首页    期刊浏览 2025年06月17日 星期二
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:New evidence on fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies.
  • 作者:Segura-Ubiergo, Alex ; Simone, Alejandro ; Gupta, Sanjeev
  • 期刊名称:Comparative Economic Studies
  • 印刷版ISSN:0888-7233
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Association for Comparative Economic Studies
  • 摘要:There is consensus in the literature on the crucial role played by initial conditions, macroeconomic stabilization, and structural reforms on growth patterns in transition economies. (1) The consensus on macroeconomic stabilization is reflected in that most studies of growth performance in transition economies include variables that measure the impact of inflation and generally find a negative relationship between inflation and growth. (2) However, there has been no conclusive evidence on fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies. As Havrylyshyn (2001) noted, 'the empirical literature is nearly unanimous on the negative impact of inflation on growth but has not been able to disentangle the separate effects of fiscal deficits and inflation on growth'. In fact, the fiscal balance is much less widely used in cross-country studies of growth performance (eg Fischer et al. (1996, 1997); Wolf, 1999; Fischer and Sahay, 2000; Berg et al., 2006). (3) A recent study (Purfield, 2003) does not find a clear relationship between fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies.
  • 关键词:Economic forecasting;Economic growth;Fiscal policy;Transition economy

New evidence on fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies.


Segura-Ubiergo, Alex ; Simone, Alejandro ; Gupta, Sanjeev 等


INTRODUCTION

There is consensus in the literature on the crucial role played by initial conditions, macroeconomic stabilization, and structural reforms on growth patterns in transition economies. (1) The consensus on macroeconomic stabilization is reflected in that most studies of growth performance in transition economies include variables that measure the impact of inflation and generally find a negative relationship between inflation and growth. (2) However, there has been no conclusive evidence on fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies. As Havrylyshyn (2001) noted, 'the empirical literature is nearly unanimous on the negative impact of inflation on growth but has not been able to disentangle the separate effects of fiscal deficits and inflation on growth'. In fact, the fiscal balance is much less widely used in cross-country studies of growth performance (eg Fischer et al. (1996, 1997); Wolf, 1999; Fischer and Sahay, 2000; Berg et al., 2006). (3) A recent study (Purfield, 2003) does not find a clear relationship between fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies.

This empirical evidence seems at odds with the widely held view that fiscal adjustment is a necessary condition for growth when fiscal deficits threaten macroeconomic stability. Agenor and Montiel (1999) survey the theoretical literature and conclude that fiscal adjustment is crucial for attaining macroeconomic stability. Excessive fiscal deficits may lead to inflation, balance of payments difficulties, external debt crises, and high real interest rates, outcomes that tend to reduce economic growth. Case studies in the literature also show that permanent fiscal adjustment is critical to uproot inflation that hurts growth. Moreover, Havrylyshyn and van Rooden (2005) and World Bank (2002) argue that growth during economic transition is likely to be driven by vast resource reallocation, efficiency improvements, and increased international trade and investment, and thus policy instruments that facilitate these changes, such as fiscal adjustment, can strongly affect growth even after accounting for the initial conditions and institutions.

The empirical literature on fiscal policy and growth also shows that healthy budget balances are good for growth over the long run. While the effect of fiscal adjustment in the short run remains open to question, a large body of empirical research finds salutary long-term effects of fiscal adjustment. (4) However, a number of studies in industrial countries have found that improving fiscal positions can stimulate growth even in the short run. A central theme in these works is that the composition of fiscal adjustment plays a key role in determining whether fiscal contractions sustain and support higher growth over time. (5) Gupta and et al. (2005a, b) show that these results can largely be extended to emerging market and low-income countries.

This paper focuses on whether fiscal adjustment affects growth in transition economies. This issue is analyzed using a sample of 26 transition economies covering the period 1992-2001. Building on the existing literature discussed above, this paper also contributes to the discussion of whether the relationship between fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies is different from other country groups.

The results suggest that the impact of fiscal adjustment on growth in transition economies is robust and not qualitatively different from what has been observed in industrial, emerging market, and low-income economies. The positive correlation between fiscal adjustment and growth is stronger for countries that need to achieve macroeconomic stability. In particular, the sustained fiscal consolidation efforts in the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) have been accompanied by accelerations in growth in the sample. (6) However, for countries that have already achieved macroeconomic stability, the relationship between fiscal adjustment and growth is less clear. (7) A fixed-effects panel error-correction model that controls for initial conditions, structural reforms, and inflation confirms the strong positive correlation of fiscal adjustment and growth. In addition, the positive effect of fiscal adjustment holds in the short and long run.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: the next section describes the empirical methodology and the data. The following section discusses some stylized facts on growth and fiscal adjustment in transition economies. Finally, we discuss the main econometric results. The last section concludes.

EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY AND SAMPLE

Overall approach

The overall approach in conducting the empirical test starts with a general framework that covers all key factors that affect growth in transition economies. These factors are based on the existing literature, which includes variables that measure initial conditions, institutions, and degree of macroeconomic stabilization. As shown in Havrylyshyn et al. (1998) and Havrylyshyn and van Rooden (2003), these are the three main categories of factors in explaining growth in transition economies. For example, Krueger and Ciolko (1998) and Popov (2000) find that initial conditions explain substantial variations in growth performance during transition, and institutional capacity is also a key determinant of growth; Havrylyshyn and van Rooden (2003) argue that policies matter in addition to institutions in affecting growth; while Fischer et al. (1996, 1997) focus on stabilization policies and find that combating inflation is an effective policy instrument to promote growth. Therefore, controlling for key indicators in all three dimensions is important for uncovering the potential impact of fiscal adjustment on growth.

The analysis of the relationship between fiscal adjustment and growth in this paper is carried out in two stages. The first stage provides a simple characterization of the data of fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies to establish some stylized facts. The second stage relies on panel estimators to test the effect of fiscal adjustment on growth and motivates the results by discussing briefly their consistency with country experiences. Panel estimators are the most appropriate choices for growth regressions as they can explore data variations across countries and over time (eg Baltagi, 2001). The regressions control for other factors that could also affect the relationship between fiscal adjustment and growth to minimize omitted variable bias. For example, in countries rich in natural resources, most notably oil or gas, it is conceivable that favorable terms of trade could be simultaneously associated with a deficit-reducing increase in fiscal revenues and a large positive impact on growth. In these cases, the observed relationship could be spurious as in Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, and Russia.

