Crisis and growth in the advanced economies: what we know, what we do not, and what we can learn from the 1930s.
Eichengreen, Barry
INTRODUCTION
As this paper is drafted, it has become commonplace to observe that
there is a high degree of uncertainty about the course of the economy.
Those making this observation are typically concerned with the high
level of uncertainty surrounding the short-term growth prospects of the
advanced economies: whether the expansion now underway will continue or
be interrupted by a double dip. I would like to suggest that a
comparably high degree of uncertainty surrounds the question of whether
the medium- and long-term growth potential of the advanced economies has
been impaired. This uncertainty arises for three reasons.
First, experience in other recent recessions is of dubious
relevance to the current episode. Typically, studies of this question
have looked at the trend rate of growth and its determinants before and
after a set of banking crisis dates. The crises considered are
heterogeneous: while some are as serious as the recent episode, others
are considerably less so. (1) Financial crises also differ in how
effectively they are resolved; growth experience following the Swedish
crisis of the early 1990s, in the wake of which damage to the banking
system was repaired relatively quickly, is unlikely to tell us much
about the medium-term effects of the current crisis. Whereas the crises
considered are, with few exceptions, idiosyncratic national events, the
recent crisis infected the entire OECD; thus, the opportunity for
individual countries to export their way out of domestic difficulties
did not arise to anywhere near the same extent in the recent episode.
Where previous studies look at growth performance in the wake of banking
crises, the recent episode is more than just a crisis for the banking
system. It affected the shadow banking system and securitization markets
at the same time it affected the banks, and in some cases it affected
them even more powerfully.
Second, empirical work focusing on aggregate effects is
inconclusive and unconvincing. Estimating what has happened to the trend
rate of growth as a result of a crisis presupposes an ability to
estimate the trend. This is something on which economists do not agree.
Growth potential is not constant in the absence of a crisis. A
pre-crisis trend estimated over a relatively long period may under-state
pre-crisis growth potential and therefore overlook post-crisis damage if
productivity growth was accelerating prior to the crisis. Recall the
'new economy' argument that US productivity growth accelerated
around the middle of the 1990s due to the adaptation to new information
and communications technologies. If there really was and is a new
economy, then attempting to measure the trend rate of growth over a
longer period will underestimate it. Alternatively, measuring pre-crisis
growth over a shorter period, say as growth between the two immediate
pre-crisis business-cycle peaks, creates the danger that estimates of
the trend will be distorted by peculiar features of the cyclical
expansion and the unsustainable growth that sowed the seeds for the
crisis itself. This approach will tend to over-estimate pre-crisis
growth and exaggerate the damage. It is no surprise, then, that studies
seeking to identify changes in trend growth before and after crises
reach a variety of conclusions.
Third, there is little agreement on the relative importance of the
mechanisms through which major recession and financial distress may
impact long-term growth potential. Some analysts emphasize the danger
that investment will fail to recover because the return to capital will
have fallen permanently as a result of the crisis and the misallocation
of pre-crisis investment. Financing constraints will be tighter because
bank balance sheets have been impaired, because borrowers have less
collateral, and because of tighter regulation. Finance being harder to
come by, there may be less investment in research and development and
related activities that throw off positive externalities for growth.
Other observers emphasize the pernicious effects of the policy
uncertainty that inevitably arises in a crisis and its aftermath. The
list goes on. Public debt loads will be higher in the wake of a crisis:
this implies higher taxes and interest rates. Structural and hard core
unemployment will rise, causing skill acquisition on the job to suffer.
Labor force participation will be discouraged. The long-term unemployed
will become demoralized and apathetic. Finally, there is the danger
that, the problems that brought on the crisis not having been
dispatched, instability may be back. (2)
In the remainder of this paper, I will argue that progress on
determining whether growth potential been impaired will occur through
research on specific mechanisms through which recession and financial
distress affect growth capacity. I will suggest that historical evidence
from earlier episodes like the 1930s, when the recession was deep, the
crisis was global, and financial distress was pervasive, is a promising
source of information on the issues at hand.
On the basis of this evidence, I will argue that there is little
reason to think that the long-term growth potential of the advanced
economies has been significantly impaired, at least insofar as such
damage operates through the standard economic channels. Neither
financing constraints, nor public debt burdens and structural
unemployment was a binding constraint on long-term economic growth in
the wake of the Great Depression. Insofar as the conclusions carry over,
it is unlikely that they will be binding constraints today.
Rather, the operative constraint in the 1930s was fractionated,
polarized politics that resulted in reactive policies. Where such
policies predominated, they hindered the economy's adjustment to
its new circumstances and depressed productivity growth. If one is
concerned to avoid permanent damage from the crisis, this is the channel
of which to beware.
The next section first elaborates my argument about the
inconclusiveness of studies using aggregate data on GDP growth in an
effort to determine whether growth potential is impaired by crises. The
two subsequent sections then consider specific mechanisms through which
crises may lead to secular growth slowdowns--damage to the financial
system, increased public debt, heightened policy uncertainty, structural
unemployment, and less spending on research and development--and tests
them against data from the Great Depression. The penultimate section
highlights the danger that the political polarization may prevent a
constructive policy response. The final section concludes.
LIMITS OF AGGREGATE EVIDENCE
To be clear, there is no disagreement about the existence of losses
from financial crises in the form of output losses that are not made up
subsequently. Recessions associated with crises are unusually severe.
(3) This fact comes through not just in recent data but in historical
experience, and it is even more clearly true of global financial crises
than of isolated national events. (4) Even true believers in
Zarnowitz's Law--that unusually deep recessions are followed by
unusually strong recoveries--do not argue that these output losses are
fully made up subsequently. At best, growth resumes, following the
crisis and recovery, at the same trend rate as before, but the level of
GDP is now lower at each point in time than in the counterfactual with
no crisis. In a graph with time on the horizontal axis and log GDP on
the vertical axis, the new trend line is parallel to the old trend line
but below and to its right. Worse still is if growth potential has been
permanently impaired, in which case the new trend line is flatter and
the gap between actual and counterfactual log GDP widens progressively
over time.
