivity growth is used as the dependent variable, Table 4 shows the results when efficiency improvement is used as the independent variable, and Table 5 reports the results when capital accumulation is the independent variable. The ethnic fractionalization and ethnic polarization indexes are used as a proxy for ethnic heterogeneity in each table. An F-test was conducted to check for unobservable individual effects and time effects. In all columns of Tables 3-5 the results of the F-test indicate that unobservable individual effects and time effects exist. Hence, these effects need to be controlled for using a fixed effects or random-effects estimation. In all columns in Tables 3-5, with the exception of column (4) of Table 3, the Hausman test does not reject the null hypothesis that the differences in coefficients between a fixed-effects model and a random-effects model are not systematic. This result implies that the random-effects model is valid and preferred.

We see in Table 3 that ethnic fractionalization yields a negative sign in column (1) and that ethnic polarization has a negative sign in columns (3). However, these coefficients are statistically significant in both columns (1) and (3). This implies that ethnic heterogeneity reduces labor-productivity growth. In addition, the number of natural disasters shows a significant positive sign in column (1), which is consistent with the argument of Skidmore and Toya (2002), where natural disasters may stimulate economic growth. Other variables do not show a significant sign in column (3), and hence they do not influence growth. As shown in columns (2) and (4), the results do not change when outliers are excluded. This suggests that the results for ethnic heterogeneity are robust. With respect to Table 4, the coefficient signs for ethnic fractionalization are negative in column (1), and that of ethnic polarization is also negative in column (3). Both are statistically significant. These results suggest that ethnic heterogeneity impedes information spillover. Furthermore, the results in columns (2) and (4) suggest that the results do not change when outliers are excluded. This indicates that the results for columns (1) and (3) are robust. Hence, the detrimental effect of ethnic heterogeneity on growth comes in part from the detrimental effect of ethnic heterogeneity on information spillover. Thus, Hypothesis 1 is strongly supported by the result. Concerning the other variables, the results are almost identical to the results presented in Table 3.

We see from Table 5 that the signs of the proxies for ethnic heterogeneity are positive in column (1) and negative in columns (2)-(4). However, they are not statistically significant. This indicates that outliers do not influence the results for ethnic heterogeneity. Ethnic heterogeneity thus does not affect capital accumulation, which is not consistent with the argument that ethnic heterogeneity reduces investment (Mauro, 1995). Hence, Hypothesis 2 is not supported by the results. Considering Tables 3-5 jointly, we conclude that ethnic heterogeneity impedes growth by reducing information spillovers rather than by reducing investment. The combined effects of ethnic heterogeneity on growth are negative, and thus, we conclude that ethnic heterogeneity is an obstacle to, rather than an engine of, economic growth.

CONCLUSIONS

There are conflicting views regarding the role of ethnic heterogeneity or diversity on growth. Social heterogeneity is thought to impede investment, reducing capital accumulation. What is more, heterogeneity is thought to hinder information spillovers, which hampers efficiency improvements over time. These have a detrimental effect on economic growth. This paper attempts to examine the influence of heterogeneity on economic growth by scrutinizing the channels through which heterogeneity affects such growth.

We used panel data from 55 countries, from 1965 to 1989, to decompose the effect of ethnic heterogeneity on growth. Using a random-effects regression model with year dummies, we found that ethnic heterogeneity has a negative effect on growth, mainly by hampering efficiency improvements, but not by reducing capital accumulation. We interpret these results to mean that ethnic heterogeneity hinders cooperation and communication among individuals and that cooperation and communication are important for technology diffusion. As a consequence, efficiency improvement is hampered, thereby impeding economic growth. In contrast, heterogeneity does not affect capital accumulation.

Information spillovers play an important role in developing countries; it enables them to catch up with more developed countries because it is otherwise difficult for them to create new technologies on their own (Vernon, 1966). From the findings in this paper, we derive the argument that heterogeneity is an obstacle to economic development, particularly for developing countries trying to catch up with developed countries via the acquisition of new technologies.

Information spillovers that occur through interactions among workers from various industries is thought to largely occur in urban rather than in rural areas (Jacobs, 1969, 1984). Such spatial factors were not considered in this study when the estimations were conducted because we used country-level macro data. Micro-level data should be used to more closely explore the effect of heterogeneity on information spillovers and therefore efficiency improvement. Furthermore, the influence of institutional factors on investment differs between private and public investment (Baliamoune-Lutz and Ndikumana, 2008). However, due to data limitations, our research was unable to examine how heterogeneity influences private and public capital accumulation. These remaining issues should be addressed in future research.

APPENDIX
Table A3: Countries used in DEA

Code   Country name

ARG    Argentina
AUS    Australia
AUT    Austria
BEL    Belgium
BOL    Bolivia
CAN    Canada (a)
CHL    Switzerland (a)
COL    Colombia
DNK    Denmark
DOM    Dominican Republic
ECU    Ecuador
FIN    Finland
FRA    France
DEU    Germany
GRC    Greece
GTM    Guatemala
HND    Honduras
HKG    Hong Kong, China (a)
ISL    Iceland
IND    India
IRL    Ireland
ISR    Israel
ITA    Italy
CIV    Ivory Coast
JAM    Jamaica
JPN    Japan
KEN    Kenya
KOR    Korea, Rep.
LUX    Luxembourg (a)
MDG    Madagascar
MWI    Malawi
MUS    Mauritius
MEX    Mexico
MAR    Morocco
NLD    Netherlands
NZL    New Zealand
NGA    Nigeria
NOR    Norway (a)
PAN    Panama
PRY    Paraguay
PER    Peru
PHL    Philippines
PRT    Portugal
SLE    Sierra Leone
ESP    Spain
LKA    Sri Lanka
SWE    Sweden
CHE    Switzerland
SYR    Syrian Arab Republic
TWN    Taiwan, China (b)
THA    Thailand
TUR    Turkey
GBR    United Kingdom
USA    United States (a)
YUG    Yugoslavia (b)
ZMB    Zambia
ZWE    Zimbabwe

(a) indicates countries excluded in sample used for estimation in
columns (2) and (4) of Tables 3, 4, and 5.

(b) indicates countries excluded in all columns of Tables 3, 4,
and 5.

Table A2: Source of data

                              Source

Ln(Output)                    Penn World Table 5.6
Capital Stock per capita      Penn World Table 5.6
Ethnic fractionalization      Website of Marta Reynal-Querol (a)
Ethnic polarization           Website of Marta Reynal-Querol (a)
Number of natural disasters   EM-DAT (Emergency Events Database) (b)
Government size               World Bank (2006)
Land size                     World Bank (2006)
French legal origin           Website of Andrei Shleifer (c)
British legal origin          Website of Andrei Shleifer (c)
Land size                     World Bank (2006)

Note: With the exception of the World Bank (2006), the data were
obtained from the internet as follows:

(a) http://www.econ.upf.edu/}{{{-}{}}}{reynal/data_web.htm
(accessed on December 1, 2011).

(b) http://www.emdat.be (accessed on June 1, 2011).

(c) http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/shleifer/dataset
(accessed on June 2, 2011).


REFERENCES

Alesina, A and La Ferrara, E. 2005: Ethnic diversity and economic performance. Journal of Economic Literature 43 (3): 762-800.

Alesina, A, Baqir, R and Easterly, W. 1999: Public goods and ethnic divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(4): 1243-1284.

Alesina, A, Devleeschauwer, A, Easterly, W, Kurlat, S and Wacziarg, R. 2003: Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth 8(2): 155-194.

Baliamoune-Lutz, M and Ndikumana, L. 2008: Corruption and growth in African countries: Exploring the investment channel. Working papers 2008-8, University of Massachusetts: Amherst, Department of Economics.

Beugelsdijk, S, de Groot, HLF and van Schaik, A.B.T.M. 2004: Trust and economic growth: A robustness analysis. Oxford Economic Papers 56(1): 118-134.

Beugelsdijk, S and van Schaik, A.B.T.M. 2005: Social capital and growth in European regions: An empirical test. European Journal of Political Economy 21 (2): 301-324.

Dincer, OC. 2011: Ethnic diversity and trust. Contemporary Economic Policy 29(2): 284-293.

Easterly, B and Levine, R. 1997: Africa's growth tragedy: Policies and ethnic divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): 1203-1250.

Henderson, JD and Russell, RR. 2005: Human capital and convergence: A production-frontier approach. International Economic Review 46: 1167-1205.

Isaksson, A. 2011: Social divisions and institutions: Assessing institutional parameter variation. Public Choice 147(3): 331-357.