Furthermore, the panel-data approach used in the second stage aims to minimize several other econometric issues that arise in the analysis of transition economies. (8) These problems are the endogeneity between GDP growth and fiscal balance, multicollinearity and parameter heterogeneity. In particular, this paper mitigates the endogeneity problem by using several estimators with increased control on endogeneity, addresses multicollinearity by examining exclusion effects with the relevant test statistics, and tackles parameter heterogeneity by focusing on samples and sub samples of countries that share some theoretical similarities. (9, 10)

The scope and quality of data is also a challenge in transition country analysis. As noted in many papers, GDP series may have been underestimated in some countries, especially at the beginning of the transition. At the same time, the definition of the fiscal deficit may vary from country to country (central government, general government, nonfinancial public sector, etc). Hence, the meaning of 'fiscal adjustment' may not be the same in all countries. This paper uses consistent data for general government in the World Economic Outlook (WEO) database to minimize this problem. Additional consistent data series were obtained from the World Bank's World Development Indicators (WDI) database and from the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) economic database.

THE ECONOMETRIC MODEL

Preliminary considerations

Many previous papers had used either cross-sectional data (without examining variations over time) or a relatively short time series with fairly simple estimation techniques, and often without including fixed effects. In contrast, in this paper panel regressions with fixed effects are used to obtain unbiased and consistent estimates. (11) Transition economies are characterized by rapid changes whose very nature is likely to have varied significantly from one country to the next. The exclusion of fixed effects ignores these country-specific differences and increases the risk of omitted-variables bias. In addition to these theoretical reasons, this is ultimately an empirical question. If regression tests show that fixed effects belong in the model, they should be included. (12) Given the focus of this paper on the impact of fiscal adjustment on growth, as long as the error term is not correlated with the fiscal and other control variables, it is not a problem if the impact of other variables is negated by the inclusion of fixed effects. The results from multiple panel estimators that provide different controls for the endogeneity between growth and fiscal balance indicate that, once fixed effects are controlled for, endogeneity is no longer a problem. This is consistent with the good small sample property of fixed-effect panel ordinary least squares (OLS) as shown in Islam (2000).

Model and sample

The paper analyzes the relationship between fiscal deficits and real GDP growth using a sample of 26 transition countries in 1992-2001. (13) The basic regression framework is described by a one-equation error-correction model. (14)

[DELTA][Y.sub.i,t] = [alpha] + [DELTA][X.sub.i,t-1][[beta].sub.k] + [phi]([Y.sub.i,t-1] - [X.sub.i,t-1][gamma]) + [[epsilon].sub.i,t] (1)

where, [Y.sub.i,t] is real GDP in country i during year t, [DELTA] is the first differences operator, X is a vector of independent variables and [[epsilon].sub.i,t] is a white noise error term. Although a number of different specifications have been used, a threevariable vector accounts for over 70% of the variation in the dependent variable. The model describes a short-term equilibrium relationship given by [DELTA][Y.sub.i,t] = [alpha] + [DELTA][X.sub.i,t-1][[beta].sub.k] + [[epsilon].sub.i,t] and a term [phi] ([Y.sub.i,t-1] - [X.sub.i,t-1] [gamma]), which measures the deviation from this short-term equilibrium relationship. Equation 1 shows that a change in [X.sub.i,t-1] produces a short-term contemporary change in [Y.sub.i,t] that is measured by the k-dimensional vector of regressors [beta]k. In addition, when the impact of [X.sub.i,t-1] on [Y.sub.i,t] throws the model off its long-run equilibrium given by the cointegrating vector [Y.sup.*.sub.i,t-1] = [X.sup.*.sub.i,t-1][gamma] where the '*' indicates equilibrium, the discrepancy or 'error' ([Y.sub.i,t-1] - [X.sub.i,t-1][gamma]) is corrected at a yearly rate of [phi]. (15)

In order to estimate equation 1, it is useful to restate it through a simple mathematical operation: Let [[beta].sub.j] be defined as - ([phi][gamma]), where both [phi] and [gamma] come from equation 1; then it follows that [gamma] = [[beta].sub.j]/-[phi]. Equation 1 can therefore be rewritten as:

[DELTA][Y.sub.i,t] = [alpha] + [Y.sub.i,t-1][phi] + [DELTA][X.sub.i,t-1][[beta].sub.k] + [X.sub.i,t-1][[beta].sub.j] + [[epsilon].sub.i,t] (2)

And equation 2 can then be estimated through panel OLS. The variables used in equation 2 are summarized in Table 1.

The selection of variables included in the empirical analysis follows the existing literature on growth in transition economies. The model is relatively simple and includes variables measured both in 'levels' and 'first-differences'. It also includes the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) structural reform index, the general government overall fiscal balance, inflation, and the external current account balance. (16,17) Unlike other studies, variables that measure differences in initial conditions are not included, but these country-specific factors will be captured by the inclusion of fixed effects in most of the models. As noted above, the inclusion of fixed effects is also key to reduce the possible omitted-variable bias.

GROWTH AND FISCAL ADJUSTMENT IN TRANSITION COUNTRIES: SOME STYLIZED FACTS

Both growth and fiscal balances improved significantly in transition economies over the past decade. For the purposes of this analysis, the sample can be divided in two 5-year periods: (i) 1992-1996, which can be broadly considered the 'decline' period; and (ii) 1997-2001, which can be described as the 'recovery' period. (18) Between these two periods, the average growth rate passed from about -2.0% to 4.5%, while the average fiscal deficit was cut in half from about 7.0% to about 3.5% of GDP. Although these averages mask important differences across countries, Table 2 provides compelling evidence that the higher growth trend and lower fiscal deficit have been quite general. In particular, growth improved in over 75% of the cases, whereas fiscal deficits were reduced in about two-thirds of the cases.

There also seems to be a strong correlation between fiscal adjustment and growth. Before moving to the results of the more sophisticated econometrics, we examine some simple descriptive patterns underlying the data. Figure 1 plots the change in the overall fiscal deficit and the change in the growth rate between the transition and post-transition periods. It shows that (i) fiscal adjustment was generally associated with higher growth; and (ii) the effect is greater the higher the initial level of the deficit. When the adjustment exceeds about 10% of GDP, the impact on growth begins to decline, as can be shown by the concavity of the curve.

The positive relationship between fiscal adjustment and growth is particularly strong for the CIS. Table 2 shows that large fiscal adjustment cases in the sample have predominantly occurred in CIS countries. (19) In the Eastern European countries, only Bulgaria had a fiscal adjustment comparable to that of a CIS country. (20) With the exceptions of Hungary and the Slovak Republic, most Central European countries had already achieved relatively low fiscal deficits by 1992. All the Baltic countries had deficits below 3% of GDP by 1992.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The correlation between fiscal adjustment and growth is unclear in countries that had relatively low deficit levels at the beginning of the period. Table 2 shows that in the Central and Eastern European group, countries where the fiscal deficit increased from a relatively low position experienced lower growth, as, for example, in the case of the Czech Republic. The opposite seems true in the Baltic countries, which are generally viewed as leaders in the implementation of structural reforms and macroeconomic stabilization. Other factors including the composition of spending may have played a role as well.