But if there is a presumption in the literature, it is that
permanent growth effects are minimal. Furceri and Mourougane (2009) find
that a financial crisis lowers output by 1.5%-2.4% and that a severe
crisis reduces output by 4%, but they find no evidence of it reducing
the economy's subsequent capacity to grow. IMF (2009) similarly
finds that there is no rebound to the pre-crisis trend but again
concludes that in most cases the trend rate itself is not depressed in
the medium term: growth resumes at the pre-crisis rate but from a lower
level. OECD (2010) puts the OECD-wide decline in potential output due to
the recent crisis at 3% but sees no evidence of the decline in potential
rising over time. Haugh et al. (2009) look at the trend of labor
productivity and total factor productivity (TFP) growth in the 10 years
before and after crises and again conclude that there is little evidence
of a downward shift.
These same studies, however, emphasize the heterogeneity of country
experiences, reflecting the heterogeneity of crises and of how
effectively they are managed. Haugh et al. (2009) find a sharp downshift
in labor and TFP growth rates between the 10 years before and after the
onset of the Japanese crisis. They find negative effects around the time
of the Nordic crises of the early 1990s when they limit the comparison
to the 5 years before and after the event. IMF (2009) points to cases in
which there is evidence of lower employment and a lower capital/labor
ratio following crises. In these episodes, TFP growth typically recovers
from the low levels plumbed during the crisis, but not entirely.
As noted, the limitation of these analyses--and the difficulty of
knowing what to generalize from them--is the difficulty of measuring the
pre-crisis trend rate of growth. Crises often follow booms that bias
upward estimates of the pre-crisis trend. Some authors, Krugman (2010)
for example, dispute the implication: they argue that there is nothing
wrong with using data from the pre-crisis boom and estimating the trend
on the basis of peak-to-peak interpolation. The boom, in this view, may
affect what is being produced (in the most recent case, more housing and
financial services, fewer other goods and services) but not the
economy's capacity to produce.
Others who see the boom as pushing investment and capacity
utilization beyond sustainable limits will not be convinced. Their
approach is therefore to estimate the pre-crisis trend excluding the
years preceding the crisis. In IMF (2009, p. 125), the Korean economy
around the time of the 1997 financial crisis is used to illustrate this
approach. First, a trend line is fit to output growth between 1987 and
1994. The 3 years immediately preceding the crisis are omitted from this
trend calculation on the grounds that the economy may have been
expanding unsustainably during the pre-crisis boom. This pre-crisis
trend is then compared to post-crisis growth in the period 1998-2004.
The two lines--the extrapolation of pre-crisis output and actual
post-crisis output--first evolve in parallel but subsequently show signs
of diverging, as if the capacity of the economy to grow was permanently
impaired.
This Korean example inadvertently illustrates the problem with the
methodology. After more than two decades of rapid growth, the Korean
economy's capacity to grow was already declining in the late 1980s.
(5) The labor force began expanding more slowly. The pool of
underemployed labor in agriculture had been drained. Slower growth was a
natural corollary of economic maturity. But this fact was disguised by
the unsustainable investment binge of 1990-1997, which the
country's large conglomerates financed by issuing debt and raising
their leverage to ultimately dangerous heights. The investment/GDP ratio
rose from the 30% typical of the 1970s and 1980s to nearly 40% before
returning to its customary 30% following the crisis. Much of the
additional investment in the intervening period was of dubious utility
and productivity--this was when the chaebol branched into unrelated
businesses far removed from their core competencies. (6) The implication
is that the trend rate of growth prior to the crisis is over-estimated
even when the 5 immediate pre-crisis years are excluded; hence the
extent of any post-crisis decline in the trend is also exaggerated.
Note that this is the opposite of the illustration in the
introduction, where a relatively recent acceleration in the potential
rate of growth causes the pre-crisis trend to be underestimated and
post-crisis damage to be understated. Either way, mechanical
calculations yield misleading results. It seems unlikely, therefore,
that analyses of aggregate data can succeed in resolving the issue.
Rather, determining whether long-term growth potential has been impaired
will require studying the specific mechanisms through which financial
crises affect the economy over time.
FINANCIAL DISTRESS
When one considers specific mechanisms through which a financial
crisis may affect the growth potential of the economy, the obvious place
to start is impairment of the financial system. Weakly capitalized banks
will be reluctant to lend. Having been burned in the crisis, they will
adopt tighter lending standards. Aspiring borrowers, having suffered
balance sheet damage, will have less collateral and be less credit
worthy. More stringent regulation adopted in response to the crisis
requires financial institutions to hold more capital and liquid assets
and to otherwise restrain their lending. The more limited supply of bank
credit will mean a higher cost of capital. The lesser availability of
finance will mean less investment. This effect is most likely to be felt
by smaller, younger firms (start-ups) that are disproportionately the
source of innovation and employment growth in normal times, that cannot
expand on the basis of internal funds, and that find it difficult to tap
securities markets. (7)
In the Great Depression, the evidence of a persistent slump in bank
lending is overwhelming (Figures 1 and 2), but evidence of a persistent
impact on investment and growth is weak. First, to the slow recovery of
lending: in part this reflected balance-sheet problems. Using
state-level data, Calomiris and Mason (2003) show that banks with less
capital and more real-estate assets in their portfolios (and therefore
more losses due to foreclosures) grew their loans more slowly in the
1930s. In part, it reflected the flight from risk and scramble for
liquidity by all banks. Calomiris and Wilson (2004), analyzing
individual bank data, find that banks curtailed their lending and
shifted into holding more liquid, less risky assets (primarily cash and
treasury securities) following depositor runs in 1931-1933. (8) Banks
cut the share of loans in their portfolios not just by limiting new
lending but by allowing existing loans to run off as they matured. In
1934-1940, FDIC-insured commercial banks held as much as 30% of their
assets in cash, 37% in treasury bills and other liquid securities, and
only 28% in loans (FDIC, 2008).
But, did the limited availability of bank credit slow the recovery?
