首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月26日 星期二
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Special vehicles of state intervention in Russia and Kazakhstan.
  • 作者:Kalyuzhnova, Yelena ; Nygaard, Christian A.
  • 期刊名称:Comparative Economic Studies
  • 印刷版ISSN:0888-7233
  • 出版年度:2011
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Association for Comparative Economic Studies
  • 摘要:The period of 2000-2007 could be characterised for Russia and Kazakhstan as an era of rapid real GDP growth and speedy catching up with the pre-transition level. At the same time raising oil prices allowed both governments to build up significant foreign reserves. Accumulated resource revenues enabled (re)emergence of a more active state intervention while rising commodity prices motivated resource nationalistic economic policies (Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2009).
  • 关键词:Actors;Actresses;Business-government relations;Crisis management;Development banks;Economic stabilization;Financial management;Government business enterprises;Planned economy;Public enterprises;Resource allocation

Special vehicles of state intervention in Russia and Kazakhstan.


Kalyuzhnova, Yelena ; Nygaard, Christian A.


INTRODUCTION

The period of 2000-2007 could be characterised for Russia and Kazakhstan as an era of rapid real GDP growth and speedy catching up with the pre-transition level. At the same time raising oil prices allowed both governments to build up significant foreign reserves. Accumulated resource revenues enabled (re)emergence of a more active state intervention while rising commodity prices motivated resource nationalistic economic policies (Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2009).

This paper analyses the link between resource revenues and financial sector management in Russia and Kazakhstan. Due to underdeveloped and structurally skewed private financial sectors, the governments of both countries introduced dedicated financial vehicles that, in principle, might substitute for the actions of private actors by directing credit for industrial development and investment. Moreover, such instruments allow both governments to use these special financial vehicles to form and pursue national economic policies and priorities. This paper specifically focuses on such two state investment vehicles with clear industrial policy remits and roles as agents of their respective governments--Samruk-Kazyna and Vnesheconombank of Kazakhstan and Russia, respectively. Nevertheless there exists in both countries a wider set of state intervention instruments that range from direct ownership in the form of national oil companies (NOCs) to more indirect forms such as state banks, equity ownership in private banks and representatives on key corporate management boards. What distinguishes these latter forms of state intervention is their arms-length relation to the governments--relations that are frequently administered via these special vehicles. Notably, given the structure of state--industry relations and state power in Russia and Kazakhstan, this distinction does not necessarily imply a weaker form of control. (1) The paper further distinguishes between crisis management and the systemic role of these special vehicles. Though in part interlinked, and to some extent providing opportunities for opportunistic government behaviour, it is also clear that the emergence of such instruments represents a longer-term trend towards systemic reform and institutions of systemic reproduction.

In the next section we set up the framework of analysis and the role of the state in financial sector's management. The subsequent section briefly summarises the financial environment in Russia and Kazakhstan prior to the financial crisis. The following two sections analyse the role of the state financial vehicles as crisis management tools as well as emphasize their systematic role. The last section concludes the paper with some policy implications.

THE ROLE OF STATE AND STATE INTERVENTION IN THE ECONOMY

What is the role of the state in managing economies and does or should it somehow differ for emerging economies? Skepticism about state intervention and links to negative long-term growth consequences have a long tradition in economics (Evans and Ranch, 1999; Fukuyama, 2004; Sinch, 1985, etc). Nevertheless, from Smith (1915) onwards there has equally been a case for state intervention in order to improve the workings of a commercial society. The provision of some social overhead investments (infrastructure), funded out of taxes, education and a judicial system to safe-guard the 'rule of law' were seen as instrumental in ensuring a prosperous commercial society. Where Smith did object to state (or any other form) of intervention was with respect to decisions regarding who would produce what and where.

More recent work on state intervention echoes these arguments. For instance Reinert (1999, p. 320) concludes that 'successful State interventions have created dynamic imperfect competition--a process of dynamic and collective national rent-seeking--which increases enormously the size of the pie. The State has given temporary help, and with clear strings attached. Unsuccessful State interventions may at a first glance look similar to the successful ones, e.g. because also they protect national manufacturing industries. However, the less successful State interventions have created static rent-seeking through relatively permanent protection with no strings attached, leading to a "shallow" industrialisation, to inefficient monopolies with a limited potential to increase the pie' (Reinert, 1999, p. 320).

The question of state and state intervention are fundamental in understanding the effective functioning of any economic system. In the classical tradition, state intervention is thus predominantly a means of ensuring that market forces provide a greater degree of social benefits though increased production. Keynes (1936) argued that in periods where production contracted as a result of declining demand, leading to unemployment, the government could additionally adjust its own spending and taxation to expand aggregate demand and facilitate the re-employment of idle factors of production (labour). Business cycle management through aggregate demand adjustment became part of economic orthodoxy in the post war period and, although of declining practical importance towards the end of the century, lay behind the large fiscal stimuli packages observed in developed and emerging economies alike following the 2007-2009 financial crisis. Moreover, it was argued that government intervention to ensure macro-economic stability was conducive to sustainable growth (Fischer, 1993). Beyond aggregate demand management, economists have argued for state intervention in order to correct market imperfections or failures (Stiglitz et al., 1993) and externalities (Broadway, 1979; Herber, 1979; Chambers et al., 1992).

However, another dominant economic paradigm, especially for many emerging economies, in the 20th century was centred on the ideological ability of the market to deliver greater prosperity for the many. In this sense, market imperfection, externalities and socially beneficial production could not be ensured simply by regulation or correction, but required the state to substitute for the actions of private agents also in decisions pertaining to who should produce what and where. While many planned economies achieved periods of rapid industrialisation and modernisation, they also failed to develop and absorb many of the technological and managerial innovations underpinning world growth in the latter third of the 20th century, as well as a shift to service/consumer product-based employment. However, as the case of Korea demonstrates, there are also examples of significant state intervention (of the form who produces what and where) that successfully managed to achieve economic catch-up and avoid structural (dynamic) stagnation. An important explanation for why state intervention worked in Korea was the state's willingness to withdraw support for once favoured industries that no longer performed satisfactorily and facilitating industrial upgrading by removing existing state-created rents and shifting these to new, more productive industries (Chang, 1993; Ray, 1998). An important vehicle for implementing Korean policy was state ownership and control of the financial sector that enabled the directing of credit to favoured industries (Chang, 1993).