These results become evident if countries are divided along two criteria: the magnitude of fiscal adjustment and the degree of growth acceleration. The matrix diagonal of Table 3 shows cases of either low adjustment-low growth acceleration or high adjustment-high growth acceleration. About 75% of the cases fall into this category. But there is also an important group of countries with low fiscal adjustment and high growth acceleration. This corresponds mostly to cases in three situations: (i) 'early adjusters' such as the Baltic countries, where most of the adjustment had taken place before 1992, hence preceding the trends captured in the sample; (ii) countries where growth is affected primarily by changes in the international price of specific commodities; or (iii) outliers such as Albania. Mongolia is the only case of high fiscal adjustment and low growth acceleration. (21,22)

Fiscal adjustment was largely sustained through time and appears not to be driven by cyclical fluctuations. Coefficients of variation of fiscal deficits of countries were modest, suggesting relative stability through time. In addition, there does not seem to be strong evidence of significant cyclicality driving fiscal adjustment as revenue and expenditure elasticities with respect to GDP are low. (23)

ECONOMETRIC MODEL RESULTS

The use of more sophisticated econometric techniques confirms the strong relationship between fiscal adjustment and growth. The results presented in Table 4 show that fiscal adjustment is positively associated with growth both in the short run as captured by the first-difference variable and in the long run as captured by the lagged variable in levels.

The positive association of fiscal adjustment and growth is robust to a variety of model specifications and estimation techniques. With the exception of Model 9--the Arellano-Bond estimator without including inflation as a regressor--all parameter estimates for the lagged level and change in the fiscal deficit are statistically significant, and in most cases at the 1% level of significance. (24)

The results suggest that the positive impact of fiscal adjustment is rather large, both in the short and long run. (25) Over the long run, controlling for everything else, if country A maintained a fiscal deficit 1% of GDP lower than country B, long-term growth would be higher by between 0.5 and 1 percentage points, depending on the estimation model. (26) The effect of fiscal adjustment on growth in the short term also seems to be positive. (27) Consistent with the previous section, this relatively large effect seems to be driven by CIS countries. In fact, if we split the sample into CIS and non-CIS countries, the regression coefficient for the CIS sample is much larger than that for the non-CIS one. (28) Figure 2 captures the different effects in both samples by plotting changes in the fiscal balance (x-axis) versus GDP growth (y-axis), controlling for other factors in the model. The contrast in the slope of the partial regression line is striking.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

The effect of the other variables is similar to that found in other studies. A reduction in inflation has a positive and highly significant effect on growth. Progress in reforms as measured by the institutional reform index of the EBRD also has a strong impact on growth. However, the inclusion of both inflation and the reform index in the same model wipes out the statistical significance of the reform index. This is not surprising, as inflation stabilization is one of the components of the reform index, and including both in the same equation leads to multicollinearity. An adjustment in the current account balance is associated with a significant decline in growth in one of the model specifications (Model 5), but it loses statistical significance once inflation is included as a regressor.

The findings from the econometric analysis show strong associations between fiscal adjustment and growth, particularly in CIS countries. Such findings are largely consistent with country experiences discussed in the literature. As shown in World Bank (2002), at the onset of transition, the highly distorted production structures, the severe terms of trade shock, and the sudden cutoff of financing from Russia generated an output collapse. The combination of the output collapse with the cut in fiscal transfers generated large fiscal deficits in many countries. Difficulties to cut public spending in a short time period and limited or non-existent access to domestic or foreign debt financing in the first years of transition forced most of the deficit to be monetized, thus leading to high rates of inflation. Countries also resorted to involuntary financing by running arrears, particularly on the external front. The large fiscal deficits were quickly associated with growing and unsustainable current account imbalances (Table 5).

Fiscal adjustment in this context helped anchor agent's expectations and attract capital inflows. Garibaldi et al. (2001) show that rising foreign direct investment was the main form of private capital inflow to transition economies, (29) and these investments were strongly influenced by sound macroeconomic fundamentals. Similar effects were also found for remittances. (30) Official flows also rose sharply. As a result, Helbling et al. (2004) document, for example, a large increase in external debt after 1992 in the CIS-7, mostly in public and publicly guaranteed debt (above 80%). (31)

This evidence suggests that fiscal adjustment may have created a strong domestic demand effect that helped achieve growth recovery in the CIS. Fiscal adjustment can provide strong signals for sustained and credible government reform and thus create incentives for private agents to fully explore new economic opportunities, particularly those enabled by increases in capital inflows. This is consistent with findings from Helbling et al. (2004) who suggest that increased capital inflows financed higher consumption; Loukoianova and Unigovskaya (2004) also support this result, and argue that only after 1998 did net export start to drive growth. But structural reforms that fostered better market-support institutions could have reinforced the effects of fiscal adjustment on growth. Further research using detailed country experiences could shed additional light on the causal mechanism through which fiscal adjustment can boost economic growth in each particular context.

CONCLUSIONS

The main result of this paper is that the impact of fiscal adjustment on growth in transition economies is not qualitatively different from the one found for industrial, emerging markets, and low-income economies.

A simple bivariate correlation analysis suggests a strong positive correlation between fiscal adjustment and growth in transition economies. In particular: (i) the correlation between fiscal adjustment and growth seems stronger the higher the initial level of the deficit; and (ii) when fiscal adjustment exceeds about 10% of GDP, the positive impact on growth begins to decline. A fixed-effects panel error-correction model that controls for initial conditions, structural reforms, and inflation confirms the strong positive correlation of fiscal adjustment and growth. In addition, the positive effect of fiscal adjustment holds in the short and long run.

The correlation between fiscal adjustment and growth is stronger for those countries that need to achieve macroeconomic stability. The largest fiscal adjustments in the sample have been observed predominantly in the CIS, since these countries had unsustainable fiscal positions at the beginning of the 1990s. The sustained consolidations efforts in the CIS have been accompanied by the largest accelerations in growth in the sample.

However, for countries that have already achieved macroeconomic stability, the correlation between fiscal adjustment and growth is less clear. As Adam and Bevan (2005) have shown, this may be because other factors such as the composition of expenditures or deficit financing play a bigger role, or because these countries could invest in structural reforms that have moderate up-front fiscal costs that yield significant long-term benefits. Further research in this area is therefore needed. (32)

These results suggest that countries that have managed to credibly stabilize and achieve fiscal sustainability are unlikely to get large benefits in terms of growth by pursuing additional fiscal adjustment. For example, addressing microeconomic distortions with structural reforms to increase the rate of return to investment to attract capital flows, improving the composition of government spending while maintaining a prudent fiscal stance, and strengthening governance are likely to be more important policies to generate growth in that context.

The above results highlight the importance of a medium term exit strategy to reverse ongoing expansionary fiscal policies adopted in response to the current financial crisis. Several countries in the sample have responded to this crisis by allowing automatic stablizers to operate and by implementing discretionary fiscal stimulus. This has caused a significant deterioration in their fiscal balances, endangering fiscal sustainability and macroeconomic stability. Unless corrective action is taken by them to restore fiscal sustainability, there are serious risks to growth over the medium term.

