The evolution of the finance growth nexus.
Wachtel, Paul
Modern growth theory dates back to the mid-1950s, only a little
more than 50 years ago, to the contributions made by Robert Solow and
others. Solow's neoclassical production function approach
attributes growth to the quantity of capital and labour inputs and a
catchall residual factor that is now called total factor productivity
(TFP). Early productivity studies tended to attribute growth to capital
deepening, improvements in labour quality (human capital investments)
and the adoption of new technologies.
The approach reached its zenith in the early 1990s with a
controversial literature on the rapid growth of the East Asian
economies. Page (1994) distinguishes between the fundamentalist and the
mystic explanation for the 'East Asian miracle'. The
fundamentalists stress the role of factor accumulation; they attribute
growth to high savings rates and capital accumulation, and human capital
development as an educated population moved into the active labour
force. The mystics place greater emphasis on the acquisition and mastery
of technology that leads to growth in TFP. The controversy goes beyond
the analytics of the sources of growth. The mystics, unlike the
fundamentalists, were likely to support interventionist government
development policies. The fundamentalist
view of growth in East Asia seems to have won the debate although the
argument regarding the efficacy of interventionist industrial policies
remains unsettled.
Over time, empirical applications of the Solow framework tended to
focus more and more on TFP. The great American productivity slowdown in
the 1970s and 1980s (the period between the oil shocks and the high-tech
boom) was attributed to many factors, but most analyses concluded that
there was a decline in TFP growth (Baily and Gordon, 1988). Such a
conclusion was very disquieting because it attributed changes in the
growth rate to a great unknown, the residual. Therefore, it comes as no
surprise that economists began to think about the sources of differences
in TFP growth. For example, the fundamentalists understood that East
Asian resource accumulation was very different from the similarly large
levels of accumulation in the Soviet Union and other planned economies.
It is now clear that the Soviet system had an uncanny ability to
misallocate enormous amounts of capital goods. However, the ability to
allocate resources efficiently is difficult to measure and, as an
omitted variable, would be reflected in differences in TFP growth.
Although the efficiency of allocation may be difficult to measure,
some of its determinants are known. Specifically, financial
intermediaries bring savers and investors together in a way that directs
savings into the most productive investments. The pooling of information
and the creation of financial instruments both induces more investment
activity and promotes efficient allocations. Thus, a country with a more
developed or more extensive financial system is likely to grow more. A
market-oriented financial sector promotes the efficient allocation of
resources. And, clearly this element was missing in the Soviet system.
Although the role of the financial sector was not a new idea, it
was largely forgotten by development economists who often called for
explicit manipulation of financial markets through subsidies, directed
credit, interest rate controls and other means in order to achieve
development objectives. However, over time, more market-oriented
discussions of the role of the financial sector, such as Goldsmith
(1969) and McKinnon (1973), began to attract attention.
This new understanding of the role of the financial sector in
economic growth began to take root in the early 1990s with a growing
empirical literature on the role of financial sector development in
economic growth. Later in the decade, a broader literature began to
emerge that related economic growth to the quality of institutions
generally. Financial intermediaries and the quality of intermediation
are only one of many institutional features that assist growth
(Acemoglu, 2008). Legal structures that reduce transactions costs,
defined property rights, reliable governance and social norms all
contribute to an institutional structure that encourages growth. In this
broader literature, financial institutions are just one part of the
puzzle. Nevertheless, given the role of the financial sector in capital
accumulation, it is worthwhile to focus attention on this particular set
of institutions.
To explore the role of financial institutions, the empirical
literature needed an available measure of the extent of financial
development. Quickly, and perhaps mistakenly, the role of financial
institutions came to be defined by the size of the sector's
activity. That is an economy with more intermediary activity was assumed
to be doing more to generate efficient allocations. Increases in the
quantity of intermediation were assumed to be synonymous with increases
in the quality. The size of the financial sector is usually measured by
the quantity of intermediation relative to GDP.
Using World Bank World Development Indicators data, there are 97
countries with a population of over 1 million and financial depth data
(ratio of domestic credit to the private sector to CDP) for both 1985
and 2005. We will use this sample here to look at the data underlying
the finance growth nexus. Table 1 groups the countries by financial
depth quartiles in 1985. The unconditional relationship to the average
growth rate in the subsequent 25-year period is striking; countries with
more intermediation grew more rapidly. The mean growth rate of countries
in the highest depth quartile is almost six times larger than that of
countries in the lowest quartile. The median growth rates do not differ
as much but the nexus relationship is clear. However, there are some
other things that come out of this table as well. Countries with greater
initial financial depth are also richer and experience more (absolute)
deepening of their financial markets over the period.
There is now an extensive econometric literature that examines this
finance growth nexus with other determinants of growth held constant and
with the most sophisticated techniques to control for the simultaneity
of growth and financial depth. Robert Barro (1991) and Robert King and
Ross Levine (1995) pioneered the use of cross-country panel data to
examine the relationship, while Paul Wachtel and Peter Rousseau (1995)
developed evidence based on long time series for the few countries with
available data. The literature grew rapidly and has been eloquently
summarised by its champion and major contributor, Ross Levine, at least
three times (1997, 2005, 2008). By the end of the 1990s, the
finance-growth nexus was a well-established part of the economic canon.
Typical results from either cross section or panel studies indicate
that the effect of credit deepening on economic growth, conditioned on a
standard set of variables that typically includes initial income, human
capital and trade openness, is quite large. Although Rousseau and
Wachtel (2011) show that the strength of the relationship has diminished
in recent years, strong results are found for the period from 1965 to
1990. A regression of the real per capita GDP growth rate on private
credit as a percent of GDP typically yields a coefficient of about 0.02.
To understand the impact of deepening, compare Greece with a credit
ratio of 77.7% in 2005 to Australia with 103.7%. If financial markets in
Greece were as deep at those in Australia, its growth rate would have
been about 0.5 percentage points higher. Looking over time, Greek credit
markets deepened from 37.8% to 77.7% from 1985 to 2005, which increased
its growth rate by about 1 percentage point. That is, credit deepening
accounted for about one-half of the Greek growth rate over this 20-year
period. Similar calculations are found in Demirguc-Kunt and Levine
(2008).
My concern here and in earlier work (Wachtel, 2001, 2004) is that
the empirical literature might have over stated the strength of the
nexus. Much of the literature relies on cross-country studies to draw
causal inferences from financial deepening to growth. There is wide
country-to-country variation in the credit to GDP ratios, even for
countries at similar levels of economic development, which are probably
due to differing institutional structures in the financial industry and
in patterns of enterprise financing. Moreover, the cross-country
variation in financial depth is much larger than the within-country
variation over time for most countries.
Figure 1 illustrates the potential problem. There are two countries
each with a positive relationship between financial depth and the growth
rate over time, shown by the distribution of data within each oval. If
the cross-country panel studies do a poor job of correcting for country
differences, then the overall slope is given by the between-country line
rather than the within-country line. Financial deepening in country A to
level X is likely to have a moderate effect on the growth rate rather
than the effect suggested by the cross-country regression slope. In this
case, it would be wrong to draw any causal inferences from the estimated
cross-country effects of substantial financial deepening on economic
growth. The issue is whether the finance growth nexus is driven by
within-country relationships or the comparison between countries. The
large effects of deepening on growth found in the literature might
indicate that the econometric results do not adequately account for
reverse causality. Perhaps, following Joan Robinson, enterprise leads
and finance follows.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Looking at the experiences of individual countries may provide a
better understanding of the issue. To begin, Table 2 presents some
summary statistics for the sample of 97 countries. The table provides
summary statistics, which indicate that there has been large variation
across countries in the change in financial depth. There is wide
variation in the financial depth of countries; the 25th percentile is
just 17%, while the 75th percentile is 88%. There is also a great deal
of variation in the amount of financial deepening experienced over the
20-year period, either measured by the percentage point change or the
proportional (percent) change in the ratio. However, we see that the
median financial depth in 2005 is about the same as in 1985. Many
countries experience financial deepening but 26 had less financial depth
in 2005 than in 1985. The deepening is concentrated among developed
countries many of which have increased debt levels substantially. This
last observation raises some questions about the finance growth nexus.
If most of the financial deepening in the last 20 years reflects
increased use of leverage by businesses and households in already
developed countries, then it might not be offering strong support for
the nexus.
A further step to examine the deepening experiences is to look at
individual countries. Five countries in the sample experienced large
deepening over the 20-year period; that is, increases in the financial
depth ratio over 100 percentage points and another five exhibited
increases between 50 and 100 percentage points (Table 3). The average
growth rate for these countries is 2.21% (2.43% if we exclude South
Africa), which is slightly larger than the average for all high-income
countries, 2.07%. Some of these countries exhibited growth spurts, using
the definition in Babych (2010). However, half of these spurts started
before the financial deepening (in the 1980s), while only the other half
(starting in the 1990s) might be considered as the consequence of
financial deepening.
Many less developed countries and even some developed countries
start the period with shallow financial markets, very small credit to
GDP ratios. Thus, it is also interesting to look at the 20 countries
where the credit to GDP ratio more than doubled between 1985 and 2005.
This list includes many of the developed countries shown above with
large absolute increases in financial depth. In Table 4, we eliminate
those countries (and also two additional relatively high-income
countries, Belgium and Greece) and show the less developed countries
that had the largest proportional increases in financial depth. The
average growth rate among these countries was 2.17%, substantially more
than the average for all low-income countries, which was 1.54%. In
summary, it appears that among more developed countries financial
deepening is just as likely to be a cause as an effect of growth. Among
less developed countries significant deepening is associated with above
average growth.
Looking at the experiences of individual countries over time may
shed some more light on how the finance growth nexus operates. There are
several econometric studies of causality with long run time series data
including Rousseau and Wachtel (1998) and Rousseau and Sylla (2002).
These papers make a convincing case for the hypothesis that financial
deepening causes growth and that reverse causality is minimal. However,
a look at some of the actual data might be additionally informative.
Figure 2a shows a broad measure of financial depth for the US from 1870
to 1929. The doubling of financial depth that took place from 1880 until
the First World War coincides with the industrial development of US
economy. But the additional quick spurt in deepening starting in 1925 is
associated with the credit boom and increasing stock prices.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
More recent US data is shown in Figure 2b. Flow of funds data is
used to show the total debt of the domestic non-financial sectors to GDP
(upper line) and private domestic non-financial debt to GDP (lower
line). There have been three distinct episodes of financial deepening in
the US in the last 50 years. The private debt ratio increased by about a
quarter between 1960 and 1974 although the total debt ratio was
constant. Larger deepening episodes occurred between 1980 and 1988 and
since the mid-1990s when both measures increased by almost half. The
first episode is associated with a period of growth but also inflation
in the last few years, which encouraged greater use of debt. The latter
two periods of financial deepening ended with financial crises, the
stock market crash in 1987 and a recession in 1990 in the first instance
and the recent financial crisis in the latter case.
How should we interpret these episodes of financial deepening in
the US? Do they represent periods of financial innovation and deeper
financial activity, which improved resource allocation and contributed
to the growth of the economy? Or do they represent periods of increased
leverage and risk taking, which may have temporarily increased growth
and may also have precipitated financial crises?
Observers of US economic history emphasise the contribution of the
financial system to growth. The emergence of a robust banking system in
the early 19th century and the development of capital markets towards
the end of the century were important forces that made the US
world's richest nation. However, by the mid-20th century the
financial system was mature and it became more difficult to identify
financial sector innovations that increased the quality of intermediary
services. Thus, one would be hard pressed to associate the 1980s and
1990s episodes of financial deepening with improvements in the efficacy
of the financial system.
The link between financial deepening and financial crises is made
clear in recent work that examines crisis episodes. In particular, the
recent global financial crisis has brought the role of financial
deepening or credit booms under scrutiny. Reinhart and Reinhart (2010)
look at 15 late 20th century severe financial crises (including emerging
markets, the Asian financial crises in 1997 and advanced economies such
as Japan and the Scandinavian banking crises). They describe the
commonalities of the 10-year pre-crisis periods. In each instance, there
was a surge in the ratio of domestic bank credit to GDP prior to the
crisis. The median increase was 38.4 percentage points and the
deleveraging in the post-crisis decade was about the same proportional
size. The run up of the credit to GDP ratio in the decade prior to 2007
in the nine countries that experienced systemic crisis was even larger,
about 60 percentage points.
The role of credit deepening as a possible cause of crisis is found
earlier in Radelet and Sachs (1998) in their analysis of financial
crises in emerging market countries. A significant variable in their
probit model to predict severe reversals in capital flows is the
'private credit build-up', the increase over 3 years in the
ratio of private sector financial claims to GDP. Of course, examining
financial crises, still relatively rare events, does not preclude the
finance growth nexus. It only goes to show that financial depth is a bit
of a chameleon; in some contexts it is a determinant of economic growth
and in others it is a precursor of crisis. One person's salubrious
financial deepening is another person's financial crisis in the
making.
Even without a financial crisis, there are difficulties in
interpreting financial deepening experiences. Consider the case of
Croatia where monetary stabilisation and the end of hostilities led to
rapid growth in intermediation in the late 1990s (see Kraft and Jankov,
2005). By all accounts, this was viewed as a desirable deepening.
However, a banking crisis in 1998-1999 led to a contraction of credit.
The banking crisis was short-lived and within a year there was a
consolidation of the banking sector and privatisation to foreign owners.
A second credit boom ensued and by 2006 domestic credit to the private
sector exceeded 70% of GDP, more than double the level of a decade
earlier but still not unusually high for a middle-income country.
Mindful of the earlier experience, the Croatian National Bank responded
to the credit boom by putting a tax on rapid lending growth and a
marginal reserve requirement on foreign borrowing. In this instance,
policymakers tried to distinguish between the gradual deepening of the
financial sector and a credit boom and were able to prevent the
formation of a credit bubble.
The financial sector's influence on economic growth is a
complex phenomenon. At the very least, an understanding of the
finance-growth nexus requires better measurement, as well as better
theory. Aggregate data on credit to GDP ratios are useful because it is
possible to abstract from national institutions and make formal
cross-country and historical comparisons. However, the recent
experiences described here make abundantly clear that the financial
depth ratios are a poor description of the finance growth nexus. The use
of financial depth ratios in the vast empirical literature (and
generalisations such as adding the ratio of equity market capitalisation
to GDP) are a matter of convenience more than choice.
Theoretical arguments about the role of the financial sector relate
to the amount or quality of intermediary activity, which need not be the
same as the extent to which an economy is leveraged. With this in mind,
Thomas Philippon (2008) examines the share of the financial sector in
GDP in the US going back over 100 years. Figure 3 from Philippon shows
that there have been several periods of rapid increase in the share.
With one exception, Philippon associates these bursts in activity with
periods of innovation when young, cash-poor firms require finance:
The financial industry was around 1.5% of GDP in the mid-19th
century. The first large increase between 1880 to 1900 corresponds
to the financing of railroads and early heavy industries. The
second big increase between 1918 and 1933 corresponds to the
financing of the electricity revolution, as well as automobile and
pharmaceutical companies ... After a continuous collapse in the
1930s and 40s, the GDP share of finance and insurance industries
was down to only 2.5% of GDP in 1947. It recovered slowly and was
mostly stable at around 4% until the late 1970s, and then grew
quickly to reach 8.3% of GDP in 2006. The third large increase,
from 1980 to 2001, corresponds to the financing of the IT
revolution.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The one exception of course is the rapid increase after 2002.
Philippon's modelling suggests that a bubble in this period
resulted in a financial sector that was about 10 % larger than justified
by economic fundamentals.
It is reasonable to ask why the literature on the finance growth
nexus has leaned so heavily on financial depth ratios to measure
intermediary activity. The answer is most likely the availability of the
data. A debt to GDP ratio can be defined unambiguously and data are
available across countries and over time. More nuanced data on the
activities of financial intermediaries, the patterns of enterprise and
household financing and the nature of innovations in the industry would
be difficult or impossible to gather. Looking at the specific activities
of the financial sector that contribute to growth would be very
difficult. Financial innovations (eg derivatives, securitisation, etc)
are valued because they facilitate the functioning of the sector but
they are difficult to measure. Thus, the literature relies on what is
essentially the lowest common denominator in the data.
Moreover, there is considerable skepticism about the value of
financial innovation. A comment made by Paul Volcker in December 2009
has been widely quoted in this regard:
I wish somebody would give me some shred of evidence linking
financial innovation with benefit to the economy.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The ATM is the one innovation in the past 25 years that he was
willing to cite:
It really helps people. It's useful.
There is one type of data that might be additionally informative.
That is, as suggested earlier, the contribution of the financial
services industry to GDP. The UN national accounts provide data for 121
countries but data availability is limited prior to the 1990s.
Nevertheless, it is worthwhile to see which countries and which type of
countries have larger financial sectors as measured by their relative
contribution to output and further to see whether the financial sector
activity by this measure is increasing.
Start with Figure 4, which shows the financial intermediary sector
as a fraction of GDP for the G8 countries. There is considerable
variation in the size of the sectors among the G8. On average it is
largest in the US, followed by the UK and Japan. The average ratio in
the US is 7.74% and slightly below 5% in France, Germany and Italy.
There is a positive linear trend, significant at the 5% level, in
Germany, Japan, Russia and the US.
Differences in the size of financial sectors across all countries
are summarised in Table 5. For countries in each income group, we
examine the annual median of the ratio of intermediary activity to GDP.
(1) The role of financial intermediation in GDP increases with the level
of income in a country. Further, it is increasing over time in wealthy
and poor countries. Some of the variation among countries is related to
inflation shocks; the financial sector balloons in countries
experiencing very high inflation as resources are diverted to cope with
the costs of inflation. The relationship between the size of the
financial industry measured in this way and economic growth remains to
be examined.
Two years past the global meltdown, where does the finance-growth
nexus stand? All in all, it is relatively unscathed but it appears to
stand on much shakier ground than was thought. Although the econometric
evidence is convincing, our understanding of how and when a growing
financial industry translates into better growth prospects is very
limited. Thus, increasing credit depth should not be viewed as a policy
prescription for growth since increased leverage might just as soon be
associated with credit bubbles and increased risk. The development of
the financial sector needs to be embedded into a broader story of
developing institutions, the legal structure that makes the financial
system work more effectively.
All in all, what we have learned is not that finance is unimportant
but, instead, how difficult it is to measure financial sector activity
properly. Rather than looking at credit to GDP ratios, we should make an
effort to measure different aspects of intermediary activity. For
example, what proportion of new enterprises obtain external financing,
how long does it take to obtain finance, how easy is it for enterprises
to do so. Direct measurement of what financial intermediaries do would
help pinpoint the role of finance in the productive process.
Acknowledgements
The author appreciate assistance and comments from Josef Brada,
Paolo Cavallino, Claudia Curi and Peter L Rousseau.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D. 2008: Growth and institutions. In: Durlauf, SN and
Blume, LE (eds). The new Palgrave dictionary of economics. Palgrave
Macmillan, http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?
id=pde2008_G000174, doi: 10.1057/9780230226203.0687, accessed 2 May
2011.
Babych, Y. 2010: Political regime changes and the turning points of
economic growth. Tbilisi Georgia Working paper, International School for
Economics, November.
Baily, MN and Gordon, RJ. 1988: The productivity slowdown,
measurement issues, and the explosion of computer power. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity 19(2): 347-420.
Barro, RJ. 1991: Economic growth in a cross section of countries.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 7-43.
Demirguc-Kunt, A and Levine, R. 2008: Finance, financial sector
policies, and long-run growth. Commission on Growth and Development
Working paper no. 11.
Goldsmith, R. 1969: Financial structure and development. Yale
University Press: New Haven, CT.
King, RG and Levine, R. 1993: Finance and growth: Schumpeter might
be right. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108: 717-737.
Kraft, E and Jankov, L. 2005: Does speed kill? Lending booms and
their consequences in Croatia. Journal of Banking and Finance 29:
105-121.
Levine, R. 1997: Financial development and economic growth: Views
and agenda. Journal of Economic Literature 35: 688-726.
Levine, R. 2005: Finance and growth: Theory and evidence. In:
Aghion, P and Durlauf, SN (eds). Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 1A.
Elsevier North Holland: Amsterdam. pp. 865-934.
McKinnon, RI. 1973: The order of economic liberalization. Brookings
Institution: Washington, DC.
Page, J. 1994: The East Asian miracle: Four lessons for development
policy. NBER Macroeconomics Annual: 219-269.
Philippon, T. 2008: The evolution of the US financial industry from
1860 to 2007: Theory and evidence. NYU Stern School working paper,
November.
Radelet, S and Sachs, JD. 1998: The East Asian financial crisis:
Diagnosis, remedies, prospects. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:
1-74.
Reinhart, CM and Reinhart, VR. 2010: After the fall. Jackson Hole
Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, August.
Rousseau, PL and Sylla, R. 2002: Financial system, economic growth
and globalization. In: Bordo, M, Taylor, A and Williamson, J (eds).
Globalization in Historical Perspective. University of Chicago Press:
Chicago, IL.
Rousseau, PL and Wachtel, P. 1998: Financial intermediation and
economic performance: Historical evidence from five industrialized
countries. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30: 657-678.
Rousseau, PL and Wachtel, P. 2011: What is happening to the impact
of financial deepening on economic growth? Economic Inquiry 49(1):
276-288.
Wachtel, P. 2001: Growth and finance: What do we know and how do we
know it? International Finance 4(3): 335-362.
Wachtel, P. 2004: How much do we really know about growth and
finance? Research in Banking and Finance (4): 91-113.
Wachtel, P and Rousseau, PL. 1995: Financial intermediation and
economic growth: A historical comparison of the United States, United
Kingdom and Canada. In: Bordo, MD and Sylla, R (eds). Anglo-American
Financial Systems, Chapter 10. Burr Ridge, IL: Irwin. pp. 329-381.
PAUL WACHTEL
Stern School of Business, New York University, 44 West 4th Street,
New York, NY 10012, USA. E-mail:
pwachtel@stern.nyu.edu
(1) The median is a better measure than the mean because the
composition of countries included can vary from year to year and the
mean is affected by outliers. The sample begins when there are at least
five countries in the group with available data.
Table 1: Averages for countries in 1985 financial depth quartiles
Financial Financial GDP per capita Growth rate,
depth, 1985 deepening 1985- 1985 (in 2005 1985-2005
(domestic 2005 (change in $) (median in
credit to financial parentheses)
private sector depth)
to GDP)
1 182.2 30.4 15,870 2.40 (1.95)
2 241.9 20.8 11,307 1.68 (1.74)
3 322.2 9.8 5,040 1.38 (1.37)
4 410.2 4.1 1,698 0.42 (1.02)
Table 2: Summary statistics
Financial Financial Change in financial
depth ratio depth ratio depth ratio
1985 2005 1985-2005
25th percentile 15.63 16.58 -3.26
Median 29.82 30.83 6.72
75th percentile 57.44 87.82 25.98
Mean 38.82 54.95 16.13
Standard deviation 30.09 51.21 33.45
% change in Annual Growth rate,
financial depth real per capita GDP
1985-2005 1985-2005
25th percentile -16.64 0.24
Median 22.54 1.69
75th percentile 80.81 2.38
Mean 41.55 1.46
Standard deviation 94.15 2.03
Table 3: Countries with largest absolute deepening
Countries with largest increases Growth rate, Growth Spurt
in credit to GDP ratio 1985-2005 (Babych)
Denmark 1.67 NA
Ireland 5.25 1994
United Kingdom 2.38 1982
Canada 1.69 1996
New Zealand 1.37 --
United States 1.93 --
Spain 2.71 1984.1996
Portugal 2.80 1980
Australia 2.09 --
South Africa 0.24 NA
NA: Not applicable.
Table 4: Countries with largest proportional deepening
Less developed countries with Largest Growth rate,
proportional increase in financial depth ranked 1985-2005
Ghana 1.92
Burundi -1.59
Nepal 2.02
Mauritius 4.21
Uganda 2.74
Bangladesh 2.63
Bolivia 1.24
Ethiopia 1.19
Botswana 4.86
Costa Rica 2.46
Table 5: Financial inteshare of G DP
Country income group Dates Mean of annual 5% significant
(number) medians positive trend
High (34) 1970-2007 5.10 Yes
Upper middle (30) 1989-2008 4.13 No
Lower middle (31) 1988-2008 3.87 No
Low (26) 1990-2008 1.65 Yes
Source: United Nations data base, World Bank country classification