House price determinants: fundamentals and underlying factors.
Algieri, Bernardina
INTRODUCTION
The determinants of house prices have attracted much attention in
recent years, because of the increasing role played by the house sector
in the global economy (1) and the global boom and bust in house prices
in several countries. From 2000 to 2006, house prices rose in most
advanced countries. For example, they soared in the United States and
other Anglo-Saxon systems, fuelled by financial innovations. In Spain,
house prices were buoyed by easy credit conditions, namely, extended
mortgage periods and record-low interest rates resulting from monetary
easing and fierce inter-bank competition, increasing household incomes,
strong employment growth, high foreign real estate investments, and
demographic factors (explicitly record levels of immigration and the
Spanish baby boom that increased household formation) (IMF, 2009). In
the Netherlands, the rise in house prices was triggered by robust income
growth and the pro-cyclical lending standards of the banks. In 2007,
house prices started to fall, first in the United States and then
elsewhere. It seems that house prices in many industrial countries
follow trends in the United States, with a lag of at least 6 months and
up to 2 years (Deutsche Bank, 2010). Rollercoaster house prices are
often seen as a major cause of the current global financial crisis and
recession and have been commonly considered a threat to global
prosperity since the Great Depression (Loungani, 2010). It is,
therefore, important to understand the drivers of real estate prices, as
doing so would contribute to the preservation of macroeconomic and
financial stability, and facilitate household consumption and
saving/investment decisions.
In this context, the present study examines real house price
dynamics in two groups of industrialized countries: one belonging to the
Euro area, the other to the Anglo-Saxon group. In particular, the
analysis focuses on the five largest Euro countries (Germany, France,
Italy, Spain, and the Netherlands) and on the two largest Anglo-Saxon
economies (the United Kingdom and the United States). This would help to
investigate common features and broad differences in house price
dynamics across countries.
In the two country groups, real house prices have shown peculiar
trends. Looking at their development from a historical perspective, four
striking aspects appear from a graphical inspection (Figure 1). First,
there have been periodic run-ups in the real house prices of these
countries during the past 40 years. This means that real house prices
show cyclical movements. Second, the size of real price increases during
the period from 1997-2007 was impressive. Afterward, the global
recession induced significant price drops. Third, price hikes and falls
occurred simultaneously across countries. Put differently, real house
prices have a tendency to co-move and to be highly synchronized. Fourth,
Germany is a special case: real house prices have been rather stable; in
particular, modest price movements and even drops have been observed
over time. The pattern of declining real house prices in Germany can be
ascribed to the interaction of several factors. These include the
excessive supply of houses that resulted from the construction boom that
followed German unification (Terrones and Otrok, 2004), slowdowns in
population growth (Ahearne et al., 2005), restrictive financing
conditions including the absence of 'innovative' mortgages
product, which contributed to hold back demand for houses (Westerheide,
2010), and the moderate growth in real disposable income (Kholodilin et
al., 2010).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Table 1 offers more evidence on real house price variations at an
average annual rate. The Anglo-Saxon countries registered real price
growth from 1970 to 2007. The same trend holds true for France. Italy
and Spain have instead registered a real price contraction during the
decade 1991-2000, while the Netherlands experienced a small drop in
1981-1990. During the years 2001-2007, house price growth was
particularly strong in the United Kingdom, France, and Spain, with an
average annual growth rate, in real terms, of 8.8%, 9.10% and 9.84%,
respectively. Lesser increases have been registered in the Netherlands,
Italy, and the United States, with average annual growth rates of about
3% and 6%. The fact that the United States belongs to the latter group
is significant, given that the financial storm, which first struck the
United States in August 2007, has its roots in the biggest house and
credit bubble in history (The Economist, 11.10.2008). Nevertheless, the
gap between the first and second group narrows if we consider the
percentage price increase between 2005 and 2007. Germany is the only
country to show counter-cyclical price developments.
In general, the synchronization of price movements across most of
the countries has induced some observers to believe that the house price
boom is a bubble (Hilbers et al., 2001; Klyuev, 2008; Girouard et al.,
2006). Thus, the house price run-ups may partly be driven by factors
that are unrelated to economic fundamentals, especially the record-low
interest rates registered in the new millennium.
This study thus tries to shed light on fundamentals and underlying
factors that cause price fluctuations within an error correction
mechanism. Technically, it introduces, in addition to the traditional
triggers of real house prices, such as interest rates and disposable
income, an unobserved component in the form of a time-varying trend, in
order to pick up on the stochastic un-modeled behaviors of the series.
Underlying factors could include economic elements that are unknown,
unobservable, unquantifiable, or not easy to compute, such as structural
changes in markets (eg land use restrictions) or in the level of
government interventions in markets that are difficult to measure (eg
homeowner's interest deducibility from taxes, grants for first time
home buyers, and cuts in rental properties' taxes), and those
factors of 'irrational exuberance' or changing tastes. Most
studies have estimated equilibrium prices for house and their deviation
from fundamentals without providing information with respect to the
underlying unobserved drivers. This study goes one step further than
other studies by capturing the veiled factors that influence price
development in the form of stochastic trends. This is done to
characterize unmodeled long-run real house price movements, reduce the
residuals in estimations, and better gauge the elasticity of the
fundamentals. If stochastic trends are appropriate, but are not
explicitly modeled, their effects will be picked up indirectly by time
trends and lags on the variables. This can lead to a proliferation of
lags that have no economic meaning, and which are subject to common
factors and problems of inference associated with unit roots (Harvey and
Shephard, 1993). In addition, the omission of important long-run
information implies that the long-run equation is misspecified, thus
raising the problem of spurious regression and omitted variables or
measurement errors. The inclusion of the unobserved time series
components adds an extra dimension to the interpretation and
specification of certain aspects of the price dynamics.
The rest of this article is organized as follows. The next section
presents a literature review of the determinants of house prices. The
section 'Econometric methodology' describes data and
methodology. The section after that, 'Estimation of House
Prices', presents the results, and the final section concludes.
THE LITERATURE ON HOUSE PRICE DETERMINANTS
Houses can be regarded as both an investment and consumption goods.
This distinguishes them not only from financial assets (eg shares), the
simple possession of which does not originate any utility, but also from
other real assets (eg land, machinery, gold, coins, stamps, art and
antiques) that require a sufficiently developed secondary market to be
included in an investment portfolio (Banco de Espana, 2003). Moreover,
houses have long average lives--they are durable goods--and can be
subjected to long construction processes because of cumbersome building
regulations and slow administrative procedures, (2) which implies that,
in the short term, their supply is relatively rigid. Likewise, a house
is linked to a specific location and, therefore, to a limited land
supply (including zoning restrictions), even over the very long term.
Owing to the high acquisition value, in relation to average household
income, the house market is also closely linked to the mortgage
financing market. Changes in the supply of mortgage lending are,
therefore, a significant determinant of the demand for houses. Other
fundamentals driving the demand for houses are household wealth,
population growth, inflation, credit availability, interest rates, and
unemployment. As the supply side of the market is more rigid, both
because of the shortage of land for houses and the time needed for new
construction to be completed, most empirical literature focuses on the
demand side when estimating house price determinants. Put differently,
the existence of supply-side constraints and other market imperfections
make house prices chiefly demand driven, above all in the short run.
It should be noted that although there is a broad consensus among
researchers regarding the direction of the impact of each house price
determinant, there is less agreement regarding the size, the explanatory
power, and the relative explanatory importance of the variables to be
added to the main house price drivers, namely, household incomes and
interest rates.
A summary of the literature review is reported in the Appendix.
Table A2 shows that some authors only consider interest rates and
disposable income as real price drivers (Hofman, 2005; Hunt and Badia,
2005), while others add such explanatory determinants as unemployment
(McCarthy and Peach, 2004; Schnure, 2005), house stock supply (McCarthy
and Peach, 2004; Verbruggen et al., 2005, Wagner, 2005), inflation
(Annett, 2005; Almeida et al., 2006; Davis and Zhu, 2004; Iossifov et
al., 2008; Tsatsaronis and Zhu, 2004), house stock and/or stock market
and real credit (Ayuso et al., 2003; Annett, 2005; Bessone et al., 2005;
Fitzpatrick and McQuinn, 2004; OECD, 2004; Sutton, 2002), and population
growth (OECD, 2004; Terrones and Otrok, 2004; Wagner, 2005). Reported
elasticities differ widely. For instance, real interest rates vary by
-7.7% to -0.02%, and real per-capita income varies by 0.3-8.3%. This
could be because of the types of empirical techniques adopted (time
series versus panel estimates), the inclusion of additional explanatory
variables, or the databases used. Panel analyses generally tend to
report more contained interest rates and income elasticity than time
series analyses. For instance, Hilbers et al. (2008), using a panel data
approach, uncovered differences in house price developments between
three distinct groups of European countries: those with rapidly
increasing house prices, called the 'fast lane', including
Spain, Belgium, Ireland, the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, and
France; those showing a closer-to-average development--the 'average
performers'--comprised of the Nordic countries, Italy, and Greece;
and those with relatively stagnant house prices--the 'slow
movers'--including Germany, Austria, Switzerland, and Portugal. For
these groups, income elasticity was about or less than 1. In his panel
approach, Schnure (2005) also found a small income elasticity of
0.2-0.3. Iossifov et al. (2008) investigated residential property prices
in 20 advanced countries in Western Europe and Asia and found that house
prices are related to some economic fundamentals, and that more than
half of price adjustments take place within a quarter with small income
and interest rate elasticity. Higher elasticity is found in the analyses
based on the Johansen procedure by Bessone et al. (2005), McCarthy and
Peach (2004), and Gattini and Hiebert (2010), and in the error
correction model (ECM) models by the OECD (2004), Meen (2002) and Ayuso
et al. (2006). Another interesting result is that transition countries
tend to have higher income and interest rate elasticity than
industrialized countries (Egert and Mihaljek, 2007).