Acknowledgement

The authors thank for their valuable comments two anonymous referees, Messrs. Flood, Chami, Flickenschild, Saadi-Sedik, Grigorian, Ding, Abiad, Gueorguiev, Klingen, Mody, and Szekely, and Mmes. Corbacho, Allard, Farhan, and Ohnsorge.

REFERENCES

Adam, C and Bevan, D. 2005: Fiscal deficits and growth in developing countries. Journal of Public Economics 89: 571-597.

Agenor, P and Montiel, P. 1999: Development macroeconomics. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.

Alesina, A and Ardagna, S. 1998: Tales of fiscal adjustment. Economic Policy 27(October): 487-546.

Alesina, A and Perotti, R. 1997: Fiscal adjustments in OECD countries: Composition and macroeconomic effects. IMF Staff Papers 44(2): 210-248.

Alesina, A, Perotti, R and Tavares, J. 1998: The political economy of fiscal adjustments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 197-266.

Alesina, A, Ardagna, S, Perotti, R and Schiantarelli, F. 2002: Fiscal policy, profits, and investment. American Economic Review 92(3): 571-589.

Arellano, M and Bond, S. 1991: Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies 58: 277-297.

Aslund, A, Boone, P and Johnson, S. 1996: How to stabilize: Lessons from post-communist countries. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 217-313.

Baltagi, B. 2001: The econometrics of panel data, 2nd Edition. John Wiley & Sons: New York.

Berg, A, Borensztein, E, Sahay, R and Zettelmeyer, J. 2006: The evolution of output in transition economies: Explaining the differences. In: Berglof, E and Gerard, R (eds). The Economics of Transition: The Fifth Nobel Symposium in Economics. Palgrave Macmillan: Houndmills.

Brunetti, A, Kisunko, G and Weder, B. 1998: Credibility of rules and economic growth: Evidence from a worldwide survey of the private sector. World Bank Economic Review 12(September): 353-384.

Buti, M and Sapir, A (eds). 1998: Economic policy in EMU: A study by the European Commission Services. Oxford University Press: New York.

Cheng, K. 2003: Growth and recovery in Mongolia during transition IMF working paper no. 03/217, Washington.

Christoffersen, P and Doyle, P. 2000: From inflation to growth: Eight years of the transition. Economics of Transition 8(2): 421-451.

De Melo, M, Denizer, C and Gelb, A. 1996: From plan to market: Patterns of transition. World Bank Economic Review 10 (September): 397-424.

Easterly, W, Rodriguez, C and Schmidt-Hebbel, K. 1994: Public sector deficits and macroeconomic performance. Oxford University Press: New York.

Fischer, S and Sahay, R. 2000: The transition economies after ten years IMF working paper no. 00/30, Washington.

Fischer, S and Sahay, R. 2004: Transition economies: The role of institutions and initial conditions Paper presented at a conference in honor of Guillermo A. Calvo, Washington.

Fischer, S, Sahay, R and Vegh, C. 1996: Economies in transition: The beginnings of growth. American Economic Review 86(2): 229-253.

Fischer, S, Sahay, R and Vegh, C. 1997: from transition to market: Evidence and growth prospects. In: Zecchini, S (ed) Lessons from the Economic Transition: Central and Eastern Europe in the 1990s. Kluwer: Dordrecht, 79-101.

Garibaldi, P, Mora, N, Sahay, R and Zettelmeyer, J. 2001: What moves capital to transition economies? IMF Staff Papers 48(Special Issue): 109-145.

Gelbard, E, McHugh, J, Iradian, G, Beddies, C and Redifer, L. 2005: Growth and poverty reduction in Armenia: Achievements and challenges. International Monetary Fund: Washington.

Gupta, S, Clements, B, Baldacci, E and Mulas-Granados, C. 2005a: Fiscal policy, expenditure composition, and growth in low-income countries. Journal of International Money and Finance 24(April): 441-463.

Gupta, S, Baldacci, E, Clements, B and Tiongson, E. 2005b: What sustains fiscal consolidation in emerging market countries? International Journal of Finance and Economics 10(4): 304-321.

Hausmann, R, Pritchett, L and Rodrik, D. 2005: Growth accelerations. Journal of Economic Growth 10(4): 303-329.

Havrylyshyn, O. 2001: Recovery and growth in transition: A decade of evidence. IMF Staff Papers 48(Special Issue): 53-87.

Havrylyshyn, O and van Rooden, R. 2003: Institutions matter in transition, but so do policies. Comparative Economics Studies 45 (1): 2-24.

Havrylyshyn, O, Berengaut, J, de Castello Branco, M, Mercer-Blackman, V, Van Rooden, R and Wolf, T. 1998: Growth experience in transition countries 1990-1998 IMF Occasional paper no. 184, Washington.

Helbling, T, Mody, A and Sahay, R. 2004: Debt accumulation in the CIS-7 countries: Bad luck, bad policies, or bad advice? In: Shiells, C and Sattar, S (eds). The Low-income Countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States. International Monetary Fund and World Bank: Washington, 15-49.

Hernandez-Cata, E. 1997: Liberalization and the behavior of output during the transition from plan to market. IMF Staff Papers 44(4): 405-429.

Hsiao, C and Sun, B. 2000: To pool or not pool panel data. In: Krishnamukar, J and Ronchetti, E (eds). Panel Data Econometrics: Future Directions. Elsevier Science B.V.: Amsterdam.

Islam, N. 2000: Small sample performance of dynamic panel data estimators in estimating the growth-convergence equation: A Monte Carlo study. Advances in Econometrics 15: 317-339.

Kaufman, R and Segura-Ubiergo, A. 2001: Globalization, domestic politics and social spending in Latin America: A time series cross section analysis. World Politics 53: 553-587.

Krueger, G and Ciolko, M. 1998: A note on initial conditions and liberalization during transition. Journal of Comparative Economics 26: 718-754.

Loukoianova, E and Unigovskaya, A. 2004: Analysis of recent growth in low-income CIS countries IMF working paper no. 04/151, Washington.

McDermott, J and Wescott, R. 1996: An empirical analysis of fiscal adjustments. IMF Staff Papers 43(4): 725-753.

Patillo, C, Gupta, S and Carey, K. 2005: Sustaining growth accelerations and pro-poor growth in Africa IMF working paper no. 05/195, Washington.

Popov, V. 2000: Shock therapy versus gradualism: The end of the debate (explaining the magnitude of transformational recession). Comparative Economic Studies 42(1): 1-57.

Purfield, C. 2003: Fiscal adjustment in transition countries: Evidence from the 1990s IMF working paper no. 03/36, Washington.

Rzonca, A and Cizkowicz, P. 2005: Non-Keynesian effects of fiscal contraction in new member states ECB working paper no. 519, European Central Bank: Frankfurt.

