Foreign direct investment in the Czech Republic: the role of origin effects and government promotion abroad.
Deichmann, Joel I.
INTRODUCTION
After more than a decade and a half of political and economic
reforms, the Czech Republic is widely considered to be among the most
successful cases of transformation among the members of the former
Soviet bloc. In 2006, foreign direct investment (FDI) in the Czech
Republic, as both a driver of this success and a reflection thereof,
reached more than $60 billion in cumulative stock, translating to $6,337
per capita, the highest in the region (Berglof, 2008). (1) In
recognition of this success, the country has been placed in the category
of 'frontrunner' (UNCTAD, 2007) in terms of inward FDI
performance and potential, and the World Bank (2008) reports that annual
inflows from 1993 through 2007 averaged 5.6% of gross domestic product,
underscoring the importance of FDI to the economy of this landlocked
Central European state.
In pursuit of convergence with Western Europe, Czech leadership has
striven to distinguish the country as the leader among transition
states. The first democratically elected governments assertively courted
constructive investment from abroad as an engine for development while
limiting potentially negative effects (Pavlinek, 2004). Governments
recognize the importance of marketing their national advantages as FDI
destinations through promotion agencies as part of broader policy
initiatives (Breznitz, 2007), (2) and recent work by Capik (2007),
Benacek (2008), and Drahokoupil (2008) has explored aspects of such
promotion in Central and Eastern Europe (hereafter CEE).
As investment into CEE accelerated, a substantial literature also
emerged from research into the determinants of the spatial distribution
of these inflows. Location factors that are competently researched and
empirically corroborated include trade links (Brenton et al., 1998),
agglomeration (Head et al., 1999), trade openness (Kinoshita and Campos,
2003) and other relational factors (Bandelj, 2002), labor costs and
gravity factors (Bevin and Estrin, 2004), policy consistency and
economic stability (Ass and Beck, 2005; Grosse and Trevino, 2005), and
political risks (Brada et al., 2006), among others (see Blonigen (2005)
for a thorough review). Many of these factors simultaneously interact
with industry (Eckert and Rossmeissl, 2005) and entry mode (Dikova and
van Witteloostuijn, 2007). Another related literature critically
assesses the impact of investment upon regional development in the host
countries (Pavlinek, 2004) and broader convergence (Eckert and
Rossmeissl, 2005).
In part because the EU accession process occurred over several
years and attracted great international attention, economic integration
in Europe had already been identified in several works as an important
enabling factor of FDI when the 2004 candidates had only preliminary EU
status (Brenton et al., 1998; Bandelj, 2002; Deichmann, 2004), and this
was confirmed in the Czech case as well (Kinoshita and Campos, 2003;
Eckert and Rossmeissl, 2005). Recognizing the success of EU accession
states, they are now generally considered a cohort distinct the former
Soviet Republics such as Belarus, Ukraine, Moldova, and the countries of
Turkestan, which lag far behind Central Europe in nearly all
socio-economic measures (Janicki and Wunnava, 2004; Brada et al., 2006;
Berglof, 2008; World Bank, 2008).
The present paper's intent is to augment the existing
literature by examining FDI from the angle of country-of-origin effects
(hereafter 'origin effects'), an approach that is essential,
yet less thoroughly understood, according to Dunning (1980, 2001) and
echoed by Hunya (2000). It is important to understand why the Czech
Republic has differential appeal to firms from different locations
around the world. The largest sources of FDI with values of $30 million
or more are presented in Table 1, and they are concentrated in Western
Europe, North America, and East Asia. The top five countries are
Germany, the Netherlands, Spain, Austria, and France, all of which are
geographically close to the Czech Republic. Moreover, Germany and
Austria also share long borders with the country, suggesting that
effects of proximity might be at work.
Outside of Europe, most of the other leading home
countries--notably the United States (#6), Japan (#11), and Canada
(#18)--are relatively large economies, as measured by GDP. In addition,
it is worth noting that several former eastern-bloc trade partners,
including Slovakia (#10), Poland (#13), Hungary (#21), Russia (#22), and
Slovenia (#30) appear in the list of leading origins. As part of
Czechoslovakia until 1993, Slovakia fares prominently probably because
of remaining business units in the Czech lands. Cursory observation of
the other patterns hints that explanatory variables identified elsewhere
are worth investigating in this context, particularly border effects
(O'hUallachain and Reid, 1992), gravity model factors (Grosse and
Trevino, 1996), and cultural factors (Zhao and Zhu, 2000; Bitzenis,
2004).
The ranking of home countries should be interpreted with caution,
especially the cases of the Netherlands and Spain. A favorable bilateral
investment treaty between the Netherlands and Czech Republic facilitates
transactions, and the Dutch registration of foreign corporations from
third countries holds special tax benefits for companies as well). (3)
For example, the Prague office of Bank of Tokyo-Mitsubishi (the
Netherlands) is registered with Dutch--rather than Japanese--origins
(BusinessInfo.cz, 2006). The Seychelles, Saint Lucia, and the Bahamas
all rank among the top 40 origins for similar reasons. Outliers provide
another reason for caution in interpretation: Telefonica's 2005
acquisition of Cesky Telecom for nearly $5 billion is the largest single
transaction to date and is largely responsible for Spain's ranking
of third after being ranked twentieth as recently as 1999.