The importance of the financial markets and their overall impact on economies, beyond a developmental argument, is well articulated in the literature (Fama, 1980; Stiglitz, 1985; Stiglitz and Weiss, 1990; Greenwald and Stiglitz, 1992). Since the recent global financial crisis, experts have started to stress the importance of proper regulation of financial markets (Colander et al., 2009).

In Russia and Kazakhstan elements of each of these arguments for state intervention are apparent in the development of industrial policy as well as of economic and legislative institutions. However, another element may also be discerned. Smith argued that state intervention may be required to ensure the 'proper workings' of a commercial society. While an analysis of what constitutes 'proper workings' is beyond the scope of this paper, we nevertheless direct attention to the notion of a commercial society. Herein lies a link between the system of economic production and a system of state and societal organisation. For emerging economies this is of importance as it highlights a link between modes of economic coordination and state building. State intervention and the vehicles for its implementation can thus become mechanisms for specific political and economic system (re)production. In a number of resource-rich emerging economies, the issue of systemic (re)production is closely linked with the emergence of resource and/or economic nationalist systemic structures (Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2008, 2009). Recent literature on 'resource nationalism' has focussed on gaining larger equity shares in energy projects or renegotiating Production Sharing Agreements (PSAs) with the aim of redirecting a greater share of revenues to the state or to parastatal enterprises (eg Domjan and Stone, 2010). Support for such measures can be found in each of the state intervention justifications considered in this section, but, from an economic point of view, raises concerns with respect to tradeoffs between static and dynamic comparative advantages and economic development.

That such systemic reproduction through state intervention need not lead to dynamic stagnation is highlighted by the Korean experience. However, in the case of Russia and Kazakhstan, a powerful static comparative advantage stems from them being resource rich. Moreover, resource revenues are instrumental in the design of some of the interventionist vehicles. An interesting angle in this respect will be the connection between resource revenues, which the governments are gaining in resource rich countries and their financial sector management. The next sections concentrate on how resource revenues are being directed through special state-controlled vehicles for strategic economic goals (Kazakhstan) or for economic and social goals (Russia). (2) Like the Korean case, these vehicles operate via the financial sector, though Russia and Kazakhstan's sources of rent differ substantially from the Korean case.

What, then, is the role of the state in emerging economies? This brief overview suggests a number of points to consider in the following sections. The State should provide predictable parameters within which the economy functions--such as law and order, stable property rights, instrumental public goods and welfare redistributions (Kolodko, 2000; Aslund, 2007; Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2008), but also a degree of macroeconomic security through demand side management. If the government is unable to guarantee all of this, then economic performance may deteriorate and poverty and governance challenges may mount. Moreover, managing crisis situations or external shocks will be more difficult (Frye and Zhuravskaya, 2000). Moreover, emerging economies are undergoing market transformation, which are complicated even in the absence of crisis or external shocks (Fidrmuc and Korhonen, 2009; Myant and Drahokoupil, 2010). The responsibility of the state in this context is to accelerate market transformation and the acquisition of new technologies. If the state is unable to meet such tasks, an explanation, and blame, is in the lack of institutional capacities and the incompatibility with pre-existing distributions of power or systemic elements.

THE PRE-CRISIS FINANCIAL ENVIRONMENT

From 1999 to 2008, financial systems of Russia and Kazakhstan grew rapidly in the context of overall macro-economic stability. Since 1999, macroeconomic stabilisation such as real GDP growth, low rate of inflation, positive fiscal balance of the central government took place in both Russia and Kazakhstan. However, the degree of financial deepening (cg the ratio of banking credits to the private sector to GDP) and the efficiency of the financial systems left needed to be improved throughout the years.

Russia and Kazakhstan also benefitted from a recovery in oil prices in 2000 leading to substantial export and real GDP growth. However, while the period after 2000 was also characterised by high investment levels in Kazakhstan, fixed capital investment in Russia remained largely unchanged. Kazakhstani growth was accompanied by substantial international leveraging, while Russia's debt levels were low--also in comparison with other FSU countries. In 2006 total debt to gross national income was 103% and 26% in Kazakhstan and Russia, respectively. Kazakhstani banks had borrowed assets amounting to 84% of GDP.

Credit to the private sector grew rapidly in Kazakhstan, with lower growth in Russia. Similarly, domestic credit to households expanded rapidly over the period, with Kazakhstan and Russia again displaying diverging trends. Unsurprisingly, non-performing loans (NPLs) increased after 2007 after having generally declined since the early 2000s (Table 1). Overall, the drivers of credit expansion have differed in emerging markets. In Kazakhstan and Russia, we would argue that energy exports had a significant impact on private sector credit growth, whereas the role of western financial institutions was prominent in the non-resource rich emerging economies (Hilbers et al., 2006).

Oil and gas constitutes some 20%-30% of GDP in Russia and Kazakhstan; however, they are not typical 'petro-state economies' (Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2009). Nevertheless there has been a constant emphasis on diversification in light of both transition dynamics (the emergence from a planned and heavy-industry-based development strategy) and longer-term consequences of over-reliance on mineral extraction. By 2007, the financial and banking sectors played significant roles in the economic life of the both countries.

The fiscal importance of the oil and gas industry in Kazakhstan and Russia is shown in Table 2. The importance of oil and gas revenues has clearly increased over the period 2000-2008. In 2008, oil and gas revenues accounted for almost half of Kazakhstan's consolidated government revenues and roughly a third of Russia's consolidated revenues. While both countries accumulated significant revenues in respective oil funds, high oil prices and revenue flows also enabled pro-cyclical policies that contributed to high pre-crisis growth levels. Moreover, the accumulation of oil revenues during the commodity price boom enabled substantial fiscal stimuli packages as the financial crisis unfolded in these countries and large scale capital inflows (associated with high oil prices and inflexible exchange rate regimes) reversed. In the case of Russia, its negative non-oil balance increased steadily during the pre-crisis period amounting to some 4.6% of GDP in 2007. During and post crisis the negative non-oil balance further increased to some 13% of GDP in 2009. Notably, much of this non-oil deficit is structural, with only 9% of budget spending being non-statutory (IMF, 2010). Similarly, Kazakhstan's non-oil balance deteriorated post crisis.