Segura-Ubiergo, A. 2007: The political economy of the welfare state in Latin America: Globalization, democracy and development. Cambridge University Press: New York.

Von Hagen, J and Strauch, R. 2001: Fiscal consolidations: Quality, economic conditions, and success. Public Choice 109: 327-346.

Wolf, H.C. 1999: Transition strategies: choices and outcomes. Princeton studies in international Finance No. 85.

World Bank. 2002: Transition--The first ten years. World Bank: Washington.

(1) Transition economies are those that were initially organized on the basis of government ownership of the factors of production and central planning and changed their economic organization to market based systems. The sample in this paper includes economies in Central and Eastern Europe, the Baltics, Commonwealth of Independent States, and Mongolia. See Table 2 for a detailed list of countries in each group.

(2) See, for example. Aslund et al. (1996); Berg et al. (2006); Brunetti et al. (1998); Christoffersen and Doyle (2000); De Melo et al. (1996); Fischer et al. (1996, 1997); Fischer and Sahay (2000); Havrylyshyn et al. (1998);. Havrylyshyn and van Rooden (2003); Hernandez-Cata (1997).

(3) For example, Fischer and Sahay (2004), who focus on the role of institutional reforms in development, mention in passing that fiscal adjustment is associated with higher growth. Their growth regressions show a substantial and statistically significant positive coefficient for the fiscal adjustment variable.

(4) See, for example, Easterly et al. (1994).

(5) These studies show that improving fiscal positions through the rationalization of the government wage bill and public transfers rather than increasing revenues and cutting public investment can foster higher growth even in the short term. See, for example, McDermott and Wescott (1996); Alesina and Perotti (1997); Alesina et al. (1998); Alesina and Ardagna (1998); Buti and Sapir (1998); Alesina et al. (2002); and Von Hagen and Strauch (2001).

(6) Hausmann et al. (2005) use the term 'growth accelerations' to describe episodes where the per capita growth rate increases by more than 2 percentage points a year and is sustained for at least 8 years. By looking at jumps in country medium-term trends they expect to gain insight into the sources of successful growth transitions. While the paper does not follow this exact definition of growth acceleration and methodology, the concept of acceleration being used is consistent with a definition of this type.

(7) Other factors, such as the composition of spending, are more likely to be the bottlenecks for growth in these countries. See Patillo et al. (2005) for evidence on the importance of the composition of fiscal spending on growth in low-income countries.

(8) For example, Krueger and Ciolko (1998) find that policy measures are endogenous to output growth. Popov (2000) also finds policy changes to be endogenous to initial conditions in former Soviet Onion countries.

(9) Estimators with increased control on endogeneity include the fixed-effect specifications that control for the related endogeneity, the feasible general least square model (FGLS) that corrects for AR(I) error autocorrelafion, and the Arellano-Bond GMM estimator that further corrects for endogeneity by exploiting the moment conditions to obtain consistent estimates in panels with short time series (Arellano and Bond, 1991).

(10) On parameter heterogeneity, as Hsiao and Sun (2000) have pointed out, the ability to exploit the information contained in panel data depends critically on the plausibility of pooling. Hsiao and Sun (2000, p. 181) note that the decision to pool or not to pool the data depends on whether, [y.sub.it], the ith individual observation of the dependent variable at time t, conditional on x, the independent variable(s) of interest, can be viewed as a random draw from a common population. This is the socalled exchangeability criterion. It implies that the individual and time subscript, it, is simply a labeling device. Observations on the dependent variable should be exchangeable so that, a priori, E([y.sub.it]|x) E([y.sub.js]|x). In other words, the expected probability of observing [y.sub.it] or [y.sub.js], conditional on x, the independent variable(s) of interest, should be the same. If this condition is satisfied, by pooling the data we can obtain more robust and precise parameter estimates. However, if individual outcomes are more appropriately viewed as stemming from a heterogeneous population, then the subscript it contains important information that can be used to determine the specific heterogeneous population from which the particular observation is generated.

(11) Despite the merits of fixed effects, they also have the limitation of masking some of the possible transmission channels. Further research through more in-depth case studies can further illuminate the relationship.

(12) Such as the Hausman test, the F-test, or the Chow test. The test results support the inclusion of fixed effects in the model.

(13) The data are from the WEO database of the International Monetary Fund.

(14) This section draws on Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo (2001) and Segura-Ubiergo (2007).

(15) In addition, the importance of the short-term effects [DELTA][X.sub.i,t-1] depends on the size of [[beta].sub.k] and on how long the effects of changes in [X.sub.i,t-1] persist through time. A change in [X.sub.i,t-1] produces an immediate (contemporary) change in [Y.sub.i,t] that is measured by [[beta].sub.k]. If at time t there is a change in [X.sub.i,t] in the opposite direction to the change in [X.sub.i,t-1], then there are no more effects. But if the change in [X.sub.i,t-1] is sustained, then the impact will continue in subsequent periods and can be measured by [DELTA][X.sub.i,t-1] [(1 + [phi]).sup.t], where t is the number of periods after the initial change. Thus, for example, 3 years after the initial change [DELTA][X.sub.i,t-1], the effect will be [DELTA][X.sub.i,t-1] [(1 + [phi]).sup.3]. Since 0 < [phi] < -1, the smaller the value of [phi], the longer the sustained changes in X will persist through time.

(16) This index is developed by EBRD and data refer to the aggregate reform index measuring progress along three fronts: (i) price liberalization; (ii) trade and foreign exchange liberalization; and (iii) privatization, restructuring and financial market reform. Given the broad coverage of first and second stage reforms, the aggregate index can be considered a proxy for institutions.

(17) Not all empirical studies include this variable. Its inclusion or not in the model, as discussed in the next following section, does not affect the main results.

(18) To be sure, countries began the transition in different years. This paper follows the transition dating convention in Havrylyshyn et al. (1998). Most countries are considered to have started transition in 1992. The exceptions are Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and the Slovak Republic, which started the process in 1990, and Albania, which started transitioning in 1991.

(19) See Table 2. This regional classification follows Havrylyshyn et al. (1998).

(20) The Eastern European countries are Macedonia, Albania, Bulgaria, and Romania. Romania had a low overall balance at the beginning of the sample period.

(21) The main international commodity price alluded to is oil, as it affects the cost of oil imports on which Belarus is highly dependent and the price of oil and gas exports of Turkmenistan.