LITERATURE
John Dunning's eclectic (OLI) theory of international
production (1980, 2001) has been the inspiration for a wide range of
published work on FDI. The framework is simple: advantages relevant to
ownership, location, and internalization are all essential in order to
fully understand why FDI takes place. These dimensions represent three
separate sets of questions in any given context, and have been widely
researched as such. The most common approach is to examine
location-specific advantages across countries (Bevin and Estrin, 2004;
Janicki and Wunnava, 2004; Blonigen, 2005; Brada et al., 2006). Hunya
(2000) explores the interaction of advantages in origin and CEE
destination countries, while other scholars simultaneously look at
ownership advantages and sub-national location choice
(O'hUallachain and Reid, 1992; Zhao and Zhu, 2000). In general, the
literature favors breadth of analysis over depth by examining large data
sets rather than specific cases.
Notwithstanding the few recent exceptions noted above, Hunya (2000,
p. 87) laments that the country-origin of FDI is 'a neglected
issue'. He contributes a thorough descriptive assessment of the
flows of FDI from home countries to CEE states and speculates that trade
is the main explanation, but stops short of empirical tests. Citing
evidence from other works (in particular, pan-European research by
Brenton et al., 1998), he finds evidence of three types of trade
relationships related to FDI: capital, exports, and imports with
Germany, Austria, France, and the UK; capital links with the USA and
Netherlands; and trade links with Russia, other CEE countries, and
Italy. The author also recognizes that proximity plays a role. Finally,
he reckons that policy can be instrumental when a 'foreigner
friendly' privatization scheme is in place, because at the time of
writing about half of the FDI in the countries in question had come
through privatization (Hunya, 2000, p. 102).
In the tradition of Dunning's (1980) seminal work on origin
effects, a handful of empirical inquiries have been published on such
enabling factors, providing a template for the present research. These
include analyses of FDI in the United States (O'hUallachain and
Reid, 1992; Grosse and Trevino, 1996), China (Luo, 1998; Zhao and Zhu,
2000), Poland (Deichmann, 2004), Bulgaria (Bitzenis, 2004), and Europe
(Brenton et al., 1998). From these county-specific inquiries a list of
mainstream variables has evolved.
O'hUallachain and Reid (1992) contend that border effects may
enable FDI. Border effects arise from home country familiarity with
adjacent territory or from cultural similarities between the home
country and host region. The authors identify patterns using location
quotients for Canadian, British, Latin American, and Japanese investment
in the USA, and analyze regression results for each home country. Border
effects can be traced to subtle linkages of communications and
transportation infrastructure that facilitate international migration
and tourist flows, which the authors conclude are important for
Japanese, Latin American, and Dutch manufacturing investment.
Grosse and Trevino (1996) test an extensive list of determinants
using multivariate regression. They find that FDI flows to the USA are
governed by trade, geographical and cultural distance, and political
risk at home. Among the authors' most interesting findings are the
divergent and significant impacts of each direction of trade flow. FDI
is found to be positively related to home countries' exports to the
USA, while imports to the home country have a negative effect on FDI in
the USA.
Brenton et al. (1998) report upon their simple but revealing
application of Linnemann's (1966) gravity model to the EU and
Central Europe. The authors compare the coefficients of FDI and trade
(imports and exports handled separately) in a straightforward equation
featuring income, population, geographical distance, and dummies for
preferential trade agreements. They find evidence that FDI into CEE
countries follows the same determinants as elsewhere, conforming to the
gravity model and exhibiting a complementary relationship with trade (in
other words, they find that FDI does not serve as a substitute for
trade).
Zhao and Zhu's (2000) work attempts to identify
origin-specific responses to location factors within China. The authors
cluster home countries according to cultural similarities (Hong Kong,
Singapore, Japan, USA, and Europe). From Ordinary Least Squares (OLS)
regression, they conclude that management style, business logic, and
cultural backgrounds shared within these groups are indeed important in
selecting locations, as are complementary factors of production between
the host region and locations within China.
In the context of Poland, Deichmann (2004) upholds the
applicability of the gravity model by confirming the importance of GDP
and geographical distance as determinants of FDI origins. The role of
early 'Europe Agreements' is found to be strong, even prior to
Polish accession to the EU. The author also finds evidence that some FDI
can be attributed to Polonia, or the relocation of poles primarily to
North America and Western Europe.
Bitzenis (2004) assesses origin-specific factors in Bulgaria, a
country where FDI has thus far been relatively scarce, appropriately
framing the research question around 'explanatory variables for low
(FDI) interest'. Bulgaria's legal system, bureaucracy, and
crime are all perceived differentially by investors according to their
home country. According to UNCTAD (2007), by the end of 2004, Bulgaria
had attracted only 13.4% as much investment as the Czech Republic (7.6
billion versus 56.4 billion). The survey approach adopted by Bitzenis
unveils barriers, obstacles, and disincentives to investing in Bulgaria,
yet observes 'significant' Russian FDI there during years when
Russia's situation was even more volatile.