Between 1933 and 1957 the US economy grew by more than 8% a year. There
was also a reasonable recovery of investment in the 1930s. (See Figure
3) A pair of survey by the National Industrial Conference Board found
only limited evidence of borrowing difficulties. (9) In 1932 (when the
problem was presumably at its peak), 86% of the responding industrial
firms indicated either no borrowing experience or no difficulty in
obtaining bank credit. It could be, of course, that the large number of
respondents reporting no recourse to bank credit reflected the depressed
circumstances of the time (no demand meaning no investment plans). (10)
Alternatively, many firms may have been intent on deleveraging as a way
of reducing their vulnerability to financial disturbances (analogous to
the argument sometimes made nowadays that the slow growth of bank
lending reflects not the weakness of the banks but the reluctance of
firms and households to borrow). (11)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
In the 1932 survey, the firms reporting difficulty in borrowing
were disproportionately small. (12) Since, in normal circumstances,
these small firms and start-ups are disproportionately the source of
innovation, this observation does not bode well for productivity growth.
But the 1930s were not normal circumstances; I return to this below.
In the aftermath of the recent crisis, OECD (2010) estimates that
two-thirds of the fall in potential output will reflect a higher cost of
capital, which will reduce the capital/labor ratio. However, it assumes
that the increase in the cost of capital will be 150 basis points, which
seems like a large number. The Institute of International Finance
(2010), in analyzing the impact of more stringent capital and liquidity
requirements, assumes very large increases in bank lending rates and
concludes that these could reduce global GDP by as much as 3% between
2010 and 2015. (13) Other analysts, such as the Bank for International
Settlements, dispute not just the magnitude but the existence of these
effects, putting the upper bound in terms of cumulative growth impact at
less than 1%. (14) One suspects that if there are long-term effects from
more limited credit availability, these will come from the stricter
application of existing regulations at the national level more than from
new capital standards promulgated in Basel. And one suspects that the
major impact will be on more credit-intensive activities and sectors
rather than the growth of the economy as a whole.
PUBLIC DEBT
Another plausible channel through which crises can lead to slower
growth is by leaving an overhang of public debt. Reinhart and
Rogoff's (2009) stylized fact, based on experience in 13 post-World
War II financial crises, is that the real value of public debt roughly
doubles in the 3 years following onset. (15) The increase is due to a
combination of lower tax revenues, reflecting output losses, and
increases in public spending taken in response to the crisis. Higher
debt burdens imply higher future taxes and higher interest rates, other
things equal, pointing to lower levels of investment and slower rates of
growth. (16)
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The 'other things equal' caveat is a big one. The
argument that government deficits leading to higher levels of debt crowd
out private investment and depress growth operates mainly through higher
interest rates, and there is less than abundant evidence of upward
pressure on interest rates in the United States and other advanced
economies at the moment. (17) Deficit spending directed at
recapitalizing a weak banking system and stabilizing economic activity,
by restoring confidence, may do more to encourage investment than
depress it. The debt ratio may also rise insofar as the economic
conditions are depressed and deflationary (that is to say, for other
reasons). Slow growth may cause heavy indebtedness rather than the other
way around.
The 1930s is again an obvious battleground for the competing
schools. The US public debt/GDP ratio more than doubled from 17% in 1929
to 40% in 1933-1937. This was certainly a period of depressed capital
formation: stocks of both equipment and structures were lower in 1941
than they had been in 1929. But it was not a period of high interest
rates; as in recent years precisely the opposite was true. (See Figure
4) Arithmetically, the main factor behind the rise in the debt ratio was
the fall in nominal GDP by nearly 50% between 1929 and 1933. The swing
in the federal government deficit as a percentage of Gross National
Product between 1929 and 1933 was a relatively modest 4%; this is
telling us that the rise in indebtedness was mainly driven by the fall
in GDP, not the other way around.
POLICY UNCERTAINTY
Thus, those seeking to argue that government policy discouraged
investment and otherwise impaired the environment for growth must look
elsewhere. In the literature on the 1930s, as in the recent period, they
look to the possibility that policy uncertainty increased the option
value of waiting. Friedman and Schwartz (1963) argue that business
confidence was weakened by uncertainty about the implications of new
regulatory measures for the business environment: they cite, among other
regulatory interventions, the Securities Act of 1933, the Securities
Exchange Act of 1934, and the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933. Higgs (1999)
is the definitive modern exponent of this point of view, arguing that
'pervasive uncertainty among investors about the security of their
property rights in their capital and its prospective returns'
depressed private investment from the mid-1930s all the way up to World
War II. His list of problematic policies is long. He points to tax
policy (the Wealth Tax of 1935, a tax on incorporate dividends,
increases in estate and gift taxes, increases in surtaxes on high
incomes, and a graduated surtax on corporate earnings), and the tax
increases imposed under the guise of 'closing loopholes' in
the 1937 Tax Act. He points to the abrupt reversal of some of these
measures by the Congress in 1938-1939. He points to the uncertain
consequences of the National Labor Relations Act, creation of the
Temporary National Economic Committee in 1938, uncertainty about the
enforcement of antitrust laws by the Department of Justice, and new
regulation of securities markets by the Securities and Exchange Act. In
arguments that anticipate recent criticism of President Obama for his
allegedly anti-business rhetoric, he points to Roosevelt's
criticism of business as creating a more uncertain business climate.
Arguments hinging on the existence of perceived uncertainty and an
unobservable hostile-to-business climate are intrinsically difficult to
test, notwithstanding the depressed level of investment that is their
alleged consequence. Higgs looks at time variation in investment and in
the composition and policies of the Roosevelt Administration. He argues
that 1938 saw a significant change in the makeup of the Roosevelt
Administration, with the replacement of dedicated New Dealers by
pro-business men, together with a stronger Conservative Coalition
opposing the New Deal after the 1938 congressional election; this was
followed by a substantial rise in gross private investment in 1939 and
again in 1940. But the rise in investment is equally attributable to
other factors, such as recovery from a 1937-1938 recession that was
widely attributed to the Fed's decision to raise reserve
requirements.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Fortunately for us, an earlier paper by Mayer and Chatterji (1985)
looks directly at the impact of policy shocks and other variables on
industrial equipment orders and investment in non-residential
structures. The authors construct dummy variables for the major policy
innovations and shocks of the period and find no evidence that it was
these as opposed to other plain-vanilla determinants of investment like
the cycle that drove investment spending.