SPECIAL VEHICLES AB CRISIS MANAGEMENT TOOLS

The financial sectors of both countries developed speedily during the period 2002-2007/2008. However, the overall trend was unrealistic with the expectations that banks will 'do more than they can reasonably accomplish' (Bonin and Wachtel, 2003, p. 2).

The lending issues in the banking sector are linked to the architecture of the banking system of the Soviet era and the transition period (Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2009). Relational lending dominated the allocation of credit following the 1998 financial crisis (Bonin and Wachtel, 2003; IMF, 2004), posing a significant barrier to renewed private sector credit expansion post crisis as NPLs increase, but structural lending issues continue to draw resources away from potentially capacity-constrained enterprises (IMF, 2010).

Kazakhstan

Since the early 2000s' Kazakhstan's economy has been growing rapidly, with an average real GDP growth of 10.1%. This growth was driven mostly by rapid credit expansion, higher oil prices and production, strong domestic consumption, but also specific policies to siphon off windfall revenues into the National Fund of the Republic of Kazakhstan (NFRK).

From July 2007, Kazakhstan's banking sector was affected by a financial crisis because banks had borrowed heavily on international capital markets. Another reason was 'the bursting of a speculative bubble in the residential property market, which has still not recovered' (Nuttall, 2008). So, in the analysis of the 2007 financial crisis in Kazakhstan we could highlight several factors, foreign borrowing and a housing market bubble, that are inter-connected. Much of the banks' foreign borrowing was to fund lending for real estate purchases; the gap between world interest rates, at which Kazakhstani banks could borrow because of the country's good credit rating given its current account surplus from oil revenues, and domestic mortgage rates kept widening, partly driven by moral hazard affects that promoted over-optimistic lending at inflated nominal interest rates, such intermediation was highly profitable for the Kazakhstani banks as long as the Tenge/$ exchange rate remained stable and creditors did not default, but it collapsed in the second half of 2007 as the housing bubble burst and borrowers defaulted. The US financial crisis exacerbated the situation in 2008 as cash-strapped foreign creditors refused to roll over loans.

The main issue for 2008 was the leverage within the banking system, which represented approximately 50% of Kazakhstan's total external debt. Bank leverage became a significant hurdle for growth in 2008. The situation in the banking sector deteriorated significantly due to the slowing economy and exchange rate devaluation. NPLs were increasing sharply. Although in 2008 there were several banks that managed to repay loans and bonds, the questions about the value of external assets and capital adequacy remained unsolved. Therefore, in 2009, the Kazakhstani government's big bank bailout programme was introduced, which was directed at Bank Turan Alem (BTA), Alliance Bank, Halyk Bank and Kazkommertsbank, the country's four largest banks. The decision to intervene in the banks came partly in response to concerns that they might face difficulties meeting their debt repayments. Kazakhstani commercial banks faced USS11 billion in external debt repayments in 2009. 2008 represented a turning point for the banking system with major stresses on both liquidity and quality of assets. From 2008, banks have significantly tightened leverage criteria for corporations. Overleveraged corporations and banks, which have funded themselves mostly through debt over the past 3 years, are currently being directed to the equity markets.

With a fall in oil prices following the financial crisis, Kazakhstan became economically more vulnerable and the deepening crisis had a significant impact on the wider Kazakhstani economy. The Kazakhstani government revised its 3-year budget plans and based its 2009 budget on an oil price of just $40/bbl for 2009 and $50/bbl for the next 2 years. At the end of 2008 a stabilisation plan of the KZT2.2 trillion ($18.3 billion) (3) was approved, the core of which was to soften the negative socio-economic consequences of the economic decline in Kazakhstan as well as to provide a basis for future economic growth.

The executor of this programme is The National Wellbeing Fund, which is a merger of the state holding company Samruk and the Kazyna national investment fund. (4) The main elements of the programme are presented in Table 3.

Total foreign exchange reserves stood at US$46 billion at end 2008, including US$27 billion in the NFRK, the oil stabilisation fund, the use of which to fund rescue packages for the economy has been authorised by President Nazarbayev. It was the availability of Kazakhstan's oil revenues, stashed in the NFRK, that made it possible for the government to respond quickly to the 2007-2009 crisis, taking over BTA and Alliance Bank in early 2009 and injecting capital into other top four banks. The government and other state-run institutions are still expected to retain this central role for some time. Samruk-Kazyna is unlikely to exit its investment in BTA in the next 3 years, although earlier sales of its stakes in the smaller Alliance Bank and TemirBank are very much on the agenda.

Russia

In Russia the ongoing crisis has resulted in the merger and acquisition of a number of smaller, banks by the larger, predominantly state-owned, banks, agencies and corporations and the government has intervened to ensure availability of liquidity for banks and capital to refinance maturing foreign loans. Overall, commercial state-owned banks, Sberbank, VTB-Bank and

Gazprombank, Russia have strengthened their position vis-a-vis private banks throughout the financial crisis. Table 4 shows the market share of Russia's 10 largest commercial banks.

Table 5 summarises some of the main crisis measures until the end of 2008. An important vehicle for implementing several of these policies is State Corporation Vnesheconombank (VEB)--'Bank for Development and Foreign Economic Affairs'. VEB's history goes back to the establishment in 1924 of the Bank for Foreign Trade of the USSR, but it emerged in its present guise as one of the Russian government's key investment instruments following the merger of Vnesheconombank USSR, the Russian Development Bank (RDB) and Roseximbank in 2006. However, already prior to this, VEB's role as a government agency was strengthened with the restructuring of its activities in 2002; to reduce its commercial business and to give greater priority to supporting government reforms.