Finally, Brada et al. (2006) note the dramatically different levels
of FDI in Central European states vis-a-vis the Balkan region, and
examine the role of political risk as a factor. Dissatisfied with the
literature's measurement of political instability with reference to
strikes, riots, civil unrest, the authors apply the same equation to the
Balkans that they use in seven countries of the Visegrad and Baltic
regions, then examine the differences between expected and actual
outcomes. Using time-series data, they find clear evidence that FDI to
countries involved in conflict (notably Croatia, Bosnia, and Slovenia)
and their neighbors (Bulgaria and Romania) suffered, especially prior to
the Dayton Peace Accords of 1995. The return of relative stability since
that time has begun to attract better-than-expected inflows.
Table 2 summarizes the empirical contributions that follow the
'ownership' (country-of-origin effects) dimension of
Dunning's theoretical flamework as described in this section.
Together, these contributions represent a small but valuable
literature on home country motivating or enabling factors for FDI. Based
upon these examples, it can be concluded that an appropriate and
manageable scope of analysis is to focus upon a single destination
country in order to pay adequate attention to the variables themselves.
Two intuitively plausible enabling factors that are absent from the
specific literature discussed above are borrowed from elsewhere as
appropriate additions to the models. The first is agglomeration,
pioneered by Knickerbocker's (1973) work on oligopolistic reaction
and later empirically corroborated as a FDI location determinant by Head
et al. (1999). In short, when expanding to unfamiliar territory, firms
show a tendency to cluster in an effort to replicate success, obtain a
portion of a proven market, and/or share ancillary services. The second
additional variable also draws from research by Head et al. (1999), who
examine the role of investment promotion offices abroad without
empirical confirmation, leading to the inclusion of this variable in the
present study.
CzechInvest abroad: a context-specific origin-effect?
The agency CzechInvest was established in 1992 within the Czech
Republic's Ministry of Industry and Trade. Its staff handles
investment promotion and support in three phases: (1) International
Marketing, (2) Site Selection and Development, and (3) Aftercare. The
available services can be summarized as follows: information provision,
incentive handling, properties and supplier identification,
infrastructure development, and facilitation of structural funds
(CzechInvest, 2009). Examples include the 2009 completion of the Holesov
Strategic Industrial Zone, and the identification of partners for
expanding small and medium-sized investing firms.
Because Czech policy explicitly treats foreign business entities
identically to one another and to domestic entrepreneurs, the
expectation that policy in practice favors investors from certain
locations warrants some clarification. In short, following expectations
by Head et al. (1999) that US states' investment promotion offices
in Japan might play a role in investment to those states, it is
similarly anticipated that firms from countries with CzechInvest offices
will be more likely to invest in the Czech Republic. In Phase I of its
charge (International Marketing), the agency's presence abroad
captures enormous potential to create awareness of opportunities and
promote the Czech brand directly in targeted countries.
Breznitz (2007) examines government investment policy in Taiwan,
Israel, and Ireland. Ireland's operation of 17 investment offices
abroad is comparable to the Czech promotion strategy. Breznitz also
overviews tools at the disposal of government to guide industrial change
with the help of FDI, especially in the information technology sector.
Other aspects of government policy have already been analyzed in
the literature, although Beyer (2002) concludes that policy in general
has had only minimal impact on FDI in the region. Moreover, Mallya et
al. (2004) as well as Drahokoupil (2008) argue that any success in
attracting investment may not be worth the expense. Survey research by
Mallya et al. (2004) investigates the Czech National Incentive Scheme in
'crowding-in' investment, finding that, at best, it has
increased FDI in manufacturing by 10%. They argue that by using tax
holidays as the main incentive lever, a considerable net cost of US
$200,000-$400,000 is incurred by the host society for each new job.
Capik (2007) finds cause for optimism, but acknowledges that the
benefits to regions in Poland and the Czech and Slovak Republics are
undermined by fierce competition between investment promotion agencies.
Focusing exclusively on Central Europe, Drahokoupil (2008) assesses
critically what he calls the investment-promotion 'machines'
as ad hoc amalgamations of self-interested parties led by agencies such
as CzechInvest. He argues that the unfortunate Visegrad Four result is
'competition states' that lobby too hard for investment, often
at the expense of their own citizens and the integrity of their own laws
(2008, p. 206). Although his case studies confirm their effectiveness in
luring well-known foreign firms such as Nemak, LG Philips, BMW, PSA
Peugeot Citroen, Kia Motors, and Hyundai, he laments that they may also
lead to 'suffering and conflict within communities' (2008, p.
218).
Unfortunately, neither Mallya et al. (2004), Capik (2007), nor
Drahokoupil (2008) specifically question the role of CzechInvest offices
abroad, which have taken investment promotion to a new level with
foreign offices in Cologne, Chicago, Silicon Valley, London, Paris,
Yokohama, Hong Kong, and Brussels. It is no coincidence that Germany,
the United States, the United Kingdom, France, and Belgium represent
five of the top nine origins, with Japan following closely. Each
CzechInvest office itself represents a strategic location decision by
the Czech government, targeting industries in which Czechs consider
themselves competitive. Frelich (2006) points out that the Chicago
CzechInvest office courts American manufacturing companies, while the
Silicon Valley location was selected to reach the largest US cluster of
high technology firms. In addition to promoting the Czech Republic,
publicizing its partners and a highly skilled Czech workforce, the
office facilitates ongoing 'Aftercare' (Frelich, 2006).