(22) The experience of two countries (Mongolia and Belarus) is somewhat puzzling because at first sight they do not fit the strong positive association between fiscal adjustment and growth presented in Table 2 and discussed in this section. Belarus seems to have experienced fast acceleration of economic growth even though structural reforms have been limited and fiscal adjustment low. However, this result is driven by other important exogenous factors that helped boost growth in Belarus: the continuing sale by Russia of subsidized oil inputs, a geographically advantageous position for energy transportation, and favorable oil price developments. Mongolia, unlike Belarus, seems to have undergone significant fiscal adjustment but no acceleration in economic growth. Cheng (2003) suggests that favorable initial conditions may have contributed to the milder initial recession. However, the composition of fiscal adjustment in Mongolia may explain why fiscal adjustment was not associated with higher growth: most of the fiscal adjustment in Mongolia was revenue-based while the level of expenditures was kept relatively high. This suggests that the public sector may not have been sufficiently reformed and may have crowded out private sector activity.

(23) Calculations of coefficients of variation and revenue and expenditure elasticities are available from the authors upon request.

(24) It is not entirely obvious why the 'level' variable of the fiscal deficit in the model without inflation is not statistically significant. As the variable turns statistically significant in the model with inflation, and inflation turns out to be statistically significant in all models across the board, there is a strong likelihood that Model 9 is misspecified.

(25) The discussion focuses on Models 5 and 6, which are robust to the presence of outliers.

(26) Note that by long-term growth, we simply refer to growth over the life of the model.

(27) The results are therefore consistent with a recent paper by Rzonca and Cizkowicz (2005).

(28) Formal tests on the coefficient differences were conducted by splitting the sample between CIS and non-CIS countries. Hausman tests lead to rejection of the hypothesis of no difference in regression coefficients at the 5% confidence level.

(29) While foreign direct investment averaged below 2% of GDP per year at the beginning of transition, by 1999 these flows reached about 4% of GDP per year.

(30) Anecdotal evidence of unrecorded foreign remittances abound. For Armenia, unrecorded private remittances are thought to be in the form of 'pocket money' from Armenians working in Russia. See Gelbard et al. (2005) for more details.

(31) The CIS-7 countries are Armenia, Azerbaijan, Georgia, the Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, Tajikistan, and Uzbekistan.

(32) Data limitations (consistency, validity, and reliability) did not allow us to probe deeper in this area.

ALEX SEGURA-UBIERGO, ALEJANDRO SIMONE, SANJEEV GUPTA & QIANG CUI

Fiscal Affairs Department, International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street, N. W., Washington D.C., 20431, USA. E-mail: sgupta@imf.org
Table 1: Description of main variables

                            Observations     Mean    Standard    Source
                                                     deviation
Dependent variable
Real GDP growth                 234           0.95        7.88   WEO
Independent variables
General gov. overall            260          -5.59        7.26   WEO
  fiscal balance
  (in percent of GDP)
Change in general gov.          234           0.85        5.21   WEO
  overall fiscal balance
Current account balance         260          -5.54       11.68   WEO
  (in percent of GDP)
Change in current               234           0.06       10.18   WEO
  account balance
Average annual consumer         202         164.75      566.11   WDI
  price index
Change in average annual        179         -93.33      533.73   WDI
  consumer price index
EBRD reform index               240           3.12        0.80   EBRD
Change in reform index          216           0.13        0.24   EBRD

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook (WEO) database, EBRO, the World
Bank, and World Development Indicators (WDI) database

Table 2: Growth and fiscal adjustment experience by transition
regions, 1992-2001

Country                Fiscal       Fiscal       Fiscal       Growth
                      balance      balance     adjustment   1992-1996
                     1992-1996    1997-2001

Central and Eastern Europe

Poland                  -3.8         -3.9         -0.1         5.8
Romania                 -3.3         -4.1         -0.7         2.3
Croatia                 -1.5         -6.2         -4.8         3.5
Slovak Republic         -4.5         -5.6         -1.1         3.8
Czech Republic          -0.9         -2.8         -1.9         2.4
Slovenia                 0.2         -1.0         -1.2         4.1
Hungary                 -6.6         -4.1          2.5         2.0
Macedonia               -4.8         -1.4          3.4        -1.4
Albania                -11.8        -10.7          1.0         5.4
Bulgaria                -6.6         -0.5          6.2        -6.1
  Average               -4.3         -4.0          0.3         2.2

Baltics

Estonia                 -0.1         -1.3         -1.2         1.6
Latvia                  -1.6         -2.5         -0.9         0.4
Lithuania               -3.4         -4.8         -1.3        -2.2
  Average               -1.7         -2.9         -1.1        -0.1

Commonwealth of independent states and Mongolia

Mongolia               -12.5         -9.7         2.7          2.4
Uzbekistan              -7.6         -2.6         5.0         -0.7
Armenia                -22.3         -5.6        16.7          1.5
Georgia                -20.7         -4.7        16.0         -3.2
Kyrgyz Republic        -13.1         -9.7         3.4         -4.3
Belarus                 -1.9         -1.1         0.8         -3.3
Russia                 -10.2         -1.4         8.8         -5.6
Moldova                -10.8         -2.4         8.4        -10.3
Kazakhstan              -5.2         -2.7         2.5         -5.6
Ukraine                 -9.7         -2.0         7.7        -12.5
Tajikistan             -12.8         -1.9        10.9         -9.5
Azerbaijan              -5.7         -2.4         3.3         -9.5
Turkmenistan             2.5         -0.6        -3.1        -10.5
  Average              -10.0         -3.6         6.4         -5.5
  Overall average       -6.9         -3.7         3.2         -1.9

Country                Growth        Growth
                     1997-2001    acceleration

Central and Eastern Europe

Poland                  3.5           -2.3
Romania                 0.5           -1.8
Croatia                 2.1           -1.4
Slovak Republic         2.9           -0.9
Czech Republic          1.4           -0.9
Slovenia                4.1            0.0
Hungary                 4.5            2.6
Macedonia               1.9            3.4
Albania                 9.4            4.1
Bulgaria                4.0           10.1
  Average               3.4            1.3

Baltics

Estonia                 4.4            2.9
Latvia                  5.6            5.2
Lithuania               4.0            6.2
  Average               4.7            4.7

Commonwealth of independent states and Mongolia

Mongolia                2.2           -0.2
Uzbekistan              3.2            3.9
Armenia                 6.6            5.1
Georgia                 3.1            6.3
Kyrgyz Republic         4.1            8.4
Belarus                 5.6            8.9
Russia                  4.0            9.6
Moldova                -0.4            9.9
Kazakhstan              6.0           11.6
Ukraine                 3.2           15.7
Tajikistan              6.9           16.4
Azerbaijan              9.6           19.1
Turkmenistan           15.5           26.0
  Average               5.4           10.8
  Overall average       4.5            6.4

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook. These data are available
upon request from the authors

Table 3: Fiscal adjustment and growth acceleration in transition
countries

Fiscal adjustment    Growth acceleration

                     Low (<2.5 percentage     High (>2.5
                     points)                  percentage points)

Low (<2.5% GDP)      Croatia [-4.8,0.5] (1)   Albania [1.0,4.1]
                     Czech Rep.[-1.9, -1.0]   Belarus [0.8, 8.8]
                     Poland [-0.1, -2.3]      Estonia [-1.2, 2.9]
                     Romania [-0.7, -1.8]     Latvia [-1.0, 5.21
                     Slovak f-1.1, -1.0]      Lithuania [-1.3, 6.2]
                     Slovenia [-1.2,0.0]      Turkmekistan [-3.1, 26.0]

High (>2.5% GDP)     Mongolia [2.7, -0.2]     Armenia [16.6, 5.1]
                                              Azerbaijan [3.3, 19.1]
                                              Bulgaria [6.2, 10.1]
                                              Georgia [16.0, 6.3]
                                              Hungary [2.5, 2.6]
                                              Kazakhstan [2.5, 11.6]
                                              Kyrgyz [3.4,8.4]
                                              Macedonia [3.4,3.4]
                                              Moldova [8.4,9.9]
                                              Russia [8.8, 9.6]
                                              Tajikistan [10.9, 16.4]
                                              Ukraine [7.7, 15.7]
                                              Uzbekistan [5.0, 3.9]

(1): If the big stump of 1992 (a large outlier) is included, Croatia
would move to the upper right cell in Table 3.

Note: The first figure in brackets corresponds to fiscal adjustment
and the second corresponds to growth acceleration. Bold
distinguishes the countries in the matrix diagonal.

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook.

Table 4: Econometric results 1
                                      OLS

                                 [1]             [2]

GDP growth (L)                 0.5346 ***      0.3462 ***
                              [0.0673]        [0.0966]
Reform index (L)               1.4998 ***      5.9487 ***
                              [0.7805]        (2.0655]
Reform index (D)              -0.9755          1.5448
                              [2.19261        [2.6141]
Fiscal balance (L)             0.4047 ***      0.6025 ***
                              [0.1475]        [0.1799]
Fiscal balance (D)             0.742 ***       0.9161 ***
                              [0.2167]        [0.1986]
Current account balance (L)   -0.0940         -0.0915
                              [0.0723]        [0.0920]
Current account balance (D)   [0.0503]        -0.0217
                              [0.0841]        [0.0950]
Inflation (L)

Inflation (D)

Constant                      -1.9036        -11.436
                              [2.6739]        [7.5059]
Observations                     192             155
F                             22.89           24.41
Prob>F                         0.0000          0.0000
Wald chi-square
Prob>Wald
[R.sup.2]                      0.5427          0.6303
Root MSE                       5.1058          3.7401
Fixed effects                     No              Yes

                                      OLS

                                 [3]             [4]

GDP growth (L)                 0.453 ***       0.2378 **
                              [0.0698]        [0.0974]
Reform index (L)              -0.3138          0.9441
                              [0.6322]        [1.6103]
Reform index (D)              -0.4137         -1.2453
                              [2.0046]        [2.2435]
Fiscal balance (L)             0.2562 *        0.6349 ***
                              [0.1479]        [0.1742]
Fiscal balance (D)             0.6812 ***      0.7665 ***
                              [0.2034]        [0.1832]
Current account balance (L)   -0.0536          0.0365
                              [0.0569]        [0.0803]
Current account balance (D)   -0.0685          0.0365
                              [O.0814]        [0.0803]
Inflation (L)                 -0.0083 ***     -0.0083 ***
                              [0.0017]        [0.0013]
Inflation (D)                 -0.007 ***      -0.0074 ***
                              [0.0016]        [0.0013]
Constant                       4.5312 **       9.8426
                              [2.3633]        [6.5827]
Observations                     155             155
F                             24.41           20.48
Prob>F                         0.0000          0.0000
Wald chi-square
Prob>Wald
[R.sup.2]                      0.6303          0.7277
Root MSE                       3.7401          3.4567
Fixed effects                     No              Yes

                                 Robust regression

                                [5]             [61

GDP growth (L)                 0.4608 ***      0.1469
                              [0.0454]        [0.0526]
Reform index (L)               1.9951 **       0.7881
                              [0.9905]        [1.24931
Reform index (D)              -1.0749         -2.5095
                              [1.5377]        [1.8842]
Fiscal balance (L)             0.4666 ***      0.8769 **
                              [0.1159]        [0.1369]
Fiscal balance (D)             0.9220 ***      0.8967 ***
                              [0.1273]        [0.12991
Current account balance (L)   -0.1005 ***      0.0411
                              [0.0454]        [0.0721]
Current account balance (D)   -0.1532 ***     -0.0007
                              [0.0471]        [0.0654]
Inflation (L)                                 -0.0083 ***
                                              [0.0012]
Inflation (D)                                 -0.0062 ***
                                              [0.0012]
Constant                       1.2436         14.3635
                              [4.3452]        [5.1236]
Observations                     192             155
F                             15.68           17.64
Prob>F                         0.0000          0.0000
Wald chi-square
Prob>Wald
[R.sup.2]                        n.a             n.a
Root MSE                         n.a             n.a
Fixed effects                    Yes             Yes

                                      FGLS

                                 [7]             [8]

GDP growth (L)                 0.3162 ***      0.2804 ***
                              [0.0608]        [0.0543]
Reform index (L)               6.3277 ***      0.9341
                              [1.3411]        [1.2423]
Reform index (D)               1.6359          -0.6626
                              [2.0336]        [1.9831]
Fiscal balance (L)             0.6034 ***      0.6002 ***
                              [0.1552]        [0.1382]
Fiscal balance (D)             0.8979 ***      0.7555 ***
                              [0.1688]        [0.1369]
Current account balance (L)    -0.0850         0.0892
                              [0.0617]        [0.0725]
Current account balance (D)    -0.0201         0.0308
                              [0.0625]        [0.0687]
Inflation (L)                                 -0.0084 ***
                                              [0.0012]
Inflation (D)                                 -0.0076 ***
                                              [0.0013]
Constant                      -12.4879
                               [5.8945]
Observations                      192            155
F
Prob>F
Wald chi-square               299.7000        504.58
Prob>Wald                      0.0000          0.0000
[R.sup.2]                        n.a             n.a
Root MSE                         n.a             n.a
Fixed effects                    Yes             Yes

                                       GMM

                                [9]             [10]

GDP growth (L)                 0.4318 ***      0.2234 **
                              [0.0760]        [0.0838]
Reform index (L)               8.8624 ***     -0.2043
                              [1.9282]        [2.5225]
Reform index (D)               5.1984 ***     -3.4134
                              [2.5361]        [2.8779]
Fiscal balance (L)             0.1839          0.5918
                              [0.2051]        [0.2289]
Fiscal balance (D)             0.4947 ***      0.7825 ***
                              [0.2065]         0.1222
Current account balance (L)    0.0587         [0.1086]
                              [0.0750]         0.028
Current account balance (D)   -0.0047         [0.0916]
                              [0.0691]
Inflation (L)                                 -0.0086 ***
                                              [0.0020]
Inflation (D)                                 -0.0068
                                              [0.0019]
Constant                      -0.0751         -0.2059
                              [0.2215]        [0.2039]
Observations                     192             134
F
Prob>F
Wald chi-square               139.28          120.68
Prob>Wald                       0.0000          0.0000
[R.sup.2]                         n.a             n.a
Root MSE                          n.a             n.a
Fixed effects                     n.a             n.a

(1): Variables followed by 'L' were lagged, while variables followed
by V were first-differenced. Current GDP Growth is the dependent
variable. 'n.a' means not applicable.