In December 2008, a list of 'system-forming enterprises' was established that were to be supported by VEB, Sberbank and Gazprombank. These companies produce some 85% of GDP. As a 'crisis management' vehicle VEB has acted along a number of lines, refinancing 10 Russian corporations' debt to foreign banks; providing subordinate loans to 17 banks; shoring up the Russian stock market; facilitating the rehabilitation of two domestic banks (plus a Ukrainian bank); extending state guarantees to banks that lend to priority (system-forming) sector enterprises. Much of the assistance directed via VEB in the first instance has been further disseminated via the above commercial state-owned banks.

A tranche of $50 billion was transferred to Vnesheconombank (VEB) in order to assist Russian companies with refinancing of foreign debt; at the end of October 2008 some $7.8 billion was made available to companies in the fuel and energy sector, metal and construction industries (www.veb.ru). For instance, RusA1 secured a $4.5 billion bailout from VEB to refinance western loans, effectively ensuring that the company remained Russian owned. Overall, some 65% of the approved refinancing resources (total $14.3 billion) went to the smelting industry with another 15 and 16%, respectively, directed at 'oil production, petro-chemistry and chemistry' and 'high technologies' refinancing.

Through October and November 2008, 365 billion roubles were transferred from the National Welfare Fund to VEB (www.minfin.ru); enabling VEB to invest some $740 million in Russian shares in October. Reserves, which peaked at just under $600 billion in August 2008, dropped to $485 billion at the end of October 2008 as the Central Bank of Russia (CBR) intervened to stabilise the rouble exchange rate. In October 2008, the rouble was allowed to depreciate in a series of step-wise devaluations that halted the rapid drain of foreign reserves needed to maintain the mid-2008 value of the rouble. By mid-January 2009, foreign reserves declined an additional $60 billion. The rate of reserve decline afterward reversed with reserves at $412.6 billion and $461.2 billion in July 2009 and 2010, respectively.

A number of measures were implemented to assist the banking sector throughout the global crisis, but much of this support has been aimed at state-owned banks and banks of systemic importance. Moreover, as NPLs begin to accumulate it is likely that further merger and acquisition activity will reduce the number of banks. Average NPLs in the Russian financial sector increased from a low of 2.6% in 2007 to 11.2% in 2009 as the effects of the financial crisis spread in the economy, with private banks generally worse off than state-owned banks. The two largest private banks, AlfaBank and MDM bank, have 10% and 7.2% NPLs, respectively. In Kazakhstan the effects of the financial crisis were evident already in 2007 and the effect on NPLs is more evident in Table 1.

SPECIAL VEHICLES AS STATE AGENCIES AND THEIR SYSTEMIC ROLE

The accumulation of oil and gas revenues in dedicated 'oil-funds' has enabled Russia and Kazakhstan to develop investment structures beyond the standard banking system and/or the money multiplier effect (Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2009), that are to promote investment and reduce bottlenecks in industry and infrastructure. The rest of this section sketches the various dedicated structures to support the economy's diversification. It is evident from the theoretical part of this paper that the market in Russia and Kazakhstan did not deliver sufficient social overhead investments and hence governments intervened and provided credits to both Samruk-Kazyna and Vnesheconombank for infrastructure development.

The creation of specific state investment vehicles must also be seen as a government response to investment barriers. Lending criteria centred on public-private partnership (PPP) type arrangements are thus a means of ensuring greater private sector involvement and a means of reducing perceived transaction costs. However, an alternative, but (partially complementary) reading of this policy is that it embodies a recognition and acceptance of the state's obligation to create an institutional framework that can compensate or complement 'standard' market-based financial intermediation where some of the systemic risk is linked to market uncertainty originating with the state itself. This, of course, additionally gives the state greater leverage in the allocation decision, but also exposes these investments to greater inefficiencies if allocation decisions reflect non-commercial objectives. In Russia, accumulated oil revenues have been instrumental in creating such an investment vehicle.

Kazakhstan

In order to overcome inefficiency of resource allocation in Kazakhstan, there is a desire to boost competitiveness of the economy via diversification, which is demonstrated by governmental documents such as Strategy of Innovative Industrial Development of Kazakhstan for 2003-2015, 2004 Cluster Development in Non-Extraction Sectors of the Economy (see Kalyuzhnova, 2008). In order to do so, since 2006 the government has engaged in the creation of various state development institutions with a stronger government presence such as Samruk or Kazyna fund.

The Sovereign Wealth Fund Samruk-Kazyna was established in October 2008 as a result of the statutory consolidation of these two state-owned holding companies. Samruk was a state-owned holding that owned and managed national companies in key industries, such as oil and gas, transportation, energy, telecommunication, nuclear power and petrochemicals. Kazyna, which was a state-owned holding that owned and managed national financial development institutions to promote the development of non-extractive industries in Kazakhstan. The purpose of the new fund was to enhance the competitiveness and sustainability of the national economy and to ameliorate potential negative impacts from changes in the world markets on economic growth of the country. (5) The mission of the fund was to manage state investments, to diversify economy, and to increase the competitiveness of the Kazakhstani economy (Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2009). Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard (2008a, b) argue that state ownership or intervention in the resource extracting industries can be detrimental to long-term growth if such ownership fails to direct resources to their most productive use. With respect to Samruk-Kazyna, a similar caveat arises in relation to its diversification strategy. Samruk-Kazyna believes that 'diversification and modernization of national economy can go efficiently through active investments especially in such prioritized sectors as: oil and gas; power energy; metallurgy; chemistry and petrochemicals; and infrastructure' (Samruk-Kazyna webpage n.d.). (6)

The 'official' purpose of Samruk-Kazyna is 'to manage shares (interests) of national development institutions, national companies, and other legal entities it owns to maximize their long-term value and competitiveness in the world markets' (Samruk-Kazyna webpage n.d.). Samruk-Kazyna is acting as a state financial vehicle, providing Kazakhstani government support in order to attract investments in the real sector of the economy. Therefore, at the present time, Samruk-Kazyna is an arm of the government with a total market capitalisation of around $30 billion.

The main objectives of the fund were initially stated as increasing of competitiveness and sustainability of the Kazakhstani economy, but, since the beginning of 2009, it is possible to observe the emergence of Samruk-Kazyna as a key governance vehicle and institution in the Kazakhstani economy. Since the financial crisis affects all sectors of the economy, Samruk-Kazyna assumed the role of the state rescuer. According to CEO Kairat Kelimbetov, Samruk-Kazyna has become an internal investor responsible for the financing of the country's economy in a time of a crisis, but, in reality, the process of state consolidation of economic assets is taking a place. Samruk-Kazyna adopted the strategy (with support of the government) of replacing the external financing from the western banks with long-term financing. Of course the government did not have sufficient means for such an expensive strategy, and, therefore, it took a $10 billion credit line in China, a $3.5 billion credit line in Russia, through Vnesheconombank, and a $1 billion credit line in the UAE. As we can see, the borrowing has a political platform, from state to state and, of course, the use of these credits will be more strategic rather than economic.

The high profile given to Samruk-Kazyna in 2009 was a reaction to the perceived failure of the Kazakhstani banking system, which had frittered away the opportunity provided by the oil boom by funding a housing bubble rather than providing loans to promote economic diversification. Although Samruk-Kazyna may not do better, data on the share of SMEs in Samruk-Kazyna's portfolio are a powerful indictment of Samruk-Kazyna as a venture capitalist, see Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard, 2009, but the government seems to believe that it can. A better response to the 2007 banking crisis would have been regulatory reform to increase the costs to bank managers and owners of excessive risk-taking.

Originally, the government stated that their priority will be the support of the local banks in order to provide for the stability of the payment system, to maintain necessary lending to the real sector of the economy, and to maintain the investment attractiveness the country at the highest possible level. In December 2008 the government stated that it's intention was not to purchase a controlling stake in the banks.

However, by May 2009, Samruk-Kazyna had acquired stakes in the four largest commercial banks: Kazkommerts (25%), BTA (75%), Halyk (25%), Alliance (76%) (Table 6). These banks represented 67% of assets, 65% of equity and 73% of deposits of the whole banking sector in Kazakhstan. Without doubt, obtaining an ownership stake in these banks increased the state's systemic role in the economy. One of the former leaders of BTA stressed that 'the antagonism was already built into the wording of the amendments to the law. The government was not seeking for means of supporting banks, it was seeking for means to seize control'. (Interview 23 July 2009, Reading, UK) No doubt, every opinion has a subjective connotation, and although on one hand it might be true that the Kazakhstani government has exercised a certain degree of toughness towards banks, on the other hand, the financial crisis exposed underlying vulnerabilities in the Kazakhstani banking sector. The Kazakhstani authorities were put in a situation where they had to respond with a large-scale policy package in order to prevent a collapse of the banking system and limit the impact on growth and employment. So, the systemic role of Samruk-Kazyna is the expansion of controlling the flows of credits to favoured investment sectors. The effect of the crisis enabled the state to rapidly expand the systemic role through its crisis management. So, in essence, we could see the combination of the two roles: crisis management and the systemic role, where the former has been instrumental in expanding the latter.

A key issue is whether and to whom Samruk-Kazyna will divest its bank holdings. If they are re-privatised, that will ease our reservations about the increasing inefficiency of financial intermediation in Kazakhstan, but, if Samruk-Kazyna hangs on to the banks or they become state-controlled in another form, then that would be bad for the Kazakhstani economy.

Russia

A series of Presidential State of the Nation addresses emphasised the need to overcome infrastructure bottlenecks in the Russian economy. The restructuring of Vnesheconombank in 2002 and 2009 thus fits within a longer-term trend to improve investment and investment allocation under state direction. However, Vnesheconombank's overall weight in industry investment is significantly less than in the case of Samruk-Kazyna. VEB's investment-loan portfolio as a share of total fixed asset investment in 2009 amounted to some 4% (VEB, 2010). While the structure of VEB's role as a 'state economic policy instrument' (VEB, 2010) emerged prior to the financial crisis, its role as an agent for government policy implementation was enhanced during 2008-2009 as the government introduced a range of policies to support the Russian economy--many of these measures were delivered by, or through, VEB. In 2009 Vnesheconombank was established as a VEB Group, with banks dedicated to specialised lending functions in different economic sectors including leasing, investment and engineering.

At the end of 2007 and shortly before Government Decision No. 892 on dividing the Oil Stabilisation Fund came into force, 300 billion roubles were transferred from the Oil Stabilisation Fund to capitalise the state-owned Vnesheconombank (VEB) and the state-owned Russian Nanotechnology Corporation. (7) This transfer should not be confused with the various crisis related transfers referred to earlier and underlines the emergence and implementation of a more active role of the state in directing economic activity in Russia.

According to VEB's corporate strategy, its main goal is not commercial or shareholder value-oriented, but instead to act as an agent for the Russian government's 'social and economic development initiatives rather than to generate profit' (www.veb.ru). As a government agency, VEB does not operate with a banking licence issued by the CBR. Its main activities are supposed to overcome infrastructure bottlenecks, upgrade and promote non-raw materials sectors and support SMEs, although its remit expanded during the financial crisis to include supporting the financial sector and 1500 'system forming enterprises'.

Part of VEB's investment strategy is centred on PPPs. Given low levels of investment in Russia, especially, but more generally the risk of private sector crowding out, PPP investment is seen as a means of ensuring greater investment efficiency. However, the degree of state ownership in major industrial sectors raises a question whether PPPs will in fact turn out to be public 'partially public' partnerships.

Two of VEB's objectives are to support the SME sector and non-raw materials sectors. The RDB was the SME arm of VEB. (8) With the full integration of RDB into the VEB corporate structure in 2008, the former's charter capital was expanded by an additional 10 billion roubles.

VEB's lending profile has fluctuated over the past 5 years {see Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard for 2006-2007 figures), but with a strong emphasis on infrastructure development, especially in the energy sectors. In 2009 (2008) some 40 (48)% of its lending was directed to infrastructure projects including sports and the Olympic Games, energy infrastructure and special economic zones, 25% (na) to the agro-industrial sector, with oil and gas (narrow definition) receiving some 3 (9)% of loans.

It is also notable that two-thirds of its financial lending in 2007 was to state-controlled companies. Following the crisis, SME activity increased, and there is a recognition that developing the SME sector can not only act as a catalyst for improving employment and self-employment in Russia, but also serve as a means of diversification in many mono-industry towns. According to VEB's 2009 annual report 'delivering [the] SME support agenda envisages a systemic development of SMEs with due regard for the priorities of Russia's socio-economic development' (VEB, 2010). Under an agreement concluded with KfW Bankengruppe, leading priority leading will be extended to businesses developing and introducing energy-efficient and energy saving technologies. Notably though, increased state sponsored credit availability to the SME sector can only partially make up for the systemic lending practices referred to earlier and the general drop in credit availability post crisis. Moreover, it raises question with respect to the identification of investment and growth sectors if the VEB's objective are to support political objectives over commercial considerations.

CONCLUSION

This study is concerned with the interlink between resource revenues and financial sector management in Russia and Kazakhstan. In the absence of a well functioning private financial sector, the governments of these two countries can substitute for the actions of private actors by introducing dedicated financial vehicles that channel and direct resource revenues from various sovereign wealth funds (SWFs). Specifically, these instruments allow the governments of Russia and Kazakhstan alternatives to direct ownership in their pursuit of national economic priorities.

Special state investment vehicles--Samruk-Kazyna and Vnesheconombank--were established that directly channelled resource from the oil and gas revenues into domestic credit markets. This structural use of resources from the oil funds for this purpose occurred prior to the financial crisis, though in absolute terms the Russian investment vehicle is small compared to Samruk-Kazyna. Notably, the oil funds themselves have performed an essential system-preserving role during the crisis. In this respect both funds have in fact conformed to theory--the crisis as such provides a unique stress-test of the viability of resource accumulation in oil funds. However, it is also evident that in their system-preserving capacity the Funds have ensured the continuation of systemic particularities in the post-crisis period that also imply the continuation of structural weaknesses.

Post-crisis Russia is again recording strong balance of payments, high fiscal reserves and low public debt, but also continued dependence on commodity prices, lack of domestic investment funds and high levels of NPLs. Post-crisis Kazakhstan has experienced strong export recovery, the successful restructuring of BTA and Alliance's foreign debt as well as foreign reserve growth. Pre-2009, oil funds' assets grew rapidly, almost by accident, and there was lack of clarity (9) about their objectives apart from general statements about their use for stabilisation. (NRFK accumulated assets when the price of oil exceeded $19 per barrel) or social goals (eg, Norwegian Wealth Fund was to fund pension obligations), but in 2009 both were raided to fund economic stimulus packages in the face of recession. In this episode, the funds themselves were passive as Samruk-Kazyna and VEB assumed the role of implementing agencies, and hence became far more important, justifying our paper's focus on these financial vehicles.

The case illustrations can also be interpreted in a neoclassical framework. Standard growth theory suggests that, in the absence of market imperfections, investments will be directed to their highest return. Our argument is that state-owned investment vehicles in this sense constitute additional market imperfections in that they may direct investment on the basis of non-economic considerations. In any given economy some investments are carried out on the basis of non-economic considerations such as equity, redistribution etc. With respect to the overall economic trajectory, an important issue is, therefore, the size of this investment vis-a-vis overall investment in the economy. In Russia and Kazakhstan these shares differ--Samruk-Kazyna's investment responsibility constitutes a much larger part of overall investment than does VEB's.

At a more general level, the inflow of oil and gas revenue in Kazakhstan and Russia has enabled economic nationalist structures via financial market intervention. However, the rapid credit expansion in recent years has not concomitantly led to a comparable expansion of investments, an issue that is compounded by structural weaknesses in the banking and credit system that, partially, necessitates the development of the dedicated state-owned investment vehicles discussed in this paper.

However, what distinguishes these instruments is the development of incentives structures more akin to quasi-market mechanisms. The banking system in Russia remains dominated by state banks whereas in Kazakhstan Samruk-Kazyna has a large equity stakes in several large private sector banks. Large private banks often remain related to specific industries or financial industrial groups. Similarly, state controlled banks have strategic objectives beyond, and sometimes before, return considerations. Thus, as the state increases its de facto and de jure property rights throughout the economy, it becomes pertinent that the state also is able to identify the 'right' places to direct resources if it is to ensure continued output expansion. It appears, however, unlikely that these 'right' places will lead to a significant real diversification of the economy or the development of a broader SME sector. For this to occur the security of property rights needs to be formally and informally strengthened. However, there may be limited incentives to conduct such a structural change in the short term.

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D and Johnson, S. 2005: Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy 113: 949-995.

Aslund, A. 2007: How capitalism was built: The transformation of Central and Eastern Europe, Russia, and central Asia. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

Bonin, J and Wachtel, P. 2003: Financial sector development in transition economies: Lessons from the first decade. Financial Markets, Institutions & Instruments 12(1): 1-66.

Broadway, RW. 1979: Public Sector Economics. Winthrop Publishers Inc: Cambridge.

Brunnschweiler, CN and Bulte, EH. 2009: Natural resources and violent conflict: Resource abundance, dependence, and the onset of civil wars. Oxford Economic Papers, Oxford University Press: Oxford, Vol. 61 no. (4), pp. 651-674.

Central Bank of Russia(CBR). 2008: Banking supervision report 2007. CBR: Moscow.

Chambers, DE, Wedel, KR and Rodwell, MK. 1992: Evaluating social programs. Allyn and Bacon J.P: Boston.

Chang, H-J. (1993): The political economy of industrial policy in Korea. Cambridge Journal of Economics 17: 131-157.

Colander, S, Goldberg, M, Haas, A, Jusekis, K, Kirman, A, Lux, T and Sloth, B. 2009: The financial crisis and the systemic failure of the economic profession. Critical Review 21 (2-3): 249-267.

Domjan, P and Matt, S. 2010: A comparative study of resource nationalism in Russia and Kazakhstan, 2004-2008. Europe-Asia Studies 62(1): 35-62.

EBRD-World Bank. (2004-2005): Business environment and enterprise performance survey(BEEPS) 2005. Data Base, http://www.ebrd.com/pages/ research/analysis/surveys/beeps.shtml.

Evans, P and Ranch, JE. 1999: Bureaucracy and growth: A cross-national analysis of the effects of 'Weberian' state structures on economic growth. American Sociological Review 64(5): 748-765, http://www.jstor.org/stable/2657374.

Fama, EF. 1980: Banking in the theory of finance. Journal of Monetary Economics 6: 38-58.

Fidrmuc, J and Korhonen, I. 2009: The impact of the global financial crisis on business cycles in Asian emerging economies. CESIFO Working paper No. 2710. Category 7: Monetary Policy and International Finance, July 2009.

Fischer, S. 1993: The role of macroeconomic factors in growth. NBER Working paper 4565, National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Frye, T and Zhuravskaya, E. 2000: Rackets, regulation and the rule of law. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization and Environment 16(2): 478-502.

Fukuyama, 17. 2004: State-building: Governance and world order in the 21st century. New York: Cornell University Press.

Greenwald, BC and Stiglitz, JE. 1992: Information, finance and markets: The architecture of allocative mechanisms. NBER Working papers 3652, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

Gylfason, T. 2000: Resources, agriculture, and economic growth in economies in transition. Kyklos 53(4): 545-580.

Hartley, P and Medlock III, K. 2007: A model of the operation and development of a national oil company. James A. Baker III Institute for Public Policy, Rice University.

Herber, BP. 1979: Modern public finance. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin Inc. Jimoh, A.

Hilbers, P, Otker-Robe, I and Pazarbasioglu, C. 2006: Going too fast? Finance and Development 43 (1), http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ ft/fandd/2006/03/hilbers.htm.

International Monetary Fund. 2004: Russian federation: Selected issues. IMF: Washington.

International Monetary Fund. 2010: Concluding statement 2010 article IV consultation June. IMF: Washington.

Kalyuzhnova, Y. 2008: Economics of the Caspian oil and gas wealth: Companies. Governments Policies. Palgrave Press: Basingstoke.

Kalyuzhnova, Y and Nygaard, C. 2008a: State governance evolution in resource rich transition economies: An application to Russia and Kazakhstan. Energy Policy 36: 1829-1842.

Kalyuzhnova, Y and Nygaard, C. 2008b: Economic nationalism and the role of national oil companies in resource-rich countries: An empirical examination. Memo, The University of Reading.

Kalyuzhnova, Y and Nygaard, C. 2009: Resource nationalism and credit growth in FSU countries. Energy Policy 37: 4700-4710.

Keynes, J. 1936: The general theory of employment, interest and money. Macmillan Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

Kohli, A. (ed.) 2004: State-directed development. Cambridge University Press: New York.

Kolodko, GW. 2000: From shock to therapy: The political economy of post-socialist transformation. Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Myant, M and Drahokoupil, J. 2010: Transition economies: Political economy in Russia, Eastern Europe and Central Asia. John Wiley & Sons, Inc.: Hoboken, NJ.

Nuttall, C. 2008: EURASIA 2009: Falling commodity prices hit region hard. Business New Europe, http://businessneweurope.eu/storyl413/ EURASIA_2009_Falling_commodity_prices to hit_region_hard, accessed February 2010.

Papyrakis, E and Gerlagh, R. 2004: The resource curse hypothesis and its transmission channels. Journal of Comparative Economics 32: 181-193.

Ray, D. 1998: Development economics. Princeton University Press: Chichester, UK.

Reinert, E. 1999: The role of the state in economic growth. Journal of Economic Studies 26(4/5): 268-326.

Sinch, R. 1985: State intervention, foreign economic aid, savings and growth in LDCs: Some recent evidence. Kyklos 38, Fasc.2, 216-232.

Smith, A. 1913: The wealth of nations. Macmillan: London.

Stiglitz, JE. 1985: Credit markets and the control of capital. Journal of Money, Banking and Credit 17(1): 133-152.

Stiglitz, JE, Jaramillo-Vallejo and Chal Park, Y. 1993: The role of the state in financial markets. World Bank Research Observer, Annual Conference on Development Economics Supplement (1993), pp. 19-61.

Stiglitz, JE and Weiss, A. 1990: Banks as social accountants and screening devices and the general theory of credit rationing. Creek Economic Review 12: 85-118. In: Courakis, A and Goodhart, C (eds). Essays in Monetary Economics in Honor of Sir John Hicks. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK.

(1) For the role of the NOCs see Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard (2008).

(2) The use of these revenues is debated widely in the economic literature (see Acemoglu and Johnson, 2005; Brunnschweiler and Bulte, 2009; Gylfason, 2000; Papyrakis and Gerlagh, 2004), but in this paper we are more interested in the impact that resource nationalism is making on the governmental strategies in the financial sector.

(3) $8.3 billion will come from the state budget and $10 billion from the National Fund of the Republic of Kazakhstan (NFRK).

(4) For more details see the section 'Special vehicles as crisis management tools' of this paper.

(5) Joint Stock Company Sovereign Wealth Fund 'Samruk-Kazyna' was founded in accordance with the Decree of President of the Republic of Kazakhstan dated 13 October 2008 No. 669 'On some measures on competitiveness and sustainability of national economy' and by the Decree of the Government of the Republic of Kazakhstan dated 17 October 2008 No. 962 'On measures on realization of the Decree of President of the Republic of Kazakhstan No. 669'.

(6) The key area for Samruk-Kazyna and companies shall be modernisation and diversification of national economy in the framework Annual Addresses of the President of Kazakhstan, Strategy of Industrial and Innovation Development of Kazakhstan 2003-2015, '30 Corporate Leaders of Kazakhstan' Program, aims and objectives assigned to Companies and other documents.

(7) Vnesheconombank resulted out of a reorganisation of a number of state-owned banks around the Vnesheconombank USSR in 2007; the latter was merged with the Russian Development Bank and Roseximbank.

(8) Kalyuzhnova and Nygaard (2009) show that the overall share of SME lending constituted only a small proportion of VEB's assets in 2007.

(9) Saving for future generations was compromised in 2009 when a large share of NFRK liquid assets ($10billion out of <$30billion) was used for short-run crisis management. This may have been a good use of funds but it was not an obvious goal in official statements in 2000-2008.

YELENA KALYUZHNOVA & CHRISTIAN A NYGAARD

The Centre for Euro-Asian Studies, The University of Reading, Whiteknights, PO Box 218, Reading, RG6 6AA, UK. E-mails: y.katuyzhnova@rdg.ac.uk; c.a.b.nygaard@rdg.ac.uk
Table 1: Domestic credit in Russia and Kazakhstan 2003, 2007 and 2008

                 Domestic credit      Domestic credit
                to private sector      to household
                    (%, GDP)             (%, GDP)

               2003   2007   2008   2003   2007   2008

Kazakhstan     21.9   58.9   48.8    2.6   17.4   12.6
Russian        21.0   37.9   41.0    1.9    9.0    9.6
Federation
FSU, average   17.7   40.3   44.3    4.1   16.0   16.2

                                          Mortgage
                   Non-performing         lending
                     loans (%)            (%, GDP)

                2003   2007   2008   2003   2007   2008

Kazakhstan       3.9    2.7    7.1    0.6    4.9    4.9
Russian          5.4    2.6    3.9    na     1.9    2.5
Federation
FSU, average     5.8    2.8    5.1    3.1   10.1   10.7

                  Asset share of
                  foreign owned
                    banks (%)

                2003   2007   2008

Kazakhstan      56.9   38.5   12.9
Russian          7.4   17.2   18.7
Federation
FSU, average    47.1   50.9   51.1

Note: FSU is the un-weighted average of Armenia. Azerbaijan,
Belarus, Estonia, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Latvia,
Lithuania, Moldova and the Russian Federation.

Source: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development

Table 2: Oil and gas revenues in energy rich FSU countries

                                            Kazakhstan

                                        2000   2007   2008

0&G general government revenue, % GDP    6.4    9.4   12.4
Revenue as % of GDP                     21.7   28.8   27.8
0&G as a share of revenue               29.5   32.6   44.6

                                              Russia

                                        2000   2007   2008

0&G general government revenue, % GDP    5.5   10.7   12.6
Revenue as % of GDP                     37.1   40.0   38.4
0&G as a share of revenue               14.8   26.8   32.8

Source: IMF Article IV consultations for Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan
and Russia in 2003 and 2010

Table 3: Stabilisation programme of November 2008

Sector                 Amount,    Description
                      $ billion

Financial                 4       Samruk-Kazyna to buy shares and
                                  subordinated debt from Kazakhstan's
                                  largest banks. Stressed assets fund
                                  to be set up.

Real-estate               3       Samruk-Kazyna to manage pension
                                  funds loaned for priority investment
                                  projects financing, purchase
                                  apartments in Astana and Almaty and
                                  make discount-rate mortgages
                                  available to homeowners.

SMEs support              1       Samruk-Kazyna to provide funding
                                  through banks, of which 70% will go
                                  to existing projects and 30% to new
                                  projects.

Agriculture               1       KazAgro Holding to finance 11
                                  projects in the agriculture sector.

Infrastructure and        1
individual projects

Table 4: Ten largest banks in Russia, bank assets and
ownership type, 2008

Bank             Percentage of    Ownership
                 banking assets

Sberbank             23.7         State
VTB                   8.0         State
Gazprombank           4.7         State
Rosselhozbank         2.9         State
Bank of Moscow        2.8         State
Alfa-Bank             2.5         Private domestic
UniCreditBank         2.1         Private foreign
Raiffeisenbank        2.1         Private foreign
VTB-24                2.0         State
Rosbank               1.7         Foreign

Source: OECD 2009

Table 5: Selected Russian state crisis measures until end 2008

Aim                         Amount ($)       Source

Russian corporate           50 billion       Central Bank of Russia
debt financing                               (CBR) reserves

Investment support          15 billion       Federal budget

Capital boost for banks     35 billion       CBR and (NWF)

Financial market support:   18 billion       National Welfare Fund
stock and bonds                              (NWF)
buy-backs

Construction industry       5 billion        Federal budget
support

Oil industry support        6 billion        Federal budget

Liquidity support for       (i) 83 billion   CBR
banks                       (ii) Variable

Aim                         Delivery vehicle

Russian corporate           Vnesheconombank
debt financing

Investment support          Corporate profit tax reduced
                            to 20% (from 24%)

Capital boost for banks     Direct infusion

Financial market support:   Vnesheconombank
stock and bonds
buy-backs

Construction industry       Construction and demolition
support                     of new (military and social)
                            and old housing

Oil industry support        Reduced calculation period on
                            export duty calculations

Liquidity support for       (i) Short-term deposits,
banks                       reduced reserve requirements,
                            unsecured lending
                            (ii) Daily repo operations

Source: www.businessneweurope.eu

Table 6: Banks with the state participation

Beginning 2009                    Samruk-Kazyna   Bank assets
(February)                            stake       (million $)

Kazkommerts                           0.25           18855
BTA                                   0.75           15910
Halyk                                 0.25           11790
Alliance *                            0.76           6624
Total for the four large banks                       53179
Other 33 banks                                       26305
Total for banking sector                             79484

Beginning 2009                    Bank equity   Bank deposits   P/B
(February)                        (million $)    (million $)

Kazkommerts                          2794           14023       0.65
BTA                                  1244           15257       0.37
Halyk                                1137           10666       0.45
Alliance *                           1049           4797        0.16
Total for the four large banks       6223           44743
Other 33 banks                       3402           16395
Total for banking sector             9625           61138       0.76

Source: Samruk-Kazyna data
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有