METHODS AND DATA
This paper employs OLS regression to measure the role of
CzechInvest and other independent variables on cumulative inflows from
2000-2005 ('FDI0005'), as well as inflows during the peak year
of 2006 alone ('FDI06'). The dependent variables are reported
by the Czech National Bank (2007). FDI0005 is calculated by subtracting
the cumulative of FDI through 1999 from the value through the end of
2005 (in other words, resulting in the total FDI from 2000-2005). The
rationale for this simple calculation is to retain cumulative FDI
through 1999 as an independent variable for examining
'follow-the-leader' strategies without double counting.
Following the specification of models for cumulative flows, FDI during
2006--the largest annual inflow thus far--becomes the dependent variable
in order to compare the initial findings with those using more recently
published data.
Table 3 defines the independent variables, for which mean values
over 5 years (2000-2004) were used. The calculation of means is deemed
to be more realistic than using a time lag in this case because it is
capricious to estimate the length of time required for enabling factors
to influence decision-making. Moreover, mean values keep the handful of
observed outliers in check. Most of the independent variables are
remarkably stable over time, although the dependent variable spiked in
2005 because of major investment activity from specific origins. (4) In
the case of variables with skewed distributions (FDI values, GDP, AGG,
and TRADE), logarithms were calculated to product normal distributions.
Missing values are replaced by means, resulting in a maximum population
of 191 countries in the models.
In the initial model, all variables are entered as follows:
log[(FDI0005).sub.i] = [alpha] + [B.sub.1] log([GDP.sub.i]) +
[b.sub.2][GNI.sub.i] + [b.sub.3] log([AGG.sub.i]) +
[b.sub.4][EXRATE.sub.i] + [b.sub.5] log([TRADE.sub.i]) +
[b.sub.6][EU.sub.i] + [b.sub.5][CULT.sub.i] + [b.sub.8][TECH.sub.i] -
[b.sub.9][DIST.sub.i] + [b.sub.10][CZI.sub.i] + [b.sub.11][CPI.sub.i]
where log([FDI0005.sub.ij]) =logarithmic transformation of the
value of investments from home country i to the Czech Republic.
Subsequent models use the dependent variable log([FDI06.sub.i]) to
examine change in the role of the determinants, [alpha] = constant for
fitting the equation, [b.sub.1], ..., [b.sub.11] = coefficients for each
independent variable.
As summarized in Table 3, FDI in the Czech Republic is expected to
be positively related to the size of the origin economy, its market
strength, existing investment from that economy, exchange rates, trade
flows, and R&D personnel. Following Bandelj's (2002) work on
relational factors, FDI expected to be facilitated through EU membership
and cultural proximity, and discouraged by geographic distance. With
regard to government policy, in line with Benacek's (2008)
affirmation of CzechInvest as a model of government competence, the
expectation is that this agency is effective at attracting FDI. High
corruption levels at home (low corruption perception index (CPI)) are
expected to also encourage FDI in the Czech Republic as a relatively
transparent environment (ranked forty-seventh), following
Cuervo-Cazurra's (2008) assertion that additional costs and
uncertainty are associated with operating in corrupt countries.
Moderate collinearity is symptomatic of OLS regression of many
variables, and is anticipated especially in the initial model, which
simply represents a means to a more parsimonious solution. (5) In
addition to the large number of determinants called for by the
literature, home countries of investors are generally high-income, and
therefore share similar values on economic measures, which are highly
correlated with spatial characteristics such as distance and cultural
similarities. In response, variables are removed from successive models
as flagged by problematic simple correlation coefficients, tolerance,
and variance inflation factors (VIFs), keeping in mind the intention to
retain for examination of the variables that are poorly represented in
the literature and of greatest interest here: government policy (CZI),
and agglomeration (AGG).
ANALYSIS
This section reports upon five models that were specified to
identify the strongest origin effects, paying special attention to the
role of CzechInvest. To begin with, Model 1 includes all of the
variables as found to be justified by existing evidence from other
contexts. Next, a more parsimonious model (#2) is presented, specified
by Statistical Package for the Social Sciences (SPSS)'s forward
selection algorithm, and including the three best-performing
determinants. Third, a model (#3) is deliberately specified to include
agglomeration, EU membership, and CzechInvest presence abroad as these
variables are of greatest interest here. Model 4 replicates Model
3's independent variables, but considers FDI in 2006 as the
dependent variable. Finally, Model 5 is specified by SPSS's forward
selection algorithm to optimize for the year 2006 and compare mainly
with Model 2 (optimized through 2005). The overarching goal of this
approach is to triangulate through a series of model specifications and
identify continuity in variables that perform well across the models.
As an initial model, Model 1 includes all 11 variables and performs
quite close to expectations with most of the valence signs as predicted.