Against this background, the present study proposes a novel
methodology that sheds light on observable and unobservable factors that
influence house prices, with the aim of more accurately assessing each
variable's elasticity and explaining an important part of price
increases that remains unexplained by existing empirical analyses.
ECONOMETRIC METHODOLOGY
The unobserved component model
To evaluate the factors that push price movements over time, a
structural time series framework, developed by Harvey (1989), has been
adopted. In a structural time series model the explanatory variables
enter into the model side by side with the unobserved components, which
slowly evolve over time. Several applied economists assume that the
variables have strong deterministic trends. Therefore, they incorporate
a time-invariant trend with constant level and slope parameters to
variables when estimating autoregressive models. In contrast Harvey
(1997, p. 192), pointed out that '... unless the time period is
fairly short, these trends cannot be adequately captured by straight
lines. In other words, a deterministic linear time trend is too
restrictive...'. He suggested that time series models should add in
gradually evolving stochastic instead of deterministic trends.
The basic structural time series framework can be expressed as:
[y.sub.t] = [phi][x.sub.t] + [[mu].sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t] (1)
where [x.sub.t] is a k x 1 vector of exogenous regressors,
[[phi].sub.t] is a k x 1 vector of coefficients, [[mu].sub.t] is the
time-varying trend or unobserved component and [[epsilon].sub.t] is the
irregular disturbance term or transient component. The [x.sub.t] vector
includes the lagged values of the dependent variable, as well as the
lagged values of exogenous variables. The trend component [[mu].sub.t]
assumes local linear specification, as given by:
[[mu].sub.t] = [[mu].sub.t-1] + [[beta].sub.t-1] + [[eta].sub.t]
[approximately equal to] NID(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[eta]]) (2)
[[beta].sub.t] = [[beta].sub.t-1] + [[xi].sub.t] [[xi].sub.t]
[approximately equal to] NID(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[xi]]) (3)
where equation (2) defines the level of the trend and equation and
(3) defines its slope ([beta]), that is, its growth rate. The stochastic
disturbances [[epsilon].sub.t], [[eta].sub.t] and [[xi].sub.t] are
normally distributed and mutually uncorrelated at all lags and leads.
The local linear trend specifies both the level and the slope as
stochastic, but the trend can also be a random walk with drift (local
level with drift) when [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[xi]] = 0 and
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.[xi]] > 0 or random walk without drift (local
level) when [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[xi]] = 0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[eta]] >
0 and [beta] = 0. A trend has a smooth specification when the level is
fixed ([[sigma].sup.2].sub.[eta]] = 0) and the slope is stochastic
([[sigma].sup.2.sub.[xi]] > 0). The model reduces to a global or
deterministic trend when [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[xi]] =
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.[eta]] = 0, in which case the level does not vary
over time. It is worth noting that to have a stationary disturbance
term, it is necessary to difference twice for local linear trends and
once for the local level, regardless of whether there is drift and a
deterministic trend (Harvey and Scott, 1994). In the latter case,
equation (1) becomes:
[DELTA][y.sub.t] = [phi][DELTA][x.sub.t] + [delta][x.sub.t-1] +
[[mu].sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t] (4)
where the lagged variables constitute the long-run dynamics and the
differenced variables ([DELTA]) represent the short-run dynamics.
The error correction specification
As it is possible to envisage a wide range of demand and supply
fundamentals underlying the evolution of house prices, a specification
that uses six variables and an unobserved component has been adopted to
explain the evolution of house prices. In particular, the choice of
explanatory variables mirrors the consensus in the literature that house
prices are primarily determined by factors affecting aggregate demand in
the short run--in primis interest rate and income--and in the long run,
namely demographic factors. The model includes two financial variables,
namely stock market prices to capture the impact of equity prices on
house price via wealth effects caused by equity price variations or as
an investment alternative to real estate (Egert and Mihaljek, 2007), and
the rate of inflation as proxy for uncertainty as well as the real
depreciation of non-indexed financial assets (Poterba, 1984; Iossifov et
al., 2008). Finally, private residential investments have been included
to take the supply side into account. The error correction house price
specification is expressed as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
[[mu].sub.t] = [[mu].sub.t-1] + [[beta].sub.t-1] + [[eta].sub.t]
[[eta].sub.t] ~ NID(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[eta]]) (6)
[[beta].sub.t] = [[beta].sub.t-1] + [[xi].sub.t] [[xi].sub.t] ~
NID(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[xi]]) (7)
where hp is the country's real house price, y is real income
per capita, r denotes the real long-term interest rate, [pi] is the
inflation rate, share is the stock market price, pop is population
change, and gfcf refers to residential investments. [DELTA] is the
difference operator and ln is the logarithm. The latent component, [mu],
reflects different phenomena embedded in house prices' trends and
cycles, components that have a stochastic nature, [epsilon], [eta] and
[xi] are normally distributed random disturbances with means of zero and
a constant variance of [[sigma].sup.2]. As before, the lagged variables
in the levels represent the long-run equilibrium equation, whereas the
differenced variables define the short-run equilibrium. Data on house
prices (hp) were obtained from DataStream and the Bank of International
Settlements, which compiles data from national sources. The variable hp
was deflated by countries' consumer price index (CPI) so as to have
real value. There is a caveat: each country compiles house price figures
using different definitions; therefore, data are not always homogeneous
and strictly comparable. Some data refer, for instance, to the average
price for all types of dwellings, others to average price per square
meter, whereas still others are focused on whole countries or main
cities. A log of real per capita gross domestic product (GDP) has been
used as a proxy for wealth. The variable y is expected to be positively
related to house prices because income growth improves house
affordability. This generates more demand for living and recreation
space, which drives up the price of construction land. In addition, the
positive influence of income on house price could be caused by the
Baumol-Bowen effect and the Balassa-Samuelson effect. (3) Like other
asset prices, house prices are influenced by interest rates (r).
Specifically, real long-term interest rates are used as a proxy for the
cost of mortgage financing. (4) As houses are predominantly financed
with borrowing, a decline in real long-term interest rates translates
into a reduction in mortgage rates, thereby boosting liquidity, demand
for houses, and house prices. Put differently, changes in interest rates
are expected to be negatively linked to real house prices because higher
real mortgage rates increase the cost of homeownership and push prices
down. Expectations of higher inflation ([pi]) are likely to be
associated with higher demand for houses used as shelters against
inflation. This leads to soaring house prices. In other terms, on the
economic side, the inclusion of the rate of inflation reflects the fact
that houses serve as a store of purchasing power; therefore, if the
inflation rate increases, people are more prone to buy houses to hedge
again the risk that inflation may erode their wealth. Besides, higher
uncertainty about future expected returns on investment in bonds and
equities associated with high inflation also contribute to the
attractiveness of real estate as a vehicle for long-term savings. On the
econometric point of view, the issue of likely endogeneity is smoothed
by considering past values of the inflation rate. The inclusion of the
rate of inflation is in line with the studies by Zhu (2003), Tsatsaronis
and Zhu (2004), Iossifov et al. (2008). The inflation rate is computed
using changes in the CPI. Share price indices (share), normally based on
a selection of shares, represent share price movements in stock markets.
Share price indices generally relate to common shares of companies
traded on national or foreign stock exchanges, other manipulation, and
adjustments. The expected sign of the variable share is uncertain
because it depends on substitution and wealth effect and which of the
two prevails. The substitution effect predicts a negative relationship
between the price of two assets (eg equities and houses), as the high
return in one market tends to cause investors to leave the other market.
The wealth effect instead postulates a positive relation because the
high return in one market will increase the total wealth of investors
and their capability of investing in other assets (Koivu, 2012). The
demand for houses is also influenced by demographic changes, thereby the
population between 15-64 years old (pop) has been included. A higher
growth rate in the working age population is likely to be associated
with higher house demand and hence higher prices. Finally, to account
for supply side variables (5) (ie factors influencing the available
house stock), private residential investments (gfcf) in real terms have
been considered for all countries. The expected sign is negative as
prices lessen when residential supply increases. A detailed data
description is reported in the Appendix.
ESTIMATION OF HOUSE PRICES
Unit root tests As a preliminary step, the degree of integration of
the series involved has been computed. Two univariate unit root tests
were carried out, the augmented Dickey-Fuller test (1979) and the
Phillips-Perron test (1988). Table A3 (Appendix) reports the results
from the tests. Overall, the picture that emerges indicates that the
variables are integrated of order one (I(1)), that is, the series
becomes stationary after the first differences.
Structural model estimation
A number of specifications were estimated for real house prices.
(6) The analysis is based on quarterly data ranging from 1970:1 to
2010:2. (7) All estimations and test statistics were produced with the
econometric software STAMP 8 (Koopman et al., 2007), which maximizes
likelihood functions using the Kalman Filter, with diffuse initial
conditions. Specification of the components was based on the
series' salient features. Starting from the Basic Structural Model
(8), the variances of disturbances in the components were evaluated.
When a parameter was found to be equal to zero, its corresponding
component was fixed. When the slope and seasons of the series were
estimated to be not null, trends were modeled on a local linear level,
(9) and when the slope and seasons were found to be null, trends were
treated on a local level (Koopman et al., 2007). Interventions, in the
form of irregular and level (10) components, were introduced, where the
residuals of house prices revealed the presence of an outlier. To
explore the appropriateness of the stochastic specification, the model
was estimated into two different scenarios. The first is less restricted
and allows for a stochastic trend according to the state equations (6)
and (7); the second scenario corresponds to the conventional model, with
fixed dummies and a deterministic time trend. A report on these
estimations is presented in Table 2 and 3 and gives information about
the maximized value of the log-likelihood function, the convergence (ie
weak or strong) and the prediction error variance. In addition, Table 2
and 3 provide a set of diagnostic statistics for the estimated
residuals, which should satisfy three important properties:
independence, homoscedasticity and normality. The assumption that the
residuals are independent is checked using a classical Durbin Watson
test, which is distributed as N(2, 4/T) and the Ljung Box statistics
(11) O(P,d). The assumption that the residuals display homoscedasticity
is evaluated using the H(h) test which is distributed as a F(h,h) with
(h,h) degrees of freedom. (12) The normality of the residuals is tested
using the Doornik-Hansen correction to the Bowman-Shenton statistic.
(13) The baseline specification for each setting and for each country
has been chosen on the basis of its robustness and, thus, on the
minimization of the Akaike information criterion (AIC), Bayesian
information criterion (BIC), and error prediction. In the first setting
(Table 2), all of the estimated coefficients display the expected signs.
Diagnostic checking rejects the presence of serial correlation,
heteroskedasticity, and non-normality. The estimates show good
explanatory power for all countries, as highlighted by the [R.sup.2]
values. The correct specification of the model is shown by the low
values of the prediction error variance, that is, the variance of the
one-step-ahead prediction errors in the steady state, and by the ratio
of the prediction error variance and the mean deviation in squares,
which is close to 1. Finally, the model strongly converges to the steady
state, which is an indication of good results (Koopman et al., 2007). In
the second setting (deterministic trend), there are some problems of
autocorrelation in the residuals for France as testified by the
Ljung-Box statistics, and the coefficient of the inflation rate is not
significant for Italy (Table 3). The traditional model specification
displays a lower [R.sup.2] than the one with an unobserved component.
Besides, it appears that stochastic trends ameliorate the evaluation of
the real house price equations when compared with the deterministic
trend, on the basis of specification and misspecification tests and of
goodness-of-fit criteria. The components' graphics with stochastic
trend plus regression effects, in fact, more accurately explain real
house prices than a traditional deterministic trend plus regression
effects. (14) The long-run parameters for the baseline setting are given
in Table 4.
The results show that real house prices are positively driven by
per capita income, stock prices, population changes, and inflation. They
are negatively driven by interest rates and residential investments
(Table 4). More specifically, income, population and inflation rate are
the core long-run determinants among the observable factors in terms of
magnitude for the two groups of countries. The long-run per capita
income elasticity is bigger than the unity for the United Kingdom, the
United States, and Spain, and varies between 0.67 and 0.82 for the
remaining countries. According to IMF (2003), the high sensitivity of
real house prices to income is linked to high loan-to-value rates. In
addition, income elasticity larger than unity may mirror increased
access to credit following financial deregulation and a higher household
propensity to borrow. Countries that have more conservative financing
systems, that is, a smaller degree of financial sophistication such as
Germany and Italy, have lower income elasticity.
Population growth have a strong role in the United States, United
Kingdom, Spain, and the Netherlands, where a 1% increase results in
5.5%, 3.2% 2.2%, and 1.50% higher house price growth, respectively. The
highest values for the United States and the United Kingdom is likely
linked to the increasing growth rate in the working-age
population--including immigrants--recorded in these countries, which
boosted the demand for houses and, thus, prices.
A 1% increase in inflation rate, keeping constant other factors,
produces a rise in house price of 1.60% in the Netherlands, 1.97% in the
United Kingdom, 1.1% in the United States, 0.64% in France, 0.30% in
Spain, and 0.13 % in Germany and Italy. This implies that uncertainty
tends to make the portfolio of investors shift toward more traditional
investments. As regards real interest rate elasticity, it is significant
and exerts a dampening effect on house price. The magnitude differs
across countries, ranging from 0.003 in Spain to 0.28 in the United
States. The interest rate that determines the effective mortgage rate
thus has an impact on homebuyers' decisions. In any case, it turns
out that countries with a higher financial liberalization of mortgage
markets show a higher sensitivity of house prices to interest rates.
This result is in line with Muellbauer and Murphy (1997) and Iacovello
and Minetti (2003}.
The stock market variable is positively related to real house
prices, suggesting that the wealth effect dominates the substitution
effect during the sample period. This finding corroborates the results
by Sutton (2002} and Borio and McGuire (2004). The stock market has a
much bigger role in the Netherlands, the United States, and the United
Kingdom than in Germany, France, and Italy. Moreover, the results show
that price reacts less than proportionately to changes in supply (ie the
elasticity is smaller than one} for all countries. Put differently,
higher residential investments make house supply shift outward, leading
to lower house prices. Interestingly, Germany has the highest
residential investment value, with falling real house prices. This is in
line with the study by ECB (2003).
The stochastic trends, which indicate the general direction in
which the series are moving, have long-run elasticity greater than one
for all the countries considered; their value is greatest in the United
States and the Netherlands. This implies the presence of substantial
unobserved long-run effects, which are effectively captured by the
stochastic trend (Table 4). The stochastic trend encompasses all the
unobserved factors that affect real house prices but cannot be directly
measured or are simply overlooked. Such latent factors can include
consumer preferences, structural changes, and local market specificities
difficult to quantify. Table 2 provides further information on the
trend's components. Specifically, the extent to which the
trend's components evolve over time is specified by the parameters
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.[eta]] and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[xi]], which have been
estimated by the maximum likelihood in the time domain. Table 2 reports
the estimated standard deviations and the signal-to-noise ratio of the
residuals driving the unobserved components. When the signal-to-noise
ratio is not zero, the permanent component is stochastic. If the
signal-to-noise ratio were equal to zero, the time series model that
represents a decomposition into permanent-plus-transient components
would have contained a deterministic trend. Moreover, as the proportion
that is not explained by the model, that is, the transitory noise, is
minimized, the model is well specified. It is worthwhile noting that
house prices are modeled differently across countries. For instance, for
the United States the specification with the best fit consists of a
stochastic trend and a fixed slope. For the Netherlands, Spain and the
United Kingdom the specifications present a stochastic trend and a
stochastic slope. For France and Italy the local linear model shows a
somewhat smoother trend, being the trend fixed and the level stochastic.
For Germany the finest specification consists of a deterministic trend,
likely because of the smooth house price patterns. The trend's
contribution to the annual rate of increase in house prices within the
sample is positive for all the countries considered, with the exception
of Germany, where the trend reduces house prices by 0.7% per year. A
negative time trend indicates secular declines in house prices, as
confirmed by Figure 1, which shows that Germany's property prices
performed unimpressively from the mid-1990s to the mid-2000s, when most
European countries were experiencing house booms. Among the economies in
which there was an underlying trend improvement in real house prices,
the largest effect at the end of each year can be seen in France, Italy,
Spain and the United Kingdom. The values for these countries would
explain the large price increases observed there. In a nutshell, the
estimated values of the slope parameter indicates that at steady state,
the median price appreciated by 5.50% a year in real terms in France,
3.13% in Spain, 3.43% in Italy, 2.65% in the United Kingdom, 1.73 % in
the Netherlands, and 1.18 % in the United States.
The cycle component has a global feature and is relevant to all
countries, with the strongest role in the United States, followed by
France and Spain. Except for Italy and France, the results also reveal
changes in the seasonal patterns with house prices generally being
higher in the second and third quarter compared with their values in the
first and fourth quarter of a year. This result supports the findings of
other studies on seasonality in house price (Kajuth and Schmidt, 2011;
Ngai and Tenreyro, 2009; Hosios and Pesando, 1992; Case and Shiller,
1989).
CONCLUSIONS
Real house prices in many industrial countries have soared
extraordinarily rapidly in recent years, and in some cases these
upsurges do not seem to be fully explained by economic fundamentals. For
this reason, the present article has extended the analysis to include
underlying factors that drive real house price fluctuations into two
groups of advanced economies: the main five Euro area countries, and the
big two Anglo-Saxon countries. Although previous studies have considered
long-run interest rates and per capita income as the main determinants
of price behavior, this article introduces a hidden factor and
constructs an unobserved component approach to modeling house price
equations. The methodology adopted enables observers of house markets to
pick up on underlying changes in real house prices after controlling for
the impact of interest rates, income, inflation, population growth,
residential investments, and stock prices. If latent information is, in
fact, overlooked, long-run price equations may be misspecified, and
spurious regressions may occur. The adopted approach overcomes any
misspecification by proxying any long-run variations with a latent
component in the form of a time-varying trend.
Differently from the mainstream approach, based on the unit root
tests and estimating cointegrating equations using deterministic trends,
this study has treated trends as a stochastic variable because of the
effects of several unobservable shocks to the economy.
Subject to the usual caveats concerning the comparability of house
price data across countries, the model shows how significant time
stochastic trends are when explaining the performance of real house
prices.
Indeed, the elasticity of the estimated stochastic trends is well
above the unity, showing how this effectively captures the changes that
occurred in recent years in the Euro area, the United Kingdom and the
United States. The only exception is Germany. As the variances of the
disturbances of the level and slope of trend were found to be equal to
zero, the structural time series model implies that a deterministic
trend is preferable to a stochastic trend. This finding likely mirrors
the smooth pattern in the country's house prices. In addition, the
econometric results confirm that real house prices in industrial
countries show dependence on economic fundamentals and underlying
factors. The latter are more relevant for the United Kingdom, Italy,
France, and Spain. The cycle component has the utmost role in the United
States.
Furthermore, the investigation reveals that there are some common
elements to the two groups of countries, namely the following: 1) the
estimated per capita income elasticity and population changes in the set
of real house price equations generally represent the main observed
fundamentals to influence real house price patterns; 2) the stock market
variable drives up real house prices, suggesting that the wealth effect
dominates the substitution effect; 3) overheating is associated with
sustained growth of inflation-adjusted real house price--this result
points to the fact that a house could be a shelter for investment when
other financial instruments present risky prospect in the long run; 4)
the stochastic trends are all above the unity. The two groups of
countries have some different features, specifically: 1) the intensity
of income elasticity is larger in the Anglo-Saxon economies than in the
Euro group, except for Spain (this is the result of less financial
sophistication within the Euro zone); 2) the equity market has a
stronger role in the United Kingdom and United States than in the Euro
Area country, except for the Netherlands.
The results of this analysis suggest that it remains crucial for
regulators to carefully monitor the house price market, given its impact
on the economic activities. To this purpose, it seems important, first
of all, to develop better data collection systems across countries and
to harmonize the systems, especially in the Euro zone. This will be
important to have a better knowledge on the state of the house market.
Then, given the swings in house prices, in the medium term, policies
should aim at forestalling boom and bust cycles. This could be reached
by proper (prudent) fiscal policies--which affect house prices largely
through taxes and subsides--and structural policies, which can
substantially impact on the supply side of the market. In particular,
gradual changes in house taxation, especially when they are announced in
advance, can help to avoid abrupt price movements. Maintaining a prudent
fiscal stance could help prevent domestic demand pressures that would
otherwise contribute to driving the house market away from its
equilibrium. This is especially important for the Anglo-Saxon economies
and Spain, given their high price response to income changes. Structural
policies that affect the constructing industry and building zoning
regulations should aim at mitigating excessive supply rigidities in
order to lessen sharp price increases. This should be accomplished in
the respect of environmental criteria. In addition, monetary policy
interventions should be foreseen in the house market. In this respect,
it seems important for the Central Banks to add to their specific goals
the objective of smoothing excessive asset price fluctuations. This is
because the primary objective of the ECB's monetary policy is to
achieve and maintain general price stability in the Euro Area, that is,
to keep inflation rates below--but close to--2 % over the medium term.
The Federal Reserve has a twofold target: economic growth (including
maximum employment) and stable prices, but the top priority is growth.
The objective of the monetary policy adopted by the Bank of England is
'to deliver price stability--low inflation--and, subject to that,
to support the Government's economic objectives including those for
growth and employment'. Therefore, the inclusions of the price of
houses and shares as explicit targets would be auspicious. This would
also imply an effective supervision of the mortgage banking systems in
order to restrain the vulnerabilities in the house market.
APPENDIX
Table A1: Data
Series going from 1970:1 Source and construction
to 2010:2
Real house price indices Data were collected from the Bank of
CPI deflated (2005=100) International Settlements (BIS) and
Thompson DataStream.
For the United States, quarterly data were
obtained from the BIS (code
Q:US:0:2:1:3:0:0) and refer to the
existing single-family houses index, not
seasonally adjusted, for the whole
country. For the United Kingdom, data were
taken from the Thomson DataStream (code
UKNSAQHPF). The house price index is
calculated as a weighted average of prices
for a standard mix of dwellings. For
France, data were obtained from the BIS
(code Q:FR:2:8:1:1:0:0). House prices
refer to existing flats (Capital City)
Index. For the Netherlands, data were
collected from Nederlandse Vereniging voor
Makelaars http://nieuws.nvm.nl///media/
NVMWebsite/Downloads/OverNVM/English/
Sale%20prices%20in%20the%20Netherlands%
201985-present.ashx. House price index
refers to all types of dwellings.
For Spain, quarterly data were obtained
from the BIS (code Q:ES:0:1:0:1:1:0).
House prices refer to all types of
dwellings, throughout the country.
For Italy, the real house price index
denotes all type of dwellings. Data were
taken from Scenari immobiliari and
transformed into quarterly series using
the moving average procedure.
For Germany, the real house price index
refers to the BD real estate price index
NSA. Data were taken from Thomson
DataStream and transformed into quarterly
series using the moving average procedure.
To counter check the last part of the
series, quarterly data from Statistische
Bundesamt Deutschland were considered.
http://www/destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/
cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/Content/
Statistics/TimeSeries/EconomicIndicators/
Prices/Content100/bpr110a,templateID=
renderPrint.psml
Where necessary, data were seasonally
adjusted.
Real interest rates Nominal long-term interest rates were
collected from Thompson Datastream. Codes
FROCFILTR, ITOCFILTR BDOCFILTR ESOCFILTR
NLOCFILTR UKOCFILTR USOCFILTR. Nominal
interest rates were adjusted to remove the
effects of inflation and reflect the real
cost of funds to the borrower.
Consumer price indices Consumer price indices, based on 2005=100,
were taken from the IMF's International
Financial Statistics http://www.imf.
org/external/ data.htm
Real per capita GDP index GDP, at constant purchasing power parity
2005 in US$ millions, was divided by population
and indexed (2005=100).Source: DataStream.
Codes FROCFGVOD ITOCFGVOD BDOCFGVOD
ESOCFGVOD NLOCFGVOD UKOCFGVOD USOCFGVOD
Share price indices Data were collected from Eurostat and the
(average) 2005 = 100 IMF's International Financial Statistics
via DataStream. For France, the SBF250
index of the Societe des Bourses
Francaises was considered. The index
covers the common shares of the 40
enterprises with the Largest
capitalization. For Germany, data refer to
the Deutscher Aktienindex. For Italy, data
refer to the MIB index calculated by the
Milan Stock Exchange and are based on the
quoted prices of all stocks traded on that
exchange. For the Netherlands, the AEX All
Shares Index was considered. It covers all
listed companies in the Amsterdam Stock
Exchange, excluding investment funds and
foreign-registered companies. For Spain,
the General Index of the Botsa de Madrid
was considered. It covers the shares of
more than 100 companies representing some
85% of total market capitalization. For
the United Kingdom, data refer to the
average of daily quotations of 500
ordinary Industrial shares on the London
Stock Exchange. For the United States, the
price-weighted monthly averages of 30 blue
chip stocks quoted in the Dow Jones
Industrial Average were considered.
Gross fixed capital DataStream codes FROCFIHSD, ITOCFIHSD,
formation--Private NLOCFIHSD, UKOCFIHSD, USOCFIHSD, ESOCFIHSD
Residential (real term) BDOCFIHSD.
Population growth index
2005 = 100 DataStream codes FROCFPOPO, ITOCFPOPO,
ESOCFPOPO, NLOCFPOPO, UKOCFPOPO,
USOCFPOPO, BDOCFPOPO
Table A2: Selected literature survey on determinants of real house
prices in industrialized countries
Investigator Country, data and Methodology
period
Annett (2005) Euro Area (8 countries) ECM
yearly 1970-2003
Ayuso et al. (2006) Spain yearly 1978-2002 ECM
Bessone et al. France yearly 1986-2004 Johansen ML
(2005)
Fitzpatrick and Ireland yearly Stock and Watson DOLS,
McQuinn (2004) 1981-1999 FM-OLS, OLS
Gattini and 9 countries quarterly VECM
Hiebert (2010) 1970Q1-2009Q4
Hofman (2005) The Netherlands ECM
quarterly 1974Q1-2003Q3
Hilbers et al. 16 countries Panel MGE analysis
(2008) (dependent variable
price-rental ratio)
Hunt and Badia UK quarterly VAR
(2005) 1972Q4-2004Q4
Iossifov et al. Two samples: (a) 17 (a) 3SLS variables in
(2008) advanced economies 1st differences (b)
quarterly cross section OLS in
199004-2006Q4; levels
(b) 89 countries
annual 2005-2006
Klyuev, (2008) US two frequency (a) Supply-demand OLS
samples approach (b) asset
(a) annual data price approach using
1976-2002 Stock and Watson
(b) quarterly dynamic OLS
(i) 197201-200841 and
(ii) 197201-200204
McCarthy and Peach US quarterly Johansen ML
(2004) 1981Q1-2003Q3
Meen (2002) UK quarterly ECM
1969Q3-1996Q1;
USA 1981Q3-1998Q2
OECD (2005) Ireland 1977Q1-2004Q4; ECM
the Netherlands
1970-2002; Spain
1989-2003
Schnure (2005) USA yearly 1978-2004 Panel analysis
Sutton (2002) 6 industrialized VAR
countries
Terrones and Otrok 18 countries yearly Dynamic panel analysis
(2004) 1971-2003
Verbruggen et al. The Netherlands yearly ECM
(2005) 1980-2003
Wagner (2005) Denmark 1993-2004 ECM
Investigator Long-run real Explanatory variables
income elasticity Long-run real interest
rate elasticity
Annett (2005) 0.7 -0.02
Ayuso et al. (2006) 2.8 Value not significant
in nominal term
Bessone et al. 8.3 --
(2005)
Fitzpatrick and -- --
McQuinn (2004)
Gattini and 3.07 -6.87 mixed interest
Hiebert (2010) rate short and long
Hofman (2005) 1.5 -0.9
Hilbers et al. 1.02 fast lane; 0.51
(2008) average performers;
-0.76 slow movers;
Panel: 0.38
Hunt and Badia 1.9 in 199904 and -6.0
(2005) 1.5 in 200404
Iossifov et al. (a)-(b) 0.28 (a) -0.24 (nominal
(2008) short-term value)
(b) -0.36 (real
short-term value)
Klyuev, (2008) (a) 0.5 (b)- (a) Real mortgage
rate -0.009-
(b) (i) -0.04 and
(ii) -0.02
McCarthy and Peach 3.2 --
(2004)
Meen (2002) United Kingdom 2.5 United Kingdom -0.035
United States 2.7 United States -0.013
OECD (2005) Ireland 1.8; Ireland -1.9;
the Netherlands 1.9; the Netherlands -7.1;
ES 3.3 to 4.1 ES -0.6 to -4.5
Schnure (2005) 0.2-0.3 short -0.21 to -0.28
run rate short run rate
Sutton (2002) GNI from 1.0-4.0 From -0.5 to-1.5
Terrones and Otrok 1.1 -1.0
(2004)
Verbruggen et al. 1.33 -5.9
(2005)
Wagner (2005) -- -7.7
Investigator Other independent
variables
Annett (2005) Real credit 0.2
Ayuso et al. (2006) Stock market return -0.3
Bessone et al. House stock supply -3.6
(2005)
Fitzpatrick and House stock -1.2; population
McQuinn (2004) 24-36 2.0; mortgage 1.3
Gattini and Real house investment -2.2
Hiebert (2010)
Hofman (2005) --
Hilbers et al. Demographic pressure -11.3
(2008) (fast lane), -6.1 (average
performers), -5.05 (slow
movers); user costs -0.49
(fast lane), -0.72 (average
performers), -1.12 (slow
movers); Panel: demographic
pressure -7.74, user costs -0.73
Hunt and Badia --
(2005)
Iossifov et al. (a) Inflation proxy for mortgage
(2008) debt -0.31; M2 proxy for
financial deepening 0.14;
government budget balance 0.7
(b) availability of credit 0.44
Klyuev, (2008) (a) Real construction cost 0.77;
unemployment not significant;
average house size not
significant; (b) real rent
(i) 1.27 and (ii) 0.74
McCarthy and Peach House stock supply -3.2
(2004)
Meen (2002) UK house stock supply -1.9;
UK real wealth 0.33; US house
stock supply -7.9; US real
wealth 0.7
OECD (2005) Ireland house stock/population
-0.007; NL house stock/
population -0.52; ES house
stock/population -6.9 to
-8.1; ES population 12 to 16.9
Schnure (2005) Unemployment -0.9 to -1.2;
labor force 0.4 to 1.8 (short run)
Sutton (2002) Stock prices from 1.0-5.0
Terrones and Otrok Population growth 0.25;
(2004) house affordability -0.14
Verbruggen et al. House stock supply -1.4
(2005)
Wagner (2005) House stock supply -2.9;
demography 2.9
Source: Own elaborations
Table A3: Unit root tests
hp y
level 1st differ level 1st differ
Prob (a).
(a) Adjusted Dickey Fuller
France 0.4308 0.0380 0.6320 0.0000
Germany 0.3083 0.0214 0.9988 0.0018
Italy 0.0964 0.0081 0.4312 0.0000
The Netherlands 0.9397 0.0302 0.9797 0.0000
Spain 0.8835 0.0113 0.7914 0.0007
United Kingdom 0.9024 0.0224 0.9153 0.0000
United States 0.1897 0.0319 0.9386 0.0000
Null Hypothesis: the variable has a unit root I(1). Lag
Length: Automatic-based on HQ, maxlag=13. The test is
carried out with a constant.
(b) Phillip-Perron
France 0.9999 0.0000 0.5214 0.0000
Germany 0.8421 0.0214 0.9999 0.0170
Italy 0.2192 0.0035 0.3527 0.0000
The Netherlands 0.9831 0.0000 0.9751 0.0000
Spain 0.9865 0.0001 0.8376 0.0000
United Kingdom 0.9353 0.0000 0.8907 0.0000
United States 0.7379 0.0000 0.9548 0.0000
r gfcf
level 1st differ level 1st differ
Prob (a).
(a) Adjusted Dickey Fuller
France 0.5349 0.0000 0.4953 0.0003
Germany 0.5268 0.0091 0.3156 0.0000
Italy 0.5532 0.0017 0.6435 0.0000
The Netherlands 0.4648 0.0000 0.4052 0.0000
Spain 0.7674 0.0055 0.4477 0.0029
United Kingdom 0.9477 0.0000 0.4180 0.0000
United States 0.6206 0.0000 0.1672 0.0000
Null Hypothesis: the variable has a unit root I(1). Lag
Length: Automatic-based on HQ, maxlag=13. The test is
carried out with a constant.
(b) Phillip-Perron
France 0.0693 0.0000 0.3993 0.0000
Germany 0.4556 0.0001 0.3156 0.0000
Italy 0.2930 0.0000 0.5431 0.0000
The Netherlands 0.1544 0.0000 0.1518 0.0000
Spain 0.8117 0.0000 0.6581 0.0000
United Kingdom 0.3181 0.0000 0.3572 0.0000
United States 0.2887 0.0000 0.3215 0.0000
pop share
level 1st differ level 1st differ
Prob (a).
(a) Adjusted Dickey Fuller
France 0.2065 0.0271 0.5927 0.0000
Germany 0.7071 0.0000 0.5523 0.0000
Italy 0.1821 0.0014 0.5346 0.0000
The Netherlands 0.8088 0.0026 0.6142 0.0000
Spain 0.3539 0.0000 0.8213 0.0000
United Kingdom 0.4899 0.0141 0.8625 0.0000
United States 0.1903 0.0000 0.8626 0.0000
Null Hypothesis: the variable has a unit root I(1). Lag
Length: Automatic-based on HQ, maxlag=13. The test is
carried out with a constant.
(b) Phillip-Perron
France 0.3987 0.0001 0.6460 0.0000
Germany 0.7541 0.0000 0.6125 0.0000
Italy 0.0508 0.0000 0.5700 0.0000
The Netherlands 0.7274 0.0000 0.6092 0.0000
Spain 0.5468 0.0000 0.8500 0.0000
United Kingdom 0.8079 0.0000 0.9065 0.0000
United States 0.2271 0.0001 0.9065 0.0000
cpi
level 1st differ
Prob (a).
(a) Adjusted Dickey Fuller
France 0.3877 0.0012
Germany 0.9515 0.0000
Italy 0.3988 0.0000
The Netherlands 0.4460 0.0803
Spain 0.5298 0.0000
United Kingdom 0.8277 0.0177
United States 0.7856 0.0029
Null Hypothesis: the variable has a
unit root I(1). Lag Length:
Automatic--based on HQ, maxlag=13.
The test is carried out with a
constant.
(b) Phillip-Perron
France 0.3858 0.0000
Germany 0.0879 0.0000
Italy 0.9458 0.0000
The Netherlands 0.5084 0.0000
Spain 0.9943 0.0000
United Kingdom 0.9857 0.0000
United States 0.9744 0.0000
Null hypothesis: The variable has a unit root I(1).
Bandwidth: Newey-West automatic using Bartlett kernel.
The test is carried out with a constant.
(a) MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Acknowledgements
I am grateful to the Editor of this Journal Josef Brada, Prof.
Antonio Aquino, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments and
suggestions. Financial assistance from the Region Calabria, Italy
(Scientific Research Program CALCOM on 'Regional Competitiveness
and Innovation') is gratefully acknowledged.
REFERENCES
Ahearne, AG, Ammer, J, Doyle, BM, Kole, LS and Martin, RF. 2005:
House prices and monetary policy: A cross-country study. International
Finance Discussion paper 841, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, Washington DC.
Almeida, H, Campello, M and Liu, C. 2006: The financial
accelerator: Evidence from international housing markets. Review of
Finance 10(3): 1-32.
Annett, A. 2005: House prices and monetary policy in the EURO area.
In: Euro Area policies: Selected issues. IMF country report no. 05/266,
International Monetary Fund: Washington DC, pp. 62-86.
Ayuso, J, Martinez, J, Maza, L and Restoy, F. 2003: House prices in
Spain. Economic Bulletin, October, Banco de Espana: Madrid.
Ayuso, J, Blanco, R and Restoy, F. 2006: House prices and real
interest rates in Spain. Banco de Espana Documentos Ocasionales. No.
0608.
Balassa, B. 1964: The purchasing power parity: A reappraisal.
Journal of Political Economy 72(6): 584-596.
Banco de Espana. 2003: Analysis of House Prices in Spain. Jorge
Martinez Pages and Luis Angel Maza Documento de Trabajo no. 0307.
Baumol, WJ and Bowen, WG. 1966: Performing Arts: The Economic
Dilemma. The Twentieth Century Fund: New York.
Bessone, AJ, Heitz, B and Boissinot, J. 2005: Marche immobilier:
voit-on une bulle? Note de Conjoncture, INSEE: Mars, Paris.
Borio, C and McGuire, P. 2004: Twin peaks in equity and housing
prices? BIS quarterly review, March, available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1491070, accessed
January 2013.
Case, K and Shiller, R. 1989: The efficiency of the market for
single-family homes. American Economic Review 79(1): 125-237.
Chen, X and MacDonald, R. 2010: Revisiting the dollar-euro
permanent equilibrium exchange rate: Evidence from multivariate
unobserved components models. SIRE Discussion paper 41, University of
Glasgow: Scotland.
Coudert, V. 2004: Measuring the Balassa-Samuelson effect for the
countries of Central and Eastern Europe? Banque De France Bulletin
Digest No. 122, February.
Davis, EP and Zhu, H. 2004: Bank lending and commercial property
prices: some cross country evidence. BIS Working paper no. 150.
Deutsche Bank. 2010: House markets in OECD countries. Deutsche Bank
Research, Issue 3 March, www.dbresearch.com.
Dickey, DA and Fuller, WA. 1979: Distribution of the estimators for
autoregressive time series with a unit root. Journal of the American
Statistical Association 74(366): 427-431.
ECB. 2003: Structural Factors in the EU House Markets. ECB:
Frankfurt am Mein.
Egert, B and Mihaljek, D. 2007: Determinants of house prices in
central and eastern Europe. Comparative Economic Studies 49(3): 367-388.
Fitzpatrick, T and McQuinn, K. 2004: House prices and mortgage
credit: Empirical evidence for Ireland. Research technical paper no.
5/RT/04, Central Bank and Financial Services Authority of Ireland:
Dublin.
Gattini, L and Hiebert, P. 2010: Forecasting and assessing Euro
area house prices through the lens of key fundamentals. ECB Working
paper no. 1249, European Central Bank: Frankfurt am Main, Germany,
October.
Girouard, N, Kennedy, M, van den Noord, P and Andre, C. 2006:
Recent house price. Developments: The role of fundamentals. Economics
Department Working paper no. 475, OECD.
Harvey, AC. 1989: Forecasting, Structural Time Series Models and
the Kalman Filter. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK.
Harvey, AC and Shephard, N. 1993: Structural Time Series Models.
In: Maddala, GS, Rao, CR and Vinod, HD (eds). Handbook of Statistics,
Vol. 11, Elsevier Science Publishers: Amsterdam, pp. 261-502.
Harvey, AC. 1997: Trends, cycles and autoregression. The Economic
Journal 107(440): 192-201.
Harvey, AC and Scott, A. 1994: Seasonality in dynamic regression
models. Economic Journal 104(427): 1324-1345.
Hilbers, P, Hoffmaister, AW, Banerji, A and Shi, H. 2008: House
price developments in Europe: A comparison. IMF Working paper no. 211,
International Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
Hilbers, P, Lei, Q and Zacho, SL. 2001: Real estate market
developments and financial sector soundness. IMF Working paper no. 129,
International Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
Hofman, D. 2005: Kingdom of the Netherlands, Netherlands: Selected
issues. IMF country report no. 05/225, International Monetary Fund:
Washington DC.
Hosios, AJ and Pesando, JE. 1992: Measuring prices in resale house
markets in Canada: Evidence and implications. Journal of House Economics
1(4): 303-317.
Hunt, B and Badia, M. 2005: United Kingdom: Selected issues. IMF
country report no. 05/81, International Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
IMF. 2003: An Analysis of House Prices in the United Kingdom, in
United Kingdom: Selected Issues. IMF: Washington DC.
IMF. 2009: Spain: Selected issues. IMF country report no. 09/129,
International Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
Iacovello, M and Minetti, R. 2003: Financial liberalization and the
sensitivity of house prices to monetary policy: Theory and evidence. The
Manchester School 71(1): 20-34.
Iossifov, P, Cihak, M and Shangavi, A. 2008: Interest Rate
Elasticity of Residential House Prices. IMF Working paper WP/08/247,
International Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
Kajuth, F and Schmidt, T. 2011: Seasonality in house prices.
Deutsch Bundesbank: Frankfurt am Main, Germany, DP 8/11.
Klyuev, V. 2008: What goes up must come down? House price dynamics
in the United States. IMF Working paper WP/08/187, International
Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
Kholodilin, KA, Menz, JO and Siliverstovs, B. 2010: What drives
house prices down? Evidence from an international panel. Jahrbucher fur
Nationalokonomie und Statistik 230(1): 59-76.
Koivu, T. 2012: Monetary policy, asset prices and consumption in
China. Economic Systems 36(2): 307-325.
Koopman, SJ, Harvey, AC, Doornik, JA and Shephard, N. 2007: STAMP
8.0 Structural Time Series Analysis Modeller and Predictor. Timberlake
Consultants Ltd.: London.
Loungani, P. 2010: House prices: More room to fall. Finance &
Development. International Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
McCarthy, J and Peach, R. 2004: Are home prices the next bubble?
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 10(3): 1-17.
Meen, G. 2002: The time-series behaviour of house prices: A
transatlantic divide. Journal of House Economics 11(1): 1-23.
Muellbauer, J and Murphy, A. 1997: Booms and busts in the UK
housing market. Economic Journal 107(445): 1701-1727.
Nyblom, J and Harvey, AC. 2000: Tests of common stochastic trends.
Econometric Theory 16(02): 176-199.
Ngai, RL and Tenreyro, S. 2009: Hot and cold seasons in house
markets. CEP Discussion paper 922, Center for Economic Performance,
London School of Economics and Political Science: London.
OECD. 2004: Housing markets, wealth and the business cycle.
Economic Outlook, Vol. 75, June, OECD: Paris and Washington DC.
OECD. 2005: Recent house price developments: The role of
fundamentals. Economic Outlook, Vol. 78, December, OECD: Paris and
Washington DC.
Phillips, PCB and Perron, P. 1988: Testing for a unit root in time
series regressions. Biometrika 75(2): 335-346.
Poterba, JM. 1984: Tax subsidies to owner-occupied house: An
asset-market approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99(4): 729-752.
Samuelson, P. 1964: Theoretical notes on trade problems. The Review
of Economic and Statistics 46(2): 145-154.
Schnure, C. 2005: Boom-bast cycles in house: The changing role of
financial structure. IMF Working paper no. 05/200, International
Monetary Fund: Washington DC.
Sutton, GD. 2002: Explaining changes in house prices. BIS quarterly
review, Bank for International Settlements: Basel, Switzerland,
September, pp 46-55.
Terrones, M and Otrok, C. 2004: The global house price boom. IMF
World Economic Outlook, September, International Monetary Fund:
Washington DC.
The Economist. 2008-2012: Special report: The world economy,
http://www.economist.com/ printedition/2008-10-11-0, accessed June 2012.
Tsatsaronis, K and Zhu, H. 2004: What drives house price dynamics:
Cross country evidence. BIS Quarterly Review, March, Bank for
International Settlements: Basel.
Verbruggen, J, Kranendonk, H, van Leuvensteijn, M and Toet, M.
2005: Welke factoren bepalen de ontwikkeIing van de huizenprijs in
Nederland? CPB Document 81, April.
Wagner, R. 2005: En model for de danske ejerbohgpriser. Okonomog
Erhvervsministeriets arbejdspapir, Vol. 1.
Westerheide, P. 2010: House market stability, house market
characteristics and savings decisions: A German spotlight. In: Hypostat
IEMF, A Review of Europe's Mortgage and House Markets, European
Mortgage Federation: Brussels Belgium.
Zhu, H. 2003: The importance of property markets for monetary
policy and financial stability. Working paper no. 21, Bank for
International Settlements: Basel, Switzerland.
(1) For many countries, house activities, including construction,
renovation and bank and trading services, are estimated to be between 5%
and 10% of CDP (Hilbers et al., 2008).
(2) In Spain, for instance, the average time between building
permit and house completion is around 2 years (IMF, 2009).
(3) The Baumol-Bowen effect (1966) and the Balassa-Samuelson effect
(1964, 1964) are closely related but distinct from each other. The main
idea behind the Balassa-Samuelson effect is that, in a given economy, a
higher productivity growth in the tradable sector than that in the
non-tradable boosts up wages in all sectors. This in turn increases the
prices of non-traded goods relative to the prices of traded goods. The
Balassa-Samuelson effect is purely a 'supply side effect';
demand does not have any role in the formation of relative prices,
whereas the Baumol-Bowen effect provides an explanation for the rise in
relative prices of non-tradable goods by introducing the consumer demand
(Coudert, 2004}. As the income elasticity of the demand for services is
greater than that of the demand for goods, the share of services in
total demand increases during the process of development. Thus, the rise
in the relative prices of services derives not only from smaller
productivity increases, as the Balassa-Samuelson effect predicts, but
also from growing demand during the development process.
(4) Data on loan-to-value ratio, mortgages, and household credit
growth are not available for all the considered countries. In addition,
the series do not always go back to 1980 and sometimes they are not
available on quarterly frequency.
(5) Data on house starts and construction costs were not considered
because the series were not available for all the countries and the
entire period of the analysis.
(6) An advantage of the unobserved component model is that it does
not need the real house price to be cointegrated with macroeconomic
fundamentals as a prerequisite to obtain non-spurious long-run
relationships and estimates of the price equation. The approach
facilitates the estimation of the long-run relationship between the
integrated variables using maximum likelihood, and the use of the
likelihood ratio test to identify the significance of the long-run
coefficients, even if cointegration is rejected. If the standard
deviation of the innovation to the random walk process is approximately
zero, the unobserved random walk component will reduce to a constant and
the real house price is said to be cointegrated with the fundamentals
(Chen and MacDonald, 2010; Nyblom and Harvey, 2000).
(7) As many series for Germany starts from 1991, the sample period
goes from 1991:1 to 2010:2.
(8) [hp.sub.t] = [[mu].sub.t] + [[gamma].sub.t] + [[PSI].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t] where [[mu].sub.t] is the trend level, [[PSI].sub.t]
is the stochastic cycle, [[gamma].sub.t] is the stochastic season and
[[epsilon].sub.t] is the irregular.
(9) This is, in fact, reflected in the non-zero estimates of the
trend level and slope in the final state vector.
(10) Level interventions accommodate permanent step shifts in the
series; they resemble structural breaks.
(11) The latter is based on the sum of the first P autocorrelations
and is tested against a [chi square] distribution with d degrees of
freedom. The null hypothesis of no autocorrelation is tested against the
alternative of autocorrelation. The critical value for eight degrees of
freedom is 15.51 at a significance of 5 %.
(12) Under the null of no heteroskedasticity and for h = 33-36, the
5 % critical value is 1.75; for h = 37-41, the 5% critical value is
1.70. For h = 42-47, the 5% critical value is 1.64.
(13) The Bowman-Shenton statistic has a [chi square] distribution
with two degrees of freedom under the null hypothesis of normally
distributed errors. The null is rejected if the calculated probability
exceeds the tabulated probabilities that are equal to 5.99 at a
significance of 5% and 9.21 at a significance of 1%.
(14) Graphical presentations of these results have been reported
for reasons of space, but they are available upon request.
BERNARDINA ALGIERI
Department of Economics and Statistics, University of Calabria,
87036 Ponte P. Bucci, Cosenza, Italy.
E-mail: b.algieri@unical.it
Table 1: Real house prices. Year-on-year percentage change. Average
for the period
United United Germany France Italy
States Kingdom (DE)
1970-1980 2.29 4.60 1.39 2.68 4.50
1981-1990 0.80 5.01 -0.85 0.74 2.88
1991-2000 1.17 1.39 -0.17 0.26 -1.57
2001-2007 5.63 8.85 -2.50 9.10 5.95
2008-2010 -5.33 -0.51 0.05 -0.38 -0.82
Spain Netherlands
(ES)
1970-1980 2.07 4.37
1981-1990 7.01 -0.55
1991-2000 -0.03 7.20
2001-2007 9.84 3.07
2008-2010 -3.53 -0.80
Source: Elaborations on Bank for International Settlements
Table 2: House price equations estimated (a) with stochastic components
1970:4-2010:2 France Germany
1991:1-2010:2
Fundamental part (b)
Lagged house price -0.58 (0.06) -0.18 (0.05)
Lagged per capita income 0.47 (0.15) 0.12 (0.06)
Lagged real long-run interest rate -0.008 (0.003) -0.001 (0.0003)
Lagged inflation 0.37 (0.16) 0.024 (0.01)
Lagged share prices 0.016 (0.01) 0.005 (0.002)
Lagged change in population 0.26 (0.14) 0.13 (0.08)
Lagged residential investment -0.13 (0.07) -0.09 (0.03)
Differenced per capita income 0.01 (0.12) 0.04 (0.08)
Differenced real long-run interest -0.003 (0.08)
rate
Differenced inflation 0.027 (0.01)
Differenced share prices 0.01 (0.008)
Differenced change in population 0.01 (0.00) 0.09 (0.05)
Differenced change in residential
investment
Trend decomposition, standard
deviations of disturbances
([10.sup.2])
[[sigma].sub.n] Trend 0.000 0.000
Slope 0.295 0.000
Seasonal 0.000 0.000
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] Irregular 0.498 0.137
Cycle 0.280 0.000
Level q ratio 0.000
Slope q ratio 0.593 0.000
Seasonal q ratio 0.000 0.000
Irregular q ratio 1 1
Cycle q ratio 0.562
Dumping factor 0.92
Growth rate per year 5.50% -0.70%
Residuals tests (c)
Standard error ([10.sup.2]) 0.9 0.1
Normality 5.01 3.66
H(h) 1.44 H(46) 0.33 H(20)
r(1) ([10.sup.2]) -0.3 2.5
r(q) ([10.sup.2]) -0.5 -4.6
DW 2.01 1.94
Q(q,q-p) 10.8 13.4
Rd^2([10.sup.2]) 66.3 55.6
Goodness-of-fit results for
residuals (d)
Prediction error variance (p.e.v.) 0.0000849 0.000021
Ratio p.e.v./[(prediction error 1.14 1.40
mean deviation).sup.2]
AIC -9.12 -12.57
Convergence Very strong Very strong
Stability Yes Yes
1970:4-2010:2 Italy Netherlands
Fundamental part (b)
Lagged house price -0.98 (0.04) -0.20 (0.03)
Lagged per capita income 0.73 (0.20) 0.17 (0.09)
Lagged real long-run interest rate -0.01 (0.0003) -0.036 (0.01)
Lagged inflation 0.126 (0.06) 0.32 (0.16)
Lagged share prices 0.01 (0.004) 0.046 (0.01)
Lagged change in population 0.65 (0.09) 0.30 (0.16)
Lagged residential investment -0.09 (0.04) -0.052 (0.01)
Differenced per capita income 0.11 (0.05) 0.09 (0.06)
Differenced real long-run interest -0.003 (0.001)
rate
Differenced inflation 0.03 (0.04) 0.55 (0.28)
Differenced share prices 0.01 (0.002) 0.02 (0.012)
Differenced change in population
Differenced change in residential
investment
Trend decomposition, standard
deviations of disturbances
([10.sup.2])
[[sigma].sub.n] Trend 0.000 0.438
Slope 0.573 0.127
Seasonal 0.000 0.127
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] Irregular 0.000 0.783
Cycle 0.002 0.001
Level q ratio 0.559
Slope q ratio 1 0.162
Seasonal q ratio 0.000 0.163
Irregular q ratio 0.000 1
Cycle q ratio 0.004 0.001
Dumping factor 1 1
Growth rate per year 3.43% 1.73%
Residuals tests (c)
Standard error ([10.sup.2]) 0.5 1.3
Normality 3.76 4.58
H(h) 0.41 H(43) 0.57 H(45)
r(1) ([10.sup.2]) -0.7 -1.6
r(q) ([10.sup.2]) -5.4 1.4
DW 2.01 1.99
Q(q,q-p) 12.0 9.07
Rd^2([10.sup.2]) 71.0 61.8
Goodness-of-fit results for
residuals (d)
Prediction error variance (p.e.v.) 0.000029 0.000175
Ratio p.e.v./[(prediction error 1.87 1.09
mean deviation).sup.2]
AIC -10.19 -8.43
Convergence Very strong Very strong
Stability Yes Yes
1970:4-2010:2 Spain United Kingdom
Fundamental part (b)
Lagged house price -0.97 (0.07) -0.36 (0.05)
Lagged per capita income 1.48 (0.53) 0.61 (0.25)
Lagged real long-run interest rate -0.003 (0.001) -0.006 (0.002)
Lagged inflation 0.28 (0.13) 0.71 (0.21)
Lagged share prices 0.04 (0.01) 0.077 (0.02)
Lagged change in population 2.36 (1.38) 1.14 (0.22)
Lagged residential investment -0.17 (0.04) -0.81 (0.03)
Differenced per capita income 1.03 (0.44) 0.26 (0.35)
Differenced real long-run interest -0.001 (0.001) -0.71 (0.21)
rate
Differenced inflation 0.12 (0.08) 0.04 (0.37)
Differenced share prices 0.01 (0.006)
Differenced change in population 0.98 (0.74)
Differenced change in residential -0.001 (0.03)
investment
Trend decomposition, standard
deviations of disturbances
([10.sup.2])
[[sigma].sub.n] Trend 0.070 0.289
Slope 0.823 0.185
Seasonal 0.085 0.113
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] Irregular 0.264 0.845
Cycle 0.359 0.002
Level q ratio 0.085 0.342
Slope q ratio 1 0.219
Seasonal q ratio 0.103 0.134
Irregular q ratio 0.321 1
Cycle q ratio 0.501 0.002
Dumping factor 0.93 1
Growth rate per year 3.13% 2.65%
Residuals tests (c)
Standard error ([10.sup.2]) 1.2 1.3
Normality 2.29 1.68
H(h) 1.32H(39) 0.62H(24)
r(1) ([10.sup.2]) 5.9 -0.8
r(q) ([10.sup.2]) -3.1 -10.3
DW 1.88 1.99
Q(q,q-p) 12.6 9.71
Rd^2([10.sup.2]) 66.9 63.8
Goodness-of-fit results for
residuals (d)
Prediction error variance (p.e.v.) 0.000134 0.000184
Ratio p.e.v./[(prediction error 1.50 1.06
mean deviation).sup.2]
AIC -8.52 -8.38
Convergence Very strong Very strong
Stability Yes Yes
1970:4-2010:2 United States
Fundamental part (b)
Lagged house price -0.27 (0.06)
Lagged per capita income 0.20 (0.10)
Lagged real long-run interest rate -0.031 (0.004)
Lagged inflation 0.16 (0.08)
Lagged share prices 0.03 (0.01)
Lagged change in population 0.79 (0.29)
Lagged residential investment -0.04 (0.02)
Differenced per capita income 0.22 (0.07)
Differenced real long-run interest -0.002 (0.001)
rate
Differenced inflation 0.36 (0.11)
Differenced share prices
Differenced change in population
Differenced change in residential -0.01 (0.02)
investment
Trend decomposition, standard
deviations of disturbances
([10.sup.2])
[[sigma].sub.n] Trend 0.251
Slope 0.000
Seasonal 0.028
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] Irregular 0.000
Cycle 0.570
Level q ratio 0.441
Slope q ratio 0.000
Seasonal q ratio 0.049
Irregular q ratio 0.000
Cycle q ratio 1
Dumping factor 0.53
Growth rate per year 1.18%
Residuals tests (c)
Standard error ([10.sup.2]) 0.66
Normality 0.51
H(h) 0.72 H(43)
r(1) ([10.sup.2]) 3.3
r(q) ([10.sup.2]) -1.6
DW 1.91
Q(q,q-p) 12.6
Rd^2([10.sup.2]) 78.5
Goodness-of-fit results for
residuals (d)
Prediction error variance (p.e.v.) 0.000044
Ratio p.e.v./[(prediction error 1.28
mean deviation).sup.2]
AIC -9.76
Convergence Very strong
Stability Yes
(a) Dependent variable: [DELTA] ln hp, real house price. ALL variables
except the real interest rate are in togs. Standard errors are given
in brackets. The method of estimation is Maximum Log-likelihood. The
State is estimated through a Kalman filter.
(b) Outliers were detected by looking at the graphs of the auxiliary
residuals, that is, the smoothed estimates of the irregular and level
disturbances. Five outliers relative to 1981:4, 1988:3, 1989:4,
2000:4, and 2002:4 were inserted in the house price equation for
United Kingdom. Their values are -0.03, 0.06, -0.04, 0.03, and 0.03,
respectively and their standard error are all 0.01. Four outliers
relative to 1976:1, 1980:1, 1980:2, and 2004:1 enter the house price
equation for the United States. Their values are -0.02, -0.03, -0.04,
and -0.02 with all standard error equal to 0.006.Three outliers were
added for France, their values referred to 1993:1, 1996:1, and 1997:1
are -0.03, -0.02, -0.02 with standard errors equal to 0.01 for all of
them. Two outliers relative to 1981:1 and 1982:1 were added to Italy's
equation: their values are 0.08 and -0.06 with standard errors equal
to 0.01. An outlier relative to 1998:2 was added to Spain, its value
0.12 with standard error equal to 0.01. An outlier relative to 2008:3
was added to Germany, its value and standard error are 0.012 and
0.004, respectively. Two outliers relative to 1976:1 and 2008:2 were
added to the hp equation for the Netherlands. Their respective values
are 0.03 and -0.03 with standard errors all equal to 0.01.
(c) Normality is tested according to the Doornik-Hansen correction to
the Bowman-Shenton statistic. The latter has a [chi square]
distribution with two degrees of freedom under the null hypothesis of
normally distributed errors. We reject the null if the calculated
probability exceeds the tabulated ones equal to 5.99 at 5%
significance level and 9.21% at 1% significance level. H(h) is the
heteroskedasticity test statistics distributed as a F(h,h) with (h,h)
degrees of freedom. Under the mutt of no heteroskedasticity and for h
= 33-36, the 5% critical value is 1.75. For h = 37-41 the 5% critical
value is 1.70. For h = 42-47 the 5% critical value is 1.64. r(1) and
r(9) are the serial correlation coefficients at the 1st and 9th
distributed as a N(0;1/T), T being the number of observations. Rho <
0.02 at 5%. DW is the classical Durbin Watson test distributed as N(2,
4/T). Q(Pd) is the Ljung Box statistics based on the sum of the first
P autocorrelations and it is tested against a [chi square]
distribution with d degrees of freedom. The null hypothesis of no
autocorre[ation is tested against the alternative of autocorrelation.
The critical value for eight degrees of freedom is 15.51 at 5%
significance level.
(d) The prediction error variance (p.e.v) is the variance of the
one-step ahead prediction errors in the steady state. It gives a
measure of the precision of a model's predictions. A low p.e.v.
(tending to zero) means that good predictions are obtained at that
point. A ratio p.e.v./ prediction error mean deviation in squares near
to 1 means that the model is correctly specified. AIC is the Akaike
Information criterion used to select the proper model estimation.
Table 3: House price equations estimated with deterministic trend
1970:4-2010:2 France Germany
Fundamental part
Lagged house price -0.104 (0.04) -0.18 (0.05)
Lagged per capita income 0.092 (0.02) 0.12 (0.06)
Lagged real long-run interest -0.014 (0.004) -0.001 (0.0003)
rate
Lagged inflation 0.006 (0.002) 0.024 (0.01)
Lagged share prices 0.011 (0.003) 0.005 (0.002)
Lagged change in population 0.028 (0.016) 0.13 (0.08)
Lagged residential investment -0.099 (0.07) -0.09 (0.03)
Differenced per capita income 0.419 (0.19) 0.04 (0.08)
Differenced real long-run -0.003 (0.08)
interest rate
Differenced inflation 0.027 (0.01)
Differenced share prices
Differenced change in population 0.09 (0.05)
Differenced change in residential
investment
Standard deviations of
disturbances ([10.sup.2])
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] Irregular 1.2 0.137
Seasonal 0.000 0.000
Trend analysis
Fixed Level 0.00897
Residuals tests
Standard error ([10.sup.2]) 1.1 0.1
Normality 2.50 3.66
H(h) 2.16 H(46) 0.33 H(20)
r(1) ([10.sup.2]) 4.6 2.5
r(q) ([10.sup.2]) 9.2 -4.6
DW 1.06 1.94
Q(q,q-p) 12.0 13.4
Rd^2([10.sup.2]) 54.3 55.6
Goodness-of-fit results for
residuals
Prediction error variance 0.00013 0.000021
(p.e.v.)
Ratio p.e.v./ (prediction error 1.15 1.40
mean deviation) (2)
AIC -8.73 -12.57
Convergence Strong Very strong
Stability Yes Yes
1970:4-2010:2 Italy Netherlands
Fundamental part
Lagged house price -0.043 (0.013) -0.08 (0.02)
Lagged per capita income 0.048 (0.05) 0.34 (0.07)
Lagged real long-run interest -0.004 (0.0007) -0.039 (0.01)
rate
Lagged inflation 0.038 (0.05) 0.21 (0.02)
Lagged share prices 0.02 (0.003) 0.03 (0.004)
Lagged change in population 0.169 (0.033) 0.05 (0.01)
Lagged residential investment -0.10 (0.03) -0.052 (0.01)
Differenced per capita income 0.06 (0.13)
Differenced real long-run -0.007 (0.004) 0.02 (0.01)
interest rate
Differenced inflation 0.38 (0.30)
Differenced share prices
Differenced change in population
Differenced change in residential
investment
Standard deviations of
disturbances ([10.sup.2])
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] Irregular 1.41 1.76
Seasonal 0.002 0.008
Trend analysis
Fixed Level 0.03759 0.0449
Residuals tests
Standard error ([10.sup.2]) 1.3 1.6
Normality 3.76 0.39
H(h) 0.11 H(46) 0.34 H(47)
r(1) ([10.sup.2]) 6.8 2.9
r(q) ([10.sup.2]) 13.5 14.6
DW 1.62 1.40
Q(q,q-p) 12.0 12.07
Rd^2([10.sup.2]) 45.5 37.46
Goodness-of-fit results for
residuals
Prediction error variance 0.00018 0.00028
(p.e.v.)
Ratio p.e.v./ (prediction error 1.19 1.01
mean deviation) (2)
AIC -8.42 -7.97
Convergence Strong Strong
Stability Yes Yes
1970:4-2010:2 Spain United Kingdom
Fundamental part
Lagged house price -0.036 (0.01) -0.14 (0.02)
Lagged per capita income 0.035 (0.02) 0.21 (0.04)
Lagged real long-run interest -0.021 (0.011) -0.008 (0.003)
rate
Lagged inflation 0.18 (0.10) 0.47 (0.07)
Lagged share prices 0.01 (0.005) 0.028 (0.01)
Lagged change in population 0.07 (0.03) 0.44 (0.11)
Lagged residential investment -0.07 (0.03) -0.11 (0.03)
Differenced per capita income 0.97 (0.24) 0.85 (0.45)
Differenced real long-run -0.002 (0.001) -0.02 (0.01)
interest rate
Differenced inflation
Differenced share prices 0.01(0
Differenced change in population
Differenced change in residential
investment
Standard deviations of
disturbances ([10.sup.2])
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] Irregular 1.83 1.81
Seasonal 0.000 0.113
Trend analysis
Fixed Level 0.0121 0.86523
Residuals tests
Standard error ([10.sup.2]) 1.7 1.7
Normality 5.35 0.19
H(h) 1.06 H(47) 0.61H(27)
r(1) ([10.sup.2]) -3.9 0.3
r(q) ([10.sup.2]) 4.7 -10.3
DW 1.91 1.89
Q(q,q-p) 10.10 12.89
Rd^2([10.sup.2]) 56.9 57.6
Goodness-of-fit results for
residuals
Prediction error variance 0.00031 0.00030
(p.e.v.)
Ratio p.e.v./ (prediction error 1.06 1.01
mean deviation) (2)
AIC -7.91 -7.95
Convergence Strong Strong
Stability Yes Yes
1970:4-2010:2 United States
Fundamental part
Lagged house price -0.03 (0.01)
Lagged per capita income 0.09 (0.05)
Lagged real long-run interest -0.013 (0.004)
rate
Lagged inflation 0.02 (0.008)
Lagged share prices 0.001 (0.006)
Lagged change in population 0.07 (0.03)
Lagged residential investment -0.04 (0.006)
Differenced per capita income 0.41 (0.10)
Differenced real long-run -0.002 (0.001)
interest rate
Differenced inflation
Differenced share prices
Differenced change in population
Differenced change in residential -0.07 (0.02)
investment
Standard deviations of
disturbances ([10.sup.2])
[[sigma].sub.[epsilon]] Irregular 0.872
Seasonal 0.000
Trend analysis
Fixed Level 0.01825
Residuals tests
Standard error ([10.sup.2]) 0.83
Normality 2.83
H(h) 0.50 H(47)
r(1) ([10.sup.2]) 2.5
r(q) ([10.sup.2]) -5.6
DW 1.68
Q(q,q-p) 11.00
Rd^2([10.sup.2]) 61.5
Goodness-of-fit results for
residuals
Prediction error variance 0.000544
(p.e.v.)
Ratio p.e.v./ (prediction error 1.11
mean deviation) (2)
AIC -9.38
Convergence Strong
Stability Yes
Dependent variable: ln hp, real house price. All variables except the
real interest rate are in logs. Standard errors are given in brackets.
Table 4: Long-run house price relationship. Baseline setting
France Germany Italy Netherlands
Ln y 0.81 0.67 0.74 0.82
Ln r -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.18
Ln [pi] 0.64 0.13 0.13 1.60
Ln share 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.23
Ln pop 0.45 0.73 0.66 1.49
Ln gfcf -0.22 -0.51 -0.11 -0.26
Unobserved component 1.72 1.02 5.00
Spain United United
Kingdom States
Ln y 1.52 1.69 1.61
Ln r -0.003 -0.03 -0.28
Ln [pi] 0.29 1.97 1.14
Ln share 0.04 0.22 0.12
Ln pop 2.43 3.16 5.52
Ln gfcf -0.18 -0.22 -0.57
Unobserved component 1.03 2.77 7.69
Dependent variable: ln hp, real house price. All variables except
interest rates are in logs (ln). y = per capita income, [pi] =
inflation rate, share = share price, pop = population growth, gfcf =
residential investments.