Notes: The first four models are estimated using ordinary least
squares with White-corrected (heroscedasticity-consistent)
standard errors. Models 5 and 6 use robust regression in
order to correct for outliers. Models 7 and 8 are estimated
with generalized least squares assuming a common autoregressive
process and homoscedastic panels. Models 9 and 10 are
estimated using the Arellano-Bond generalized method of moments
estimator. Where possible, Lagrange Multiplier tests were used to
test whether there was any remaining serial correlation. In most
cases no serial correlation was found. Corrogram results on the
baseline fixed-effect panel OLS are also provided in Table 7 of
Annex I to show that there is no significant threat of serial
correlation because no serial correlation is not rejected in any case
at the 1% level and in only I out of 48 cases at the 5% level with
tests up to two lags. This means that any possible bias due to the
simultaneous inclusion of a lagged dependent variable and fixed
effects is likely to be very small.

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Table 5: Selected economic indicators at the beginning and at the end
of the sample period (average for years 1992-1993 and 2000-2001)

Country                 Total revenues (TR)     Total expenditures (TE)

                       1992-1993    2000-2001    1992-1993    2000-2001

Central and Eastern Europe

Poland                   45.2         38.1         50.5         42.6
Romania                  35.6         30.7         38.1         34.3
Croatia                  33.2         45.5         35.5         52.1
Slovak republic          42.9         37.7         52.0         44.7
Czech republic           44.5         39.2         44.3         42.4
Slovenia                 41.7         41.2         40.7         42.5
Hungary                  45.9         45.8         54.4         49.6
Macedonia                39.7         35.5         51.3         37.5
Albania                  23.2         22.5         36.4         31.1
Bulgaria                 37.8         38.1         45.9         39.1
Average                  39.0         37.4         44.9         41.6

Baltics

Estonia                  37.2         37.8         37.6         37.9
Latvia                   32.2         36.2         32.3         38.9
Lithuania                31.1         30.4         33.5         32.8
Average                  33.5         34.8         34.5         36.5

Commonwealth of independent states and Mongolia

Mongolia                 30.0         36.5         43.6         42.7
Uzbekistan               33.8         27.0         48.6         29.1
Armenia                  28.8         17.5         75.6         22.5
Georgia                  14.8         15.7         53.3         18.7
Kyrgyz Republic          21.0         19.5         37.1         27.2
Belarus                  48.8         45.4         51.1         46.3
Russia                   37.9         37.1         50.9         34.2
Moldova                  26.4         30.0         42.6         30.6
Kazakhstan               27.0         23.7         31.3         22.7
Ukraine                  38.5         33.5         56.5         34.9
Tajikistan               24.2         14.4         49.5         14.8
Azerbaijan               45.8         20.7         52.1         21.2
Turkmenistan             47.3          1.7         36.1          1.5
Average                  32.6         24.8         48.3         26.6
Overall Average          35.2         30.8         45.4         33.5

Country                    Overall balance          Current account
                                                   (percent of GDP)

                       1992-1993    2000-2001    1992-1993    2000-2001

Central and Eastern Europe

Poland                   -5.2         -4.5         -3.0         -5.0
Romania                  -2.5         -3.6         -6.2         -4.7
Croatia                  -2.4         -6.7          4.5         -3.1
Slovak republic          -9.1           -7         -2.6         -5.9
Czech republic            0.3         -3.2          1.7         -5.5
Slovenia                  1.0         -1.3          3.6         -1.3
Hungary                  -8.5         -3.9         -4.0         -4.8
Macedonia               -11.6         -1.9         -1.7         -4.5
Albania                 -13.2         -8.7        -40.2         -6.8
Bulgaria                 -8.1         -0.9         -7.2         -5.9
Average                  -5.9         -4.2         -5.5         -4.7

Baltics

Estonia                  -0.5         -0.1          2.6         -5.9
Latvia                   -0.1         -2.7          6.6         -8.2
Lithuania                -2.4         -2.4         -1.1         -5.4
Average                  -1.0         -1.7          2.7         -6.5

Commonwealth of independent states and Mongolia

Mongolia                -13.7         -6.2          1.2         -5.9
Uzbekistan              -14.8         -2.1         -7.2          0.3
Armenia                 -46.9         -5.1        -34.6        -12.3
Georgia                 -38.5         -3.0        -21.4         -5.5
Kyrgyz Republic         -16.1         -7.7        -10.7         -5.0
Belarus                  -2.4         -1.0         -3.3         -3.1
Russia                  -13.0          2.9          0.0         14.0
Moldova                 -16.2         -0.6         -8.9         -6.9
Kazakhstan               -4.3          1.0        -30.1          0.4
Ukraine                 -18.0         -1.4         -4.6          4.2
Tajikistan              -25.3         -0.4        -22.1         -6.7
Azerbaijan               -6.3         -0.5        -14.4         -2.2
Turkmenistan             11.2          0.2         56.5          3.4
Average                 -15.7         -1.8         -7.7         -1.9
Overall Average         -10.2         -2.7         -5.6         -3.6

Country                 Change in TR   Change in TE

Central and Eastern Europe

Poland                     -7.1           -7.8
Romania                    -4.9           -3.8
Croatia                    12.3           16.6
Slovak republic            -5.2           -7.3
Czech republic             -5.3           -1.8
Slovenia                   -0.5           1.80
Hungary                    -0.1           -4.8
Macedonia                  -4.2          -13.9
Albania                    -0.7           -5.2
Bulgaria                    0.3           -6.8
Average                    -1.6           -3.3

Baltics

Estonia                     0.6            0.2
Latvia                      4.0            6.6
Lithuania                  -0.7           -0.8
Average                     1.3            2.0

Commonwealth of independent states and Mongolia

Mongolia                    6.5           -0.9
Uzbekistan                 -6.8          -19.6
Armenia                   -11.3          -53.1
Georgia                     0.9          -34.6
Kyrgyz Republic            -1.5           -9.9
Belarus                    -3.4           -4.8
Russia                     -0.8          -16.7
Moldova                     3.6          -12.0
Kazakhstan                 -3.3           -8.6
Ukraine                    -5.0          -21.6
Tajikistan                 -9.8          -34.7
Azerbaijan                -25.1          -30.9
Turkmenistan              -45.6          -34.6
Average                    -7.8          -21.7
Overall Average            -4.4          -11.9

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有