The variables that perform best are the logarithmic transformations of
agglomeration (AGG) and total trade (TRADE), both positive determinants
of FDI that are significant at the 0.001 level of confidence. Evidence
of follow-the-leader strategies in the Czech Republic corroborates
findings by Head et al. (1995, 1999) from the US context. The
observation that firms practice herd behavior by national origin is
discussed further in this section. Trade emerges as the second most
important origin-effect with regard to FDI in the Czech Republic,
perhaps as a precursor to FDI as originally observed in Sweden by
Johanson and Wiedersheim-Paul (1975). This evidence of complementarity
refutes earlier theory by Vernon (1966) that trade and FDI are
necessarily competitive modes of internationalization. This observation
also supports findings elsewhere in CEE by Brenton et al. (1998) and
Hunya (2000) that the two modes of internalization can reinforce one
another and are not mutually exclusive.
Subsequent variables that fall slightly short of significance in
the model include geographic distance (to which FDI is positively
related), CzechInvest offices abroad (negatively related), and the CPI,
which suggests that firms from countries with more transparent corporate
cultures are more likely to do business in the Czech Republic. The
unexpected valence relationship of FDI to geographic distance is
understandable because the top FDI origins include the United States
(#6), Japan (#11), Canada (#18), China (#27), and Mexico (#28)--all of
which are located far from Central Europe. Reasons underlying the
negative valence sign of government promotion in the first model are
unclear and support the need to examine the question more thoroughly in
subsequent specifications. However, especially given the fact that no
CzechInvest offices are located within the borders of three leading
origin countries--Netherlands, Austria, and Spain--it is plausible that
the agency's principle strategy is to make investors in non-leading
countries aware of opportunities in the Czech Republic. Certainly, this
explanation is plausible when looking at Japan and China (including Hong
Kong), both of which host CzechInvest offices but lie outside the list
of the top 10 investors. With regard to transparency, it is worth noting
that the Czech Republic also scores in the CPI's mid-range (4.3 out
of possible 10), tied with Greece and Slovakia at forty-seventh out of
158. This mid-range score and arbitrary result suggests that foreign
firms do not necessarily consider this detail relevant.
While the goal of Model 1 was to be inclusive of a wide range of
variables found in the literature, it makes little sense to dwell on
those that performed poorly in context of the Czech Republic. These
variables are worth mentioning but not inflating. While market size
(GDP) and strength (GNI), do predict FDI flow as expected, they are not
statistically significant. Reflecting on the data set, FDI from
countries with the world's largest markets (ie China and India)
remains dwarfed by that from smaller (mainly European) markets.
Similarly, a substantial amount of FDI from countries with relatively
low GNIs (Slovakia, Poland, Russia, and Mexico) confounds the
statistical significance for firms from high-income countries to invest
(GNI leaders like Luxembourg, Norway, Switzerland, USA, and Japan, and
much of Western Europe). As is common in OLS regression with many
variables, the collinearity statistics for Model 1 leave room for
improvement, with agglomeration having the highest VIF among the
variables at 4.218. This magnitude of collinearity is interpreted as
being unacceptably high, but such is to be expected with an inclusive
initial model in this exercise.
A tendency exists, albeit not statistically significant (p=0.196),
for cultural proximity to facilitate FDI in the Czech Republic, in
harmony with Zhao and Zhu's (2000) insights from the Chinese
context and Bandelj's (2002) examination of CEE. However, in
opposition to Bandelj's findings on bilateral relations with EU
members, actual EU membership since 2004 now seems to play a negative
role, corroborating earlier observations by Bevin and Estrin (2004) that
most importantly firms from non-EU countries see FDI as a strategy to
gain a foothold in the EU. Annual change in the real exchange rate
(REER) and the number of research and development personnel per 1000
(TECH) show no evidence of explaining the origins of FDI in the Czech
context. This final inconclusive observation with regard to these
variables reflects widely varying conditions in countries from which
firms originate.
The subsequent models in this exercise are intended to clear up
uncertainties about the results of Model 1. Model 2 is specified by the
SPSS forward selection algorithm as the optimal explanation of FDI
through 2005 and yields the variables agglomeration (AGG), trade
(TRADE), and transparency (CPI) as the critical origin effects with an
[R.sup.2] of 0.839 (Table 4), and a high level of significance:
agglomeration (p=0.000), trade (p=0.000), and corruption perceptions
index (p = 0.033). The results of collinearity tests in Model 2 were
satisfactory, with the minimum tolerance of 0.398 and maximum VIF of
2.512 (both AGG), meaning that the standard error for the coefficient of
AGG is 1.585 times as large as it would be if were uncorrelated with the
other independent variables. In light of these results, this variable
warrants specific discussion in the context of the Czech Republic.
Following Head et al. (1995), agglomeration is the realization of
positive externalities associated with the proximate location of related
firms, in this case related by a common national origin. Plausibly, this
factor is particularly important for firms that come from countries that
are culturally dissimilar to the Czech Republic (such as Japan and
Korea), and for this reason tend to follow--the leader, either to
provide ancillary services such as banking or insurance or in an attempt
to emulate the success of competitors. Reflection upon this result and
inspection of the data set suggest that agglomeration may be a key
variable for a small number of large firms (high investment value) from
Asia and North America, and not as important for firms from European
origins, which already share substantial cultural proximity with the
Czech Republic and therefore benefit from existing 'local'
knowledge (O'hUallachain and Reid, 1992).