Jambs, J. 1969: The economies of cities. Vintage: New York.

Jacobs, J. 1984: The wealth of nations: Principles of economic life. Vintage: New York.

Kumar, S and Russell, RR. 2002: Technological change, technological catch-up, and capital deepening: Relative contributions to growth and convergence. American Economic Review 92(3): 527-548.

La Porta, R, Lopez de Silanes, F and Shleifer, A. 2008: The economic consequence of legal origins. Journal of Economic Literature 46(2): 285-332.

La Porta, R, Lopez de Silanes, F, Shleifer, A and Vishni, R. 1997: Legal deterrents of external finance. Journal of Finance 57(3): 1131-1150.

La Porta, R, Lopez de Silanes, F, Shleifer, A and Vishni, R. 1998: Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy 106(6): 1113-1150.

La Porta, R, Lopez de Silanes, F, Shleifer, A and Vishni, R. 1999: Quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 15(1): 222-279.

Levine, R. 1998: The legal environment, banks, and long-run economic growth. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 30(3): 596-613.

Lind, JT. 2007: Fractionalization and the size of government. Journal of Public Economics 91 (1-2): 51-76. Marshall, A. 1920: Principles of Economics. Macmillan Press: London.

Mauro, P. 1995: Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3): 681-712.

Montalvo, JG and Reynal-Querol, M. 2003: Religious polarization and economic development. Economics Letters 80(2): 201-210.

Montalvo, JG and Reynal-Querol, M. 2005a: Ethnic polarization, potential conflict and civil war. American Economic Review 95 (3): 796-816.

Montalvo, JG and Reynal-Querol, M. 2005b: Ethnic diversity and economic development. Journal of Development Economics 76(2): 293-323.

Mueller, DC. 2003: Public Choice III. Cambridge University Press: New York.

Munshi, K. 2004: Social learning in a heterogeneous population: Technology diffusion in the Indian Green Revolution. Journal of Development Economics 73 (1): 185-213.

Nishimizu, M and Page, J. 1982: Total factor productivity growth, technological progress and technical efficiency change: Dimensions of productivity change in Yugoslavia, 1965-78. Economic Journal 92(368): 920-936.

Rajan, RG and Zingales, L. 1998: Financial development and growth. American Economic Review 88(3): 559-586.

Reynal-Querol, M. 2002: Ethnicity, political systems and civil war. Journal of Conflict Resolution 46(1): 29-54.

Skidmore, M and Toya, H. 2002: Do natural disasters promote long-run growth? Economic Inquiry 40(4): 664-687.

Thornton, RA and Thompson, P. 2001: Learning from experience and learning from others: An exploration of learning and spillovers in wartime shipbuilding. American Economic Review 91(5): 1350-1368.

Vernon, R. 1966: International investment and international trade in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics 80(2): 190-207.

World Bank. 2006: World Development Indicators, CD-ROM. World Bank: Washington, D.C.

Yamamura, E. 2011: Decomposition of the effect of government size on growth. Economics Letters 112(3): 230-232.

Yamamura, E and Shin, I. 2007a: Technological change and catch-up and capital deepening: Relative contributions to growth and convergence. Economics Bulletin 15(3): 1-8.

Yamamura, E and Shin, I. 2007b: Dynamics of agglomeration economies and regional industrial structure: The case of the assembly industry of the greater Tokyo Region, 1960-2000. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 18(4): 483-499.

Yamamura, E and Shin, I. 2008: The benefit of efficiency improvement on growth and convergence: A study using Japan panel data. Economics Letters 99(1): 209-211.

Zak, PJ and Knack, S. 2001: Trust and growth. Economic Journal 111 (470): 295-321.

EIJI YAMAMURA [1] & INYONG SHIN [2]

[1] Department of Economics, Seinan Gakuin University, 6-2-92 Sawaraku Nishijin, Fukuoka 814-8511, Japan. E-mail: yamaei@seinan-gu.ac.jp

[2] Asia University, 5-24-10 Sakai Musashino-shi, Tokyo 180-8629, Japan.

(1) Previous works examined the effect of religious heterogeneity on economic development, which relate to works exploring the influence of ethnic heterogeneity (Alesina et al., 2003; Montalvo and Reynal-Querol, 2003).

(2) Alesina et al. (1999) used US data to show that shares of spending on productive public goods are inversely related to a city's (metro area's/county's) ethnic fragmentation.

(3) Heterogeneity is found to influence government size (Lind, 2007). This also possibly affects economic performance and growth.

(4) The seminal work of Nishimizu and Page (1982) attempted to decompose total productivity growth into technological progress and technical efficiency change.

(5) Thornton and Thompson (2001), using micro-level data on wartime shipbuilding, suggest that learning spillovers were a significant source of productivity growth.

(6) Mauro (1995) exhibits a negative and significant correlation between ethnic heterogeneity and institutional efficiency. Institutional efficiency is positively associated with economic efficiency. It follows then, with the exception of the information spillover channel, that ethnic heterogeneity impedes efficiency improvements.

(7) A secured property right is considered to provide an incentive to invest and therefore creates capital accumulation. Isaksson (2011) used cross-countries data to present evidence that social division measured in terms of ethnic fractionalization weakens the association between property rights institutions and income. If this is true, then heterogeneity reduces the incentive to invest even when property rights are well secured.

(8) Kumar and Russell (2002) admitted that their method includes the possibility of an implosion of the technological frontier. Henderson and Russell (2005) precluded an implosion of the frontier over time. In this paper, it is also precluded.

(9) The independent variables used in this paper were not available for two of the 57 countries. Hence, data from just 55 countries were used in the estimation, which are identified in Table A2, in the Appendix.

(10) In alternative estimations, instead of the log for GDP per capita, the initial level of technical efficiency (level of capital stock) is included when change in technical efficiency (capital accumulation) is examined. In these alternative estimations using a random-effects model, the results for ethnic heterogeneity are similar to those reported in this paper. However, the Hausman test does not reject the null hypothesis that the results of a fixed-effects model are systematically different from those of a random-effects model. This suggests that the results of an estimation using a random-effects model suffer from estimation bias. However, the effect of ethnic heterogeneity is captured completely by country-specific effects in a fixed-effects model. Hence, the results of an alternative specification are not reported in this paper, but are available upon request from the author.

(11) The data are available from Center of International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania, http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ (accessed May 1, 2007).

(12) Data on ethnic fractionalization and polarization is available at http://www.econ.upf.edu/ ~reynal/data_web.htm (accessed June 1, 2011).

(13) The data were obtained from the International Disaster Database, http://www.emdat.be (accessed June 1, 2011).

(14) Wars and civil disturbances are also considered to have an effect on growth. However, in less-developed countries, discontent regarding governmental economic polity increases, which possibly triggers a civil war or disturbance. That is, the occurrence of wars and civil disturbances are thought to be influenced by economic growth. Hence, wars and civil disturbances can be considered as endogenous variables, resulting in estimation bias. It is for this reason that these variables are not incorporated as independent variables.

(15) The number of years at school is available only for 1960, 1970, and 1980. Therefore, to construct the panel data, additional data were generated by interpolation based on the assumption of constant changes in rates to compensate for this deficiency. After 1980, the value for 1980 is used. The data are available from http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXT RESEARCH/0,,contentMDK:20700002 ~ pagePK:64214825 ~ piPK:64214943 ~ theSitePK:469382,00.html (accessed June 2, 2011).

(16) In addition to legal origins, institutional factors captured by, for instance, corruption and transparency of government appear to influence economic growth. However, the variables used to capture them are regarded as endogenous variables because the causality between these factors and economic growth is ambiguous. Hence, these variables lead to estimation bias and are not used in this paper. In contrast, legal origin is related to historical events. Therefore, legal origin dummies can be considered as exogenous variables and are used in this paper.

(17) Correlation between British legal origin and French legal origin countries is -0.67 and statistically significant at the 1% level. With the exception of British legal origin and French legal origin countries, all other legal origin countries (German legal origin and Scandinavian legal origin countries) are included in the sample. That is, even if a country is not a French legal origin country, there is the possibility that the country is not a British legal origin country.
Table 1: Basic statistics

                                             Standard
                                    Mean     deviation

Gr(output)                          1.01       0.05
Gr(efficiency)                      0.99       0.04
Gr(capital)                         1.01       0.02
Ln(Output)                          9.19       0.87
Ethnic fractionalization            0.39       0.27
Ethnic polarization                 0.48       0.26
Number of natural disasters         1.24       2.19
Government size                     14.9       5.81
(Government expenditure/GDP) (%)
French legal origin                 0.49       0.50
British legal origin                0.32       0.46
Latitude                            0.33       0.19
Land size ([Km.sup.2])             871,614   1,904,466

                                    Maximum    Minimum

Gr(output)                           1.37       0.75
Gr(efficiency)                       1.38       0.71
Gr(capital)                          1.15       0.92
Ln(Output)                           10.5        674
Ethnic fractionalization             0.90       0.01
Ethnic polarization                  0.95       0.02
Number of natural disasters           22          0
Government size                      43.4       3.84
(Government expenditure/GDP) (%)
French legal origin                    1          0
British legal origin                   1          0
Latitude                             0.72       0.01
Land size ([Km.sup.2])             9,158,960    1,042

Table 2: Correlation matrix

                               Gr            Gr            Gr
                            (output)    (efficiency)   (capital)

Gr(output)                  1.00
Gr(efficiency)              0.85 ***     1.00
                           (0.00)
Gr(copital)                 0.31 ***    -0.11 ***       1.00
                           (0.00)       (0.00)
Ln(Output)                 -0.01         0.03          -0.09 ***
                           (0.71)       (0.15)         (0.00)
Ethnic fractionalization   -0.12 ***    -0.09 ***      -0.08 ***
                           (0.00)       (0.00)         (0.00)
Ethnic polarization        -0.10 ***    -0.08 ***      -0.07 ***
                           (0.00)       (0.00)         (0.00)
Number of natural          -0.002        0.03          -0.07 ***
disasters
                           (0.91)       (0.13)         (0.00)
Government size            -0.09 ***     0.03          -0.25 ***
                           (0.00)       (0.24)         (0.00)
French legal origin        -0.05 **     -0.07 ***       0.06 *
                           (0.03)       (0.00)         (0.02)
British legal origin       -0.03         0.02          -0.16 ***
                           (0.20)       (0.35)         (0.00)
Latitude                    0.05 **      0.03           0.04 *
                           (0.02)       (0.15)         (0.07)
Land size                  -0.04 *      -0.01          -0.11 ***
                           (0.06)       (0.58)         (0.00)

                               Ln            Ethnic
                            (Output)    fractionalization

Gr(output)
Gr(efficiency)

Gr(copital)

Ln(Output)                  1.00

Ethnic fractionalization   -0.43 **      1.00
                           (0.00)
Ethnic polarization        -0.14 ***     0.66 ***
                           (0.00)       (0.00)
Number of natural           0.02         0.17 ***
disasters
                           (0.36)       (0.00)
Government size             0.39 ***    -0.19 ***
                           (0.00)       (0.00)
French legal origin         0.01         0.02
                           (0.75)       (0.36)
British legal origin       -0.23 ***     0.29 ***
                           (0.00)       (0.00)
Latitude                    0.07 ***     0.03
                           (0.00)       (0.16)
Land size                   0.23 ***     0.25 ***
                           (0.00)       (0.00)

                              Ethnic      Number of    Government
                           polarization    natural        size
                                          disasters

Gr(output)
Gr(efficiency)
Gr(copital)
Ln(Output)
Ethnic fractionalization
Ethnic polarization         1.00
Number of natural          -0.02           1.00
disasters                  (0.32)
Government size            -0.14 ***      -0.15 ***     1.00
                           (0.00)         (0.00)
French legal origin         0.24 ***      -0.04 *      -0.26 ***
                           (0.00)         (0.07)       (0.00)
British legal origin        0.10 ***       0.10 ***     0.10 ***
                           (0.10)         (0.00)       (0.00)
Latitude                   -0.13 ***       0.14 ***    -0.09 ***
                           (0.00)         (0.00)       (0.00)
Land size                   0.16 ***       0.38 ***     0.06 **
                           (0.00)         (0.00)       (0.01)

                             French      British      Latitude
                             legal        legal
                             origin       origin
Gr(output)
Gr(efficiency)
Gr(copital)
Ln(Output)
Ethnic fractionalization
Ethnic polarization
Number of natural
disasters
Government size
French legal origin         1.00
British legal origin       -0.67 ***     1.00
                           (0.00)
Latitude                   -0.06 **     -0.008        1.00
                           (0.01)       (0.75)
Land size                  -0.15 ***     0.30 ***     0.18 ***
                           (0.00)       (0.00)       (0.00)

                              Land
                              size

Gr(output)
Gr(efficiency)
Gr(copital)
Ln(Output)
Ethnic fractionalization
Ethnic polarization
Number of natural
disasters
Government size
French legal origin
British legal origin
Latitude
Land size                   1.00

*, **, and *** indicate significance at
the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Numbers in parentheses are p-statistics.

Table 3: Determinants of labor-productivity
growth (random-effects estimates: 1965-1989)

                                     (1)                  (2)
                                 Full sample       Excluding outliers

Ln(Output)                          -0.001               -0.002
                                   (-0.52)-             (-0.73)-
Ethnic fractionalization          -0.030 ***           -0.030 ***
                                   (-3.45)              (-3.19)
Ethnic polarization

Number of natural disasters        0.001 *               0.001
                                    (1.86)               (1.57)
Government size                    -0.001 *             -0.001 *
                                   (-1.77)              (-1.58)
French legal origin                 -0.007               -0.007
                                   (-1.06)              (-1.03)
British legal origin                -0.001               -0.001
                                   (-0.09)              (-0.23)
Latitude                             0.01                 0.01
                                    (1.49)               (1.12)
Land size                     -0.96 x [10.sup.2]   -2.09 x [10.sup.2]
                                   (-0.79)              (-1.09)
Constant                           1.05 ***             1.06 ***
                                    (38.6)               (36.3)
F-test (Year dummies)                3.28                 2.79
                                 p-value=0.00         p-value=0.00
F-test (Country dummies)             2.24                 2.28
                                 p-value=0.00         p-value=0.00
Housman test                         33.1                 25.2
                                 p-value=0.18         p-value=0.55
Groups                                55                   50
Observations                        1,312                1,187

                                     (3)                  (4)
                                 Full sample       Excluding outliers

Ln(Output)                          0.002                0.001
                                   (0.91)-               (0.44)
Ethnic fractionalization

Ethnic polarization               -0.020 **             -0.018 *
                                   (-2.28)              (-1.96)
Number of natural disasters         0.001                0.001
                                    (1.43)               (0.99)
Government size                    -0.001 *             -0.001 *
                                   (-1.97)              (-1.65)
French legal origin                 -0.007               -0.008
                                   (-1.05)              (-1.09)
British legal origin                -0.002               -0.004
                                   (-0.32)              (-0.57)
Latitude                            0.009                0.006
                                    (0.95)               (0.57)
Land size                     -1.70 x [10.sup.2]   -2.70 x [10.sup.2]
                                   (-1.40)              (-1.36)
Constant                           1.02 ***             1.03 ***
                                    (39.8)               (36.5)
F-test (Year dummies)                3.28                 2.79
                                 p-value=0.00         p-value=0.00
F-test (Country dummies)             2.43                 2.49
                                 p-value=0.00         p-value=0.00
Housman test                         2.08                 41.1
                                 p-value=0.99         p-value=0.04
Groups                                55                   50
Observations                        1,312                1,187

*, **, and *** indicate significance at the
10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Note: Year dummies are not reported but are included in all
estimations as independent variables. Numbers in parentheses
are z-statistics.

Table 4: Determinants of efficiency improvement
(random-effects estimates: 1965-1989)

                                     (1)                  (2)
                                 Full sample       Excluding outliers

Ln(Output)                          -0.001               -0.001
                                   (-0.06)-             (-0.56)-
Ethnic fractionalization          -0.021 ***           -0.018 ***
                                   (-3.34)              (-2.80)
Ethnic polarization

Number of natural disasters        0.001 *              0.001 *
                                    (1.78)               (1.68)
Government size                     0.0001               0.0002
                                    (0.50)               (0.91)
French legal origin                 0.001                -0.001
                                    (0.50)              (-0.26)
British legal origin                0.001                0.004
                                    (0.01)               (0.77)
Latitude                             0.01                 0.01
                                    (1.44)               (0.67)
Land size                     -0.73 x [10.sup.2]   -1.33 x [10.sup.2]
                                   (-0.85)              (-0.99)
Constant                           0.99 ***             1.00 ***
                                    (49.2)               (47.6)
F-test (Year dummies)                3.43                 2.78
                                 p-value=0.00         p-value=0.00
F-test (Country dummies)             1.95                 1.90
                                 p-value=0.00         p-value=0.00
Hausman test                         28.4                 19.1
                                 p-value=0.38         p-value=0.85
Groups                                55                   50
Observations                        1,312                1,187

                                     (3)                  (4)
                                 Full sample       Excluding outliers

Ln(Output)                          0.002                0.001
                                   (1.40)-              (0.58)-
Ethnic fractionalization

Ethnic polarization               -0.013 **             -0.010 *
                                   (-2.26)              (-1.68)
Number of natural disasters         0.001                0.001
                                    (1.24)               (1.10)
Government size                     0.001                0.0002
                                    (1.24)               (0.75)
French legal origin                 -0.004               -0.002
                                   (-0.08)              (-0.45)
British legal origin                0.006                0.002
                                    (1.24)               (0.40)
Latitude                            0.006                0.001
                                    (0.90)               (0.23)
Land size                     -1.19 x [10.sup.2]   -1.63 x [10.sup.2]
                                   (-1.37)              (-1.22)
Constant                           0.96 ***             0.98 ***
                                    (51.4)               (49.9)
F-test (Year dummies)                3.43                 2.78
                                 p-value=0.00         p-value=0.00
F-test (Country dummies)             2.06                 2.00
                                 p-value=0.00         p-value=0.00
Hausman test                         36.4                 30.7
                                 p-value=0.11         p-value=0.28
Groups                                55                   50
Observations                        1,312                1,187

*, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1%
levels, respectively.

Note: Year dummies are not reported but are included in all
estimations as independent variables. Numbers in parentheses
are z-statistics.

Table 5: Determinants of capital accumulation
(random-effects estimates: 1965-1989)

                                    (1)                    (2)
                                Full sample         Excluding outliers

Ln(Output)                       0.004 ***              0.005 ***
                                  (2.81)-                (3.07)-
Ethnic fractionalization          0.0007                  -0.001
                                  (0.11)                 (-0.17)
Ethnic polarization

Number of natural                  0.003                  0.002
  disasters                       (1.34)                  (0.86)
Government size                 -0.001 ***              -0.001 ***
                                  (3.99)                  (3.92)
French legal origin               -0.004                  -0.002
                                  (-0.98)                (-0.48)
British legal origin              -0.006                  -0.003
                                  (-1.13)                (-0.54)
Latitude                           0.004                  0.007
                                  (0.67)                  (0.95)
Land size                  -1.79 x [10.sup.9] **   -2.35 x [10.sup.9] *
                                  (-2.13)                (-1.79)
Constant                         0.99 ***                0.98 ***
                                  (58.9)                  (55.4)
F-test (Year dummies)              18.7                    19.6
                               p-value=0.00            p-value=0.00
F-test (Country dummies)           10.8                    10.8
                               p-value=0.00            p-value=0.00
Housman test                       27.9                    29.9
                               p-value=0.41            p-value=0.31
Groups                              55                      50
Observations                       1,312                  1,187

                                    (3)                    (4)
                                Full sample         Excluding outliers

Ln(Output)                       0.004 ***              0.005 ***
                                  (3.01)-                (3.40)-
Ethnic fractionalization

Ethnic polarization               -0.003                  -0.005
                                  (-0.58)                (-0.79)
Number of natural                  0.003                  0.002
  disasters                       (1.31)                  (0.82)
Government size                 -0.001 ***              -0.001 ***
                                  (4.00)                  (3.93)
French legal origin               -0.003                  -0.001
                                  (-0.61)                (-0.10)
British legal origin              -0.004                  -0.001
                                  (-0.83)                (-0.21)
Latitude                           0.004                  0.007
                                  (0.61)                  (0.90)
Land size                  -1.70 x [10.sup.9] **   -2.40 x [10.sup.9] *
                                  (-2.06)                (-1.80)
Constant                         0.99 ***                0.98 ***
                                  (62.1)                  (57.2)
F-test (Year dummies)              18.7                    19.6
                               p-value=0.00            p-value=0.00
F-test (Country dummies)           11.6                    11.9
                               p-value=0.00            p-value=0.00
Housman test                       26.2                    26.8
                               p-value=0.50            p-value=0.47
Groups                              55                      50
Observations                       1,312                  1,187

*, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5% and 1%
levels, respectively.

Note: Year dummies are not reported but are included in all
estimations as independent variables. Numbers in parentheses
are z-statistics.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有