An alternative hypothesis is that investment will recover fully
only once capacity utilization returns to normal levels. This was the
explanation for the less-than-complete recovery of investment of the
original historian of US capacity utilization in the 1930s (Streever,
1960). Capacity utilization in US industry fell from 83% in 1929 to 42%
in 1932; at its peak in 1937 it just matched the 1929 level of 83%
before falling back again in 1938 and 1939. A level of 83% does not
suggest inadequate capacity; this is more-or-less normal levels of
utilization by second-half-of-20th-century standards. Moreover, the 1929
level was also down considerably from the earlier part of the decade
(See Figure 5). (18)
The bulk of the evidence, then, suggests that the failure in the
1930s of investment to recover more fully reflected not crowding out or
policy uncertainty but the continuing low level of capacity utilization.
The latter was a legacy of the singular depth of the slump. It was
something that solved itself eventually--in the event, with the
intervention of World War II. This suggests that, with growth and with
time, there is no reason why investment cannot again recover to
pre-crisis levels.
STRUCTURAL UNEMPLOYMENT
Another worry is that a rise in structural unemployment will reduce
labor input and efficiency. It is harder to grow when you have to
retrain construction workers and hedge fund managers to work as welders
and nurses, as will be the case when the economy is undergoing
structural change--including when it is rebalancing away from
unsustainable activities that boomed before the crisis. The mismatch
between skills supplied and demanded will then constrain the growth of
employment. Firms may not be able to find workers with the requisite
training and experience. One currently hears complaints from
manufacturing firms of a shortage of, inter alia, machinists--see Bowers
(2010). Similarly, workers lacking the skills and experience demanded
may find it more difficult to find their way out of a crisis. The
outward shift in the Beveridge Curve starting in 2009 Q2 (Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 2010) is at least superficially consistent with
this view. (19) More generally, there is evidence that unemployment is
concentrated to an unusual extent in the current recession among
individuals previously with long-term jobs who are now faced with the
challenge of finding new jobs in different sectors.
Similar complaints about shortages of qualified machine-shop and
tool-room workers were voiced in the midst of high unemployment in the
1930s (Allen and Thomas, 1939). Motor vehicle manufacturers in
Oxfordshire complained that Welsh coalminers lacked both the skills and
attitudes required of productive factory workers (Heim, 1983). Regional
labor market problems and geographical disparities are similarly evident
in the recent recession, accentuated by housing market declines which
leave homeowners with negative equity hesitant to sell and by
exceptional distress in traditionally vibrant areas like California and
Florida which have traditionally absorbed workers from declining
regions. (20) More generally, mismatch is a theme in studies of the
British labor markets in the 1930s (see for example, Booth and Glynn,
1975). Dimsdale et al. (1989) develop an empirical measure of the extent
of mismatch in interwar Britain, summing the absolute value of the
change in the shares of total employment across 27 industries. (21) They
show that a high level of mismatch moderates the downward pressure on
real wages normally exerted by a rise in the number of unemployed
workers, in turn limiting employment and output growth in their model.
(22)
Figure 6 displays their mismatch index (the sum of absolute changes
in the shares of total employment across 27 industries as described in
the previous paragraph). Not surprisingly, it is procyclical, rising
with the onset of the slump in the early 1930s, falling when recovery
commences in 1932, and then rising again sharply with the 1937-1938
slowdown. With capital goods industries hit especially hard in the
slump, it is not surprising that the dispersion of employment growth
rates moved so strongly with the cycle. (23)
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
But the other striking feature of the figure is that the mismatch
index falls quickly and sharply with recovery after 1931. Evidence of
structural unemployment dissolves, it would appear, with the recovery of
aggregate demand. This suggests that present-day evidence of structural
unemployment will similarly dissolve in the face of economic growth.
Figure 7 shows the analogous mismatch index for the United States,
constructed from data from Table Ba814-840 of Historical Statistics of
the United States. Again, the pattern is strongly procyclical. Compared
to the United Kingdom, the peak in the 1930s is later, reflecting the
fact that the first full year of recovery is 1934. Once again, however,
evidence of persistent structural unemployment dissolves in the face of
economic recovery.
Then there are worries about hysteresis due to the concentration of
joblessness among a hard core of long-term unemployed. There is some
evidence that unemployment in the current cycle is concentrated among a
hard core of long-term unemployed to a greater extent than in the
preceding recessions. (24) The same was true of the 1930s. Woytinksy
(1942) describes the US unemployed as subject to two very different
patterns, pointing to 'the existence of two contrasting groups
among the unemployed: persons who have a fair chance of reemployment in
the near future, and those who remain out of jobs for considerable
periods of time'. (25) Jensen (1989) estimates that structural and
hard core unemployment accounted for fully half of US unemployment in
1935 and an even higher fraction of the total in subsequent years. (26)
Crafts (1987) similarly documents the exceptionally high incidence of
long-term unemployment in 1930s Britain.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
The pernicious effects of long-term unemployment are well known.
Skills acquired on the job atrophy when off it. Individuals experiencing
long-term unemployment tend to become demoralized and apathetic. (27) An
influential 1933 study by Paul Lazarsfeld and associates of the Austrian
town of Marienthal painted this picture in detail, as did a 1938 study
of England by the Pilgrim Trust. (28) Crafts (1987) cites commentary
from the 1930s to this effect for the United Kingdom from both private
commentators and policy authorities. (29)
The long-term unemployed may also become stigmatized in the eyes of
employers. Jensen (1989, p. 556) writes of the long-term unemployed in
the United States and United Kingdom in the 1930s that '(e)mployers
distrusted their job qualifications; they would not hire them for any
reason at any wage'. This problem particularly afflicted older
workers: 'Some entry into the hard core resulted ... when
middle-aged workers became, at age 45 or 50, "too old" '.
Together, these mechanisms imply a decline in the efficiency of
labor utilization and in growth capacity, underscoring the damage to
growth potential from long-term unemployment.
TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS
Another worry is that technological progress may slow as a result
of the crisis. Research and development, especially by small firms and
startups, is sensitive to the availability of bank funding, as noted
above. R&D has a long lead time, which means that the effects of
financial disruptions can be persistent.
Nabar and Nicholas (2009) observe that there was a drop in R&D
activity in the early 1930s due to the depth of the economic collapse
and tighter financial constraints. (30) But this history also points to
the possibility of a more positive outcome. Rather than being depressed
as the previous perspective would suggest, TFP growth in the 1930s in
the United States was unusually fast. Between 1929 and 1941, TFP growth
ran at an annual average compound rate of growth of 2.3%, faster than in
the first two decades of the century, faster than in the 1920s, faster
than during World War II, and faster than in the second half of the 20th
century. (31)
The external effects of capital deepening cannot explain this, as
noted: net stocks of both equipment and structures did not rise over the
period. The phenomenon was not simply mis-measurement of labor input:
while there was probably some tendency for firms to retain their most
skilled and productive workers in the downturn, the fact that both 1929
and 1941 were business cycle peaks suggests that the contribution of
this factor was limited. Rather, there was a fundamental reorganization
of operations in a variety of industries. The example given in Field
(2009b) is the railroads, which suffered from severe financial shocks
(Schiffman, 2003), a depressed economy, and competition from road (and
nascent air) transport. Managers fought back by figuring out how to use
their labor and capital more efficiently, through inter alia more
efficient scheduling and continuous utilization of freight cars, changes
in staffing practices, and so forth.
Field refers to this as the 'adversity effect': to
survive in the face of adverse demand conditions, firms have to figure
out how to cut costs and raise efficiency. Koenders and Rogerson (2005)
present a model that predicts (or rationalizes) this behavior. In their
framework, firms invest in internal reorganization at the cost of
diverting resources from more immediate uses. In periods of high
economic activity, organizations postpone structural changes to take
advantage of more immediate opportunities. In periods of low activity,
they do the opposite.
While Koenders and Rogerson do not apply it to the 1920s and 1930s,
their framework has two implications consistent with that historical
experience. One is a continued high unemployment rate following the
shock: once immediate opportunities dissipate and the firm turns to
reorganization, it is less likely to hire because reorganization is less
labor intensive than current production. The second is that the effects
in question will be stronger following a long expansion like that of the
1920s. The longer the expansion, during which the firm will have focused
on production rather than reorganization, the larger will be the backlog
of potential structural changes. Looking at post-1964 experience,
Koenders and Rogerson show that the longer the preceding expansion, the
more jobless but also efficiency enhancing is the subsequent recovery.
1921-1929 was the longest unbroken expansion in US history up until the
expansion of the 1991-2001 (the case that motivates their study); hence
the same logic plausibly applies.
There are hints that what was true of railroads in the 1930s was
also true, broadly speaking, of the manufacturing sector. As factories
were idled, firms had more opportunity to adapt factory layout and
raw-material flow to the availability of the small electric motors that
became available in the 1920s. More firms adopted the modern personnel
management practices pioneered by a handful of large enterprises in
preceding years. (32) More firms set up in-house research laboratories
to develop new methods and products; in a period when overall employment
was stagnant, total R&D employment in US manufacturing rose from
6,274 in 1927 to 10,918 in 1933 and 27,777 in 1940, despite double digit
unemployment (Mowrey, 1982). With less pressure to push product out the
door, more time and effort could be devoted to commercializing new
technologies like neoprene and nylon. Firms could experiment with new
materials like plastics and alloy steels. They could experiment with
instrumentation capable of saving both capital and labor. They could
invest in new chemical processes for extracting minerals and processing
agricultural materials. (33)
These examples of technologically progressive firms in the 1930s
are disproportionately large 'Chandlerian' firms in a position
to pioneer the commercialization of complex technologies, able to build
in-house research labs and personnel departments, and in a position to
reorganize large existing factories to take advantage of electric
motors. These were not the kind of small firms and start-ups most
heavily impacted by the limited availability of bank credit (see above).
The question for our time, of course, is whether small or large firms
will be the locus of innovation and productivity growth going forward.
POLICY AND POLITICS
Crises can also catalyze efficiency enhancing public-policy
initiatives. It can be argued that the economic and financial crisis of
the early 1930s catalyzed a whole host of economic policy changes that
limited instability and set the stage for faster and more successful
growth. Those of us who live in the San Francisco Bay Area and rely on
the San Francisco-Oakland and Golden Gate Bridges cannot help but recall
that the federal government contributed to the build-out of the road
network and otherwise financed growth-friendly infrastructure
investments in the depressed conditions of the 1930s. Government dealt
with threats of financial instability through the adoption of deposit
insurance and other bank regulatory measures. The Federal Reserve Act of
1935 centralized monetary policy decision making at the Board,
preventing disagreements between regional reserve banks from again
immobilizing central bank policy. Social welfare policies from
unemployment insurance to social security were put in place, ensuring a
fair sharing of the burden of adjustment and providing the social
foundations for the post-World War II golden age of economic growth.
(34)
The recent literature suggests that certain kinds of economies are
most likely to respond in efficiency enhancing ways to economic and
financial crises. (35) These are economies with cohesive, stable,
centrist political systems that are able to equitably share out the
costs of adjustment, compensate the losers, and facilitate rather than
resist adjustment. The United States, which adopted not just
unemployment insurance and Social Security but also the Reciprocal Trade
Adjustment Act, was evidently able to do just that.
But other countries, such as the United Kingdom, were less
successful. The response of British TFP growth to the crisis of the
1930s, in both the short and longer terms, was decidedly less positive.
(36) Broadberry and Crafts (1990, 2003) show that many of the policies
put in place in the 1930s--import restraints, the absence of an
effective anti-trust policy, and the heavy regulation of public
utilities, for example--created enduring obstacles for productivity
growth. As they put it, 'The response of British industry to the
Depression of the 1930s was a further retreat from competition, a
process already well under way from the depressed conditions of the
1920s. There was a substantial increase in concentration, brought about
primarily by a merger boom during the 1920s ... Furthermore ... the
1930s saw the introduction of a General Tariff'. (37) In the
absence of competition, rent seeking by cloistered management became
pervasive. Rather than systematically restructuring, industries like
cotton textiles and iron and steel were cartelized and protected from
foreign competition to avoid further short-term falls in employment. For
a quarter of a century, political control then swung back and forth
between a hard-line Labor Government and equally hard-line
Conservatives. Politics were fractionalized and fragmented. There was
little serious talk of burden sharing. Policy was stop-go. Not until the
1980s was the legacy of the interwar Depression finally cleared away.
These observations about political structure are not reassuring
about the growth prospects of the United States today. Is its political
system, with strong inter-party competition and checks on the executive,
conducive to a positive response to the crisis? Or have there been
changes in American politics that have rendered the political system
more polarized and less capable of mounting a coherent response to the
crisis?
CONCLUSION
This analysis of impacts of the Great Depression on the long-term
growth potential of the advanced economies highlights the following
points. First, the impact of weak bank balance sheets and increased risk
aversion on the part of lenders in the wake of the Depression was mainly
felt by smaller, younger firms. But with large firms enjoying access to
other sources of funding and retained earnings growing reasonably
strongly after 1933, it is hard to conclude that this had a first-order
impact on capital spending or output growth. Second, there is little
evidence that increased public debt or policy uncertainty had major
effects in depressing investment. Third, while there was extensive
structural and long-term unemployment in the 1930s, this also declined
relatively quickly once sustained recovery set in. Fourth, the crisis
was also an opportunity, as firms used the downtime created by the
Depression to reorganize and modernize their operations in ways that
boosted productivity growth. But creating a policy environment where
they had an incentive to do so required political compromise of a sort
that can be difficult given the polarizing effects of financial crises.
Mark Twain is alleged to have once said 'History does not
repeat itself, but it does rhyme'. (38) There is no certainty, in
other words, that the impact on long-term growth potential of the
2007-2009 financial crisis will be the same as the impact of the Great
Depression. Indeed, the more carefully policy makers study Depression
experience and the more successfully they avoid the errors of their
predecessors, the more likely it is that the aftermaths of the two
crises will differ.
REFERENCES
Allen, RGD and Thomas, B. 1939: The supply of engineering labour
under boom conditions. Economic Journal 49: 259-275.
Bank for International Settlements. 2010: An assessment of the
long-term economic impact of the new regulatory framework. BIS: Basel.
Booth, A and Glynn, S. 1975: Unemployment in the interwar period: A
multiple problem. Journal of Contemporary History 10: 610-628.
Bordo, M, Goldin, C and White, E. 1998: The defining moment: The
great depression and the American economy. University of Chicago Press:
Chicago, IL.
Bordo, M and Landon-Lane, J. 2010: The global financial crisis: Is
it unprecedented? Unpublished manuscript, Rutgers University, August.
Bowers, C. 2010: Skilled labor shortage frustrates employers,
www.cbsnews.com, 11 August.
Broadberry, S and Crafts, N. 1990: The impact of the depression of
the 1930s on productivity potential in the United Kingdom. European
Economic Review 34: 599-607.
Broadberry, S and Crafts, N. 2003: UK productivity performance from
1950 to 1979: A restatement of the Broadberry-Crafts view. Economic
History Review 56: 718-735.
Calomiris, C and Mason, J. 2003: Consequences of bank distress
during the great depression. American Economic Review 93: 937-947.
Calomiris, C and Wilson, B. 2004: Bank capital and portfolio
management: The 1930s 'capital crunch' and the scramble to
shed risk. Journal of Business 77: 421-456.
Cavallo, A and Cavallo, E. 2008: Are crises good for long term
growth: The role of political institutions. IDB Working Paper no. 643,
August.
Cole, H and Ohanian, L. 2004: New Deal policies and the persistence
of the great depression: A general equilibrium analysis. Journal of
Political Economy 112: 779-816.
Crafts, NFR. 1987: Long-term unemployment in Britain in the 1930s.
Economic History Review, 2nd set. XL: 418-432.
Dimsdale, NH, Nickell, SJ and Horsewood, N. 1989: Real wages and
unemployment in Britain during the 1930s. Economic Journal 99: 271-292.
Dowling, T, Estevao, M and Tsounta, E. 2010: The great recession
and structural unemployment in United States, Selected Issues, Country
Report no 10/248, IMF: Washington, DC, July.
Eichengreen, B. 1987: Unemployment in interwar Britain: Dole or
doldrums? Oxford Economic Papers 39: 597-623.
Eichengreen, B, Perkins, D and Shin, K. 2011: From miracle to
maturity: The growth of the Korean economy. Harvard Asia Center for the
Korea Development Institute: Cambridge, MA.
Eisenberg, P and Lazarsfeld, PF. 1938: The psychological effects of
unemployment. Psychological Bulletin 35: 358-390.
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. 2008: Historical statistics
on banking. FDIC: Washington, DC.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. 2010: Employment survey delivers
JOLTS. Quarterly Review of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta (Spring): 6-17.
Field, AJ. 2006: Technological change and U.S. productivity growth
in the interwar years. Journal of Economic History 66: 203-236.
Field, AJ. 2009a: Uncontrolled land development and the duration of
the depression in the United States. Journal of Economic History 52:
785-805.
Field, AJ. 2009b: Do economic downturns have a silver lining?
Unpublished manuscript, University of Santa Clara, November.
Friedman, M and Schwartz, A. 1963: A monetary history of the United
States, 1865-1960. Princeton University Press for the National Bureau of
Economic Research: Princeton, NJ.
Fryer, D and Fagan, R. 2003: Toward a critical community
psychological perspective on unemploy-ment and mental health research.
American Journal of Community Psychology 32: 89-96.
Furceri, D and Mourougane, A. 2009: The effect of financial crises
on potential output: New empirical evidence. OECD Economics Department
Working Paper no.699, OECD: Paris, May.
Hatton, TJ. 1985: The British labor market in the 1920s: A test of
the search-turnover approach. Explorations in Economic History 22:
257-270.
Hatton, TJ. 1986: Structural aspects of unemployment in Britain
between the world wars. Research in Economic History 10: 55-92.
Haugh, D, Ollivau, P and Turner, D. 2009: The macroeconomic
consequences of banking crises in OECD countries. OECD Economics
Department Working Paper no.683, OECD: Paris, March.
Helm, C. 1983: Industrial organization and regional development in
interwar Britain. Journal of Economic History 43: 931-952.
Higgs, R. 1999: Regime uncertainty: Why the great depression lasted
so long and why prosperity resumed after the war. Independent Review 1:
561-590.
Institute of International Finance. 2010: Interim report on the
cumulative impact on the global economy of proposed changes in the
banking regulatory framework. Institute of International Finance:
Washington, DC.
International Monetary Fund. 2009: What's the damage?
Medium-term output dynamics after financial crises. World Economic
Outlook. IMF: Washington, DC pp. 121-151.
Jacoby, S. 1985: Employing bureaucracy: Mangers, unions and the
transformation of work in the 20th century. Columbia University Press:
New York.
Jahoda, M, Lazarsfeld, P and Zeisel, H. 1972: Marienthal: The
Sociography of an Unemployed Community. Tavistock: London reprint.
Jensen, RJ. 1989: The causes and cures of unemployment in the great
depression. Journal of Interdisciplinary History XIX: 553-583.
Katz, L. 2010: Comment on 'the labor market in the great
recession'. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring): 1-48.
Kimmel, L. 1939: The availability of bank credit 1933-1938.
National Industrial Conference Board: New York.
Koenders, K and Rogerson, R. 2005: Organizational dynamics over the
business cycle: A view on jobless recoveries. Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Review 87: 555-580.
Koo, R. 2009: The holy grail of macroeconomics. Wiley: New York.
Krugman, P. 2010: Getting trendy. 23 July.
Lee, J and Wong, K. 2003: Overinvestment and the financial crisis:
The case of Korea. Unpublished manuscript, University of Washington,
July.
Leonhardt, D. 2010: For those with jobs, a recession with benefits.
10 August.
Machin, S and Manning, A. 1998: The causes and consequences of
long-term unemployment in Europe. Centre for Economic Performance
Discussion Paper 400, July.
Matthews, RCO, Feinstein, C and Odling-Smee, J. 1982: British
economic growth. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Mayer, T and Chatterji, M. 1985: Political shocks and investment:
Some evidence from the 1930s. Journal of Economic History XLV: 913-924.
Mowrey, D. 1982: The emergence and growth of industrial research in
American manufacturing 1899-1946. Unpublished dissertation, Stanford
University.
Nabar, M and Nicholas, T. 2009: Uncertainty and innovation at the
time of the great depression. Unpublished manuscript, Wellesley College
and Harvard Business School, January.
National Industrial Conference Board. 1932: The availability of
bank credit. National Industrial Conference Board: New York.
OECD. 2010: Prospects for growth and imbalances beyond the short
term. OECD Economic Outlook 88 (April): 232-262 Consump.
Orwell, G. 1937: The road to Wigan Pier. Victor Golancz: London.
Reinhart, C and Rogoff, K. 2009: The aftermath of financial crises.
NBER Working Paper no. 14656, January.
Robb, A and Robinson, D. 2009: The capital structure decisions of
new firms. Unpublished manuscript, UC Santa Cruz and Duke University,
February.
Schiffman, D. 2003: Shattered rails, ruined credit: Financial
fragility and railroad operations in the great depression. Journal of
Economic History 63: 802-825.
Streever, D. 1960: Capacity utilization and business investment.
University of Illinois Bulletin 86/76.
Tomassi, M. 2004: Crisis, political institutions and political
reform: The good, the bad, and the ugly. In: Tungodden, B, Stern, N and
Kolstad, I (eds). Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics:
Europe. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Weidner, J and Williams, J. 2010: Update of 'how big is the
output gap?' Unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, 18 August.
Weiland, J. 2009: Bank lending during the recovery from the great
depression. Unpublished manuscript, University of California, Berkeley,
May.
Woytinksy, WS. 1942: Three aspects of labor dynamics. Social
Science Research Council: Washington, DC.
BARRY EICHENGREEN
University of California, Evans Hall 508, CA 94708 Berkeley, USA.
E-mail: eichengr@econ.berkeley.edu
(1) Consider Canada in 1983-1985, France in 1994-1995, Germany in
1976-1979, and the Savings and Loan crisis in the United States in the
early 1980s, for example.
(2) This observation highlights another issue. In the wake of the
crisis, the US will have to rebalance away from the production of
housing in favor of merchandize and away from consumption in favor of
net exports. A decline in the US real exchange rate that makes the
country's merchandize exports more attractive to foreign consumers
is a necessary part of this adjustment. That decline can occur either
through a fall in US dollar prices (deflation) or depreciation of the
dollar exchange rate; this way of putting it makes clear why American
policy makers prefer a controlled depreciation of the dollar. The
problem is that other countries are reluctant to see their currencies
rise. At the time of writing, recovery in the other advanced economies
is weak, making stronger currencies the last thing that they need.
Emerging markets, for their part, are reluctant to abandon a model of
export-led growth that has served them well. They see export-oriented
manufacturing as a locus of learning by doing and productivity
spillovers and worry that their competitiveness would be damaged by
excessive real appreciation. But, absent nominal exchange rate changes,
we will either see the same adjustment occur through other less
desirable mechanisms (deflation in the US and/or a further acceleration
of inflation in emerging markets), or else the US current account
deficit will widen again. Since US indebtedness to the rest of the world
cannot rise indefinitely (especially if the denominator of the foreign
debt/GDP ratio is growing more slowly), sooner or later something will
have to give, presumably in the form of a sudden sharp fall in the value
of the dollar like that warned of by some observers before the crisis.
This, however, is the subject of another paper.
(3) See for example IMF (2009).
(4) See Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) and Bordo and Landon-Lane
(2010).
(5) If one mechanically uses statistical methods to pinpoint the
break in the trend, the computer places it in 1989--midway through the
period when the authors of the IMF fit a single linear trend. See
Eichengreen et al. (2011).
(6) Businesses that they often liquidated subsequent to the crisis.
On explanations for the over investment phenomenon in Korea in this
period, see Lee and Wong (2003).
(7) Thus, Robb and Robinson (2009) show that start-ups rely on bank
credit for their financing needs to an unusual extent, all the
high-profile attention attracted by the venture capital industry
notwithstanding.
(8) Their sample of banks is for New York City.
(9) See National Industrial Conference Board (1932) and Kimmel
(1939).
(10) The two occasions that saw upticks in loans outstanding were
1939 and 1940-1941, which were the only times in the 1930s when late
1920s levels of capacity utilization were reached and a substantial
number of firms felt compelled to borrow for capacity expansion
(Weiland, 2009).
(11) See Koo (2009).
(12) A substantial fraction of the firms in question reported that
they would not have experienced comparable difficulties in more normal
financial-market conditions. The 1939 study concluded that the majority
of loan refusals reflected changes in the instructions given loan
officers ('bank policy') and not the condition of the
borrowing firm or its industry.
(13) In other words, it could reduce growth by as much as a fifth.
(14) See Bank for International Settlements (2010). In any case,
there has been agreement since the earlier Institute of International
Finance analysis (for better or worse) on scaling back proposed
increases in capital and liquidity requirements and delaying their
implementation for as long as 7 years.
(15) The precise increase averages 86%.
(16) With the deficit currently running at 10% of national income,
the US debt/GDP ratio is now reaching the 90 % threshold where the
authors argue that these growth-reducing effects kick in with a
vengeance.
(17) Greece is a different story, but the contrast is, presumably,
instructive.
(18) Another possibility is that investment is depressed in the
post-crisis period not so much by the crisis itself as the nature of the
pre-crisis investment boom. Residential construction will remain
depressed in the wake of a housing boom that leaves the residential
sector overbuilt. Investment will be less productive and slower to
recover insofar as complementary investments made before the crisis
embody an economic structure and expectations that no longer prevail. To
continue with the case of housing, new investment is more costly insofar
as prior encumbrances (how the land was subdivided, for what uses it was
zoned) are difficult to change, and when existing structures have to be
demolished in order for new ones can be built. Field (2009a) suggests
that such encumbrances (excessive sub-development, poorly planned
infrastructure investment) depressed the construction sector all through
the 1930s. Developers wishing to build multiple units within a
subdivision had to incur heavy costs to reassemble subdivided acreage
(something complicated by the sheer difficulty of tracking down the
individual plot owners), demolish inappropriate improvements, and adapt
preexisting site hookups and street layouts. One is reminded,
inevitably, of recent arguments about the difficulty of replacing
McMansions with green housing.
(19) More detailed analyses by Dowling et al. (2010) and Weidner
and Williams (2010) suggest that the natural rate of unemployment has
risen by 1.5% to 2.8% points since the onset of the crisis purely as a
result of the mismatch problem.
(20) On this, see Katz (2010).
(21) Data taken from British Labour Statistics.
(22) The alternative interpretation, now largely discredited (on
this, see Hatton, 1985 and Eichengreen, 1987), is that generous
unemployment benefits discouraged search activity. One hears today the
same argument that the extension of unemployment benefits has shifted up
the level of unemployment for any level of vacancies. But Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta (2010) shows that even making a generous
adjustment for this factor is not enough to eliminate the shift in the
Beveridge curve. There is an analogous set of arguments for the US,
centering on New Deal policies (Cole and Ohanian, 2004) for which this
author does not hold much brief.
(23) A further notable feature of the series is the relatively high
level of mismatch in the mid1920s, this being a period when commentators
referred to the international competitive difficulties of Britain's
old industries (the so-called staple trades): textiles, coal, and iron
and steel, and shipbuilding. The literature on the interwar period
emphasized spatial as well as industrial mismatch, pointing to the much
higher unemployment rate in 'Outer' than 'Inner'
Britain as an additional dimension of mismatch that slowed labor-market
adjustment (Inner Britain being London, the Southeast, the Southwest,
and the Midlands). Even adjusting for differences in industrial
composition, some regions displayed persistently higher unemployment
rates (Hatton, 1986). This suggests that the problem was more than just
the fact that some industries are more cyclically sensitive than others.
(24) See Leonhardt (2010). At the time of writing, the share of the
unemployed out of work for more than 27 weeks was nearly double that of
any other post-World War II recession.
(25) Woytinksy (1942), p. 67.
(26) He reports for cities like Buffalo that the share of the
unemployed who had been out of work 1 year or more rose from 9% in 1929
to 21% in 1930 to 43% in 1931 to 60% in 1932 and 68% in 1932; the share
of the male labor force in this condition rose from 0.5% in 1929 to 20%
in 1932.
(27) Machin and Manning (1998) provide survey evidence from 1990s
Europe that individuals' self-worth deteriorates as a result of
unemployment.
(28) Marienthal was banned by the Nazis soon after publication, and
all extant copies were burned. The republication is Jahoda et al.
(1972). In the psychological effects in particular, see Eisenberg and
Lazarsfeld (1938). A companion study for the modern period is Fryer and
Fagan (2003).
(29) George Orwell described the effect in The Road to Wigan Pier:
'It is only when you lodge in streets where nobody has a job, where
getting a job seems about as probable as owning an aeroplane and much
less probable than winning 50 pounds in the Football Pool, that you
begin to grasp the changes that are being worked out in our
civilization'.
(30) And also because of the perceived rise in uncertainty
associated with the structural transformation of the economy. At the
same time, they provide evidence that firms were able to learn about the
nature of these shifts and redirect their R&D investments by the
late 1930s.
(31) By Field's (2006) calculations, TFP growth averaged 1.08%
in 1900-1919, 2.02% in 1919-1929, 2.31% in 1929-1951, 1.29% in
1941-1948, 1.90% in 1948-1973, 0.34% in 1973-1989, and 0.78% in
1989-2000.
(32) See Jacoby (1985).
(33) Field (2006), p. 216.
(34) See Bordo et al. (1998). The reader will have noted that that
this is the opposite of how the policy response of the 1930s is
characterized by the regime-uncertainty school. The two views can
probably be reconciled in practice. Policy reforms that are supportive
of growth in the longer run can still heighten uncertainty in the short
run, making immediate post-crisis recovery more difficult. It is not
inconceivable that both effects resulted from the Great Depression.
(35) See inter alia Tomassi (2004) and Cavallo and Cavallo (2008).
(36) See Matthews et al. (1982).
(37) Broadberry and Crafts (1990), p. 603.
(38) Twain scholars have disputed the accuracy of the attribution.