The trade variable again performs well in Model 2 as a positive and
significant predictor of FDI, in harmony with findings by Brenton et al.
(1998) and Hunya (2000) elsewhere in CEE. As a form of spatial
interaction, FDI is itself not unlike trade, which Frankel (1997)
recently confirms to remain governed by gravity rules. Both forms of
interaction are directly related to the size of two objects--for
example, population size--and inversely related to the (geographic)
distance between them. What is interesting about the intuitive
commonality of these flows is that FDI in this context is not governed
by hypothesized similar predictors as originally postulated by Linnemann
(1966). This is probably because of overarching intense linkages between
the Czech Republic and major distant global traders such as the United
States, Japan, and Korea. In fact, recognizing the new potential of FDI
from Asia, the CzechInvest web site has recently expanded its language
menu, adding Japanese and Korean to the four European languages
(CzechInvest, 2009).
Finally, because the Czech Republic is not listed as a particularly
transparent country (4.3 on a scale of 1-10), it is difficult to
speculate upon the reason behind the tendency for firms from more
transparent countries to invest there. The findings refute the
expectation that corruption at home, as a form of home country risk,
serves as a catalyst for investing in the Czech Republic, as was found
in the more transparent environment of the USA (Grosse and Trevino,
1996). Because the Czech Republic is listed as only moderately
transparent, the ambiguity of this variable suggests that other factors
are at work in drawing FDI.
While Models 1 and 2 confirm the importance of agglomeration and
trade origin effects that are widely recognized from research on other
contexts, they offer little by way of new insights in the Czech context.
For this reason, it is worthwhile to re-run the model specifying only
the variables of greatest interest in this inquiry. Therefore,
agglomeration, EU membership, and CzechInvest are entered into Model 3.
Agglomeration is retained as it has been by far the best performing
variable so far. EU membership is of interest because the Czech Republic
joined the organization during the time period under investigation, and
because expectations of integration long preceded the actual event on 1
May 2004 (Bandelj, 2002; Bevin and Estrin, 2004). The presence of
CzechInvest offices abroad, of course, is the variable of main interest
in this study. Although only agglomeration is statistically significant,
together these three variables provide a very strong model with an
[R.sup.2] of 0.825, slightly lower than that of Model 2. It is worth
noting that very little explanatory power was lost by simplifying the
models from 11 to three variables.
Given the strong performance of Model 3, Model 4 features the same
specification for the dependent variable of FDI in 2006, (6) but with
agglomeration defined as cumulative FDI through the end of 2005, rather
than only 1999. The model performs quite well ([R.sup.2] = 0.479, p =
0.000), with all three expected determinants showing significance. As
oligopolistic reaction, EU membership, and CzechInvest have all been
thoroughly explained in preceding pages, there is no need to reiterate
the interpretations.
It is, however, worth underscoring the remarkable consistency among
determinants over time. The data for 2006 clearly show that EU
membership (negative) and CzechInvest promotion abroad (positive) have
grown in importance in 2006 vis-a-vis previously, as both the
coefficients of these variables and their significance levels have
increased using the new dependent variable; EU's p = 0.078;
CZI's p = 0.021, and the collinearity statistics show that Model 4
is the most in-check of all five models with a peak VIF of 1.795.
While Models 3 and 4 are specified based upon intuitive rationale,
Model 5 is run in order to observe the determinants that are
statistically most parsimonious. SPSS's algorithm selects in a
forward direction the most important independent variables for
explaining the 2006 FDI inflow, and accordingly its [R.sup.2] is 0.586,
somewhat higher than Model 4. Consistent with Models 1-4, the most
important explanatory variable is agglomeration.
Agglomeration is the only common explanatory variable among the
five models, and in each case it is significant at the 0.001 level. What
is new in the present study is that agglomeration is tested as an
origin-effect, in contrast to its use as a location determinant
elsewhere (Knickerbocker, 1973; Head et al., 1999). Aside from the role
of ancillary services linking firms from the same origin, a
company's demonstration of success likely attracts the attention of
other decision-makers at home, enticing them to follow suit. This
behavior has been documented by Head et al. (1999), among others, and
has also been anecdotally observed in the case of Japanese auto
manufacturers in the Czech Republic (Frelich, 2006).
It is important to note that cultural proximity (CULT) also appears
in Model 5, and that TRADE does not. Explained elsewhere as the desire
by firms to avoid problems related to cultural uncertainty (Grosse and
Trevino, 1996; Zhao and Zhu, 2000), it can also been seen as a form of
local knowledge (O' hUallachain and Reid, 1992). Why would it
appear first as a significant variable in 2006? A glance at the Czech
National Bank's investment figures yields the observation that many
Asian firms first arrived in the Czech Republic only in 2006. Japan and
South Korea each accounted for more than $118 million in FDI, led by
Hyundai, IPS Alpha, and Hitachi. A conspicuous absence of TRADE in Model
5 reveals a changing relationship with FDI that appears only in the
unprecedented 2006 inflow of FDI. This observation merits further
discussion in the forthcoming section on 'Implications and
Conclusions'.
The extended process of the Czech accession to the European Union
in May of 2004 has been instrumental in facilitating inward investment
(Bevin and Estrin, 2004). In addition, it is shown here that home
country EU membership plays little role in facilitating FDI, but also
that FDI from non-EU countries including European countries such as
Switzerland (#8) and Norway (#20) continues to thrive. This hints that
the Czech Republic may be seen from outside the EU as a favorable export
platform to the EU. Because this finding goes against Deichmann's
(2004) observations in neighboring Poland, another interpretation is
that the nature of inflows has changed over time and EU-based firms are
expanding farther eastward. Indeed, Czech National Bank (2007) data
confirm that hundreds of millions of dollars worth of FDI from EU
members, Italy, Spain, Belgium, Sweden, Denmark, and Portugal, were
withdrawn from the country.
The third major finding, based upon three of the five models, is
that CzechInvest's foreign promotion indeed represents an effective
government policy tool, lending credence to Benacek's (2008)
assertion of the agency's competence. While Mallya et al. (2004)
attempted elsewhere to interrogate the expense of government policy
vis-a-vis its benefits, it remains impossible to speculate on how much
investment would have taken place without CzechInvest offices. Moreover,
one can only estimate the intangible value for investing firms to have
Czech investment support available near their home country headquarters.
The strong support found here for the three dominant variables
should not entirely discount other variables. Among the conspicuously
weak variables from the perspective of economic geography is geographic
distance, which grosse and Trevino (1996) and Deichmann (2004) found to
be statistically significant in earlier work. The insignificance of the
variable in this case plausibly suggests that in the midst of
ever-increasing transportation and communications sophistication,
distance is becoming less of a barrier to economic interaction. Given
the clear importance of the variables discussed above, it is conceivable
that this traditionally prominent variable--one of two considerations in
Linnemann's (1966) traditional gravity model--could become
displaced by other considerations or the notion of distance, especially
when reflecting upon the substantial level of investment from smaller
neighboring countries as well as distant places such as Canada with
economies relatively smaller than traditional gravity-model champions
such as the USA and Japan.
IMPLICATIONS, LIMITATIONS, AND CONCLUSIONS
The empirical evidence presented here for the role of
agglomeration, trade flows, government policy, and the European Union
generates several suggestions for policy and further research. These
findings are particularly noteworthy in the context of the Czech
Republic because of its unique situation as a new EU member with a
prominent investment-promotion machine.
Although agglomeration strategies are well documented as a
determinant of location choice (Head et al., 1995, 1999), it is puzzling
that oligopolistic reaction has for the most part escaped scholarly
attention as an origin effect, or a strategy of follow-the-leader (from
one's own country). Moreover, oligopolistic reaction may become
more common as the complexity of international production and
distribution chains continues to increase. Further research should at
least take notice of a tendency for firms from a given origin to
'travel in packs'. Moreover, it would be most beneficial if
this complex question is approached through qualitative analysis, by
asking direct questions of decision-makers regarding inter-firm linkages
and reporting responses that might either support or refute the present
findings.
Trade flows are found to be a significant predictor of FDI through
2005, but not so in 2006. As FDI patterns develop over time, perhaps
they do so at the expense of trade flows, corroborating Vernon's
(1966) explanation of FDI as a more intimate level of internalization
that supplants arms-length trade. Evidence from an unprecedented inflow
of FDI in 2006 therefore supports Vernon's suggestion that the two
modes of serving an international market can be competitive and
redundant. As only modest evidence is offered here, this issue remains
to be settled through further inquiry in a broader context.
The European Union is the global frontrunner among economic
integration efforts. Its customs union, shared currency among an
ever-increasing number of member states, and near elimination of travel
and trade restrictions were expected to facilitate cross-border FDI.
Kinoshita and Campos (2003) and Eckert and Rossmeissl (2005) identified
membership prospects as an advantage among transition states in
attracting FDI, and the present data indicate that non-EU firms are more
interested than EU firms in investing in the Czech Republic, plausibly
as a means to access the EU. Brenton et al's early (1998)
expectation that accession plans would be unlikely to generate a surge
appear to have underestimated the role of integration. With reference to
the transient nature of firms and change in FDI patterns over time,
Eckert and Rossmeissl (2005) argue that FDI might yet move eastward,
into (new EU or non-EU) states with lower production costs. As time
progresses, further research examining Bulgaria, Romania, and other
places may shed light on this issue.
Empirical evidence for the variable CZI in 2006 suggests that Czech
policymakers should be encouraged with the results of Phase I of the
investment process: reaching out to transnational firms in their home
countries. Not only does CzechInvest's presence abroad provide
exposure to investment opportunities, it demonstrates a commitment to
support investors both in their home countries and in the Czech Republic
(Phases II and III), providing a compelling advantage for firms from
those seven countries. However, following Mallya et al. (2004) and
Drahokoupil (2008), policymakers should also reflect upon the expense of
this presence abroad, yet another direction for future inquiry.
Implications for government policy can also be extended beyond the
Czech Republic. This empirical evidence supports Benacek's (2008)
portrayal of CzechInvest as a model of public administration, so
additional credence is provided for his suggestion of general rules to
emulate this model, including the importance of policy continuity at the
national level and the need for such agencies to behave like a private
consultancy without charging their clients, rather than as a typical
government bureaucracy.
The limitations of the approach adopted here should also be
acknowledged. While many important enabling factors of home countries
have been identified, these findings cannot be generalized to the cases
of individual firms. Especially with regard to motivations of individual
decision-makers, a full understanding calls for parallel inquiry at the
firm level. For this reason, the case study approach would enhance the
depth of understanding presented here. Neither inquiry restricted to the
macroeconomic level nor that at the individual level is alone
sufficient; therefore more work remains to be done at the corporate
level with reference to firm characteristics and local conditions.
Moreover, to inspire substantiated suggestions for firms engaging in
FDI, it would be helpful to reflect upon the performance of firms that
have made decisions to invest, especially in the context of the current
global economic crisis.
In the interest of guiding further research, two additional trends
that were observed in the data warrant mentioning. The first is the
enormous and sustained outward flow of FDI from countries that were
until recently themselves to be considered 'transition
countries' and researched only as recipients of FDI. The second is
an enormous withdrawal of FDI by Western European and North American
firms from some leading transition countries (Wilson, 2009), presumably
in many cases to be relocated farther eastward as anticipated by Eckert
and Rossmeissl (2005), but also because of corporate hardship during
global economic downturn of the new millennium's first decade. It
has been noted in the present data set that disinvestment in the
hundreds of millions of dollars has taken place by firms from Italy,
Spain, Sweden, Denmark, Portugal, Taiwan, and Australia, all of which
have been large past suppliers of FDI to CEE. In addition to measuring
these trends, scholars should consider whether they can be linked to
conditions in the home countries, in the Czech Republic, perceived
better opportunities elsewhere, or some combination of these. Finally,
it will be worthwhile to examine the impact on investment flows to the
Czech Republic as data emerge from the present period of global
recession.
In conclusion, this research generates several models for assessing
the importance of specific origin effects and their ability to explain
the home countries of firms conducting FDI in the Czech Republic.
Supporting Knickerbocker's (1973) oligopolistic reaction theory,
agglomeration is found to be the most important variable across all
models, indicating that investors engage in
'follow-the-leader' behavior in an attempt to mimic successful
ventures from their own countries, as well as extending existing
inter-firm trade relationships to the Czech Republic. Evidence is also
presented that economic integration facilitates FDI from outside the EU
by firms seeking a foothold inside this growing market of 500 million,
the world's largest supranational bloc of accelerating human,
capital, and material mobility. The complementarity of trade and FDI is
confirmed through 2005, following Brenton et al. (1998), while evidence
from 2006 adds credence in the Czech context to Vernon's (1966)
theory that local production through FDI can take the place of trade.
Finally, this research demonstrates the importance of maintaining
CzechInvest office as tools for FDI promotion and support, as well as
reinforcing crucial role of cultural proximity (Bandelj, 2002) between
home countries and the Czech Republic.
In sum, this paper begins to fill a gap in the literature on origin
effects that enable and facilitate FDI, responding to supplications by
Hunya (2000, p. 87) to address this 'neglected issue'. The
findings provide insights into the unique Czech context during and
following its accession to the European Union and in response to its
investment promotion efforts abroad. The evidence does not categorically
refute mainstream origin effects, but rather examines them in a new
context, thereby adding to them the value of insights from the unique
Czech case. The paper also calls for further examination of
under-researched determinants, in particular government investment
promotion and economic integration. As the European Union expands
eastward, the 12 new additions from 2004 and 2007 are integrating and
changing rapidly, offering rich laboratories for further research on FDI
as a facet of globalization. Subsequent projects should therefore
reflect upon this changing context, interrogate the findings presented
here, and expand our collective understanding of origin effects.
APPENDIX See Table A1.
Table A1: Countries in the data set
Afghanistan
Albania
Algeria
Andorra
Angola
Antigua and Barbuda
Argentina
Armenia
Australia
Austria
Azerbaijan
Bahamas
Bahrain
Bangladesh
Barbados
Belarus
Belgium
Belize
Benin
Bhutan
Bolivia
Bosnia
Botswana
Brazil
Brunei
Bulgaria
Burkina Faso
Burma (Myanmar)
Burundi
Cambodia
Cameroon
Canada
Cape Verde
Central African Rep
Chad
Chile
China
Colombia
Comoros
Congo (Brazzaville)
Congo (Kinshasa)
Costa Rica
Cote d'Ivoire
Croatia
Cuba
Cyprus
Denmark
Djibouti
Dominica
Dominican Republic
East Timor
Ecuador
Egypt
Et Salvador
Equatorial Guinea
Eritrea
Estonia
Ethiopia
Fiji
Finland
France
Gabon
Gambia
Georgia
Germany
Ghana
Greece
Grenada
Guatemala
Guinea-Bissau
Guinea
Guyana
Haiti
Honduras
Hungary
Iceland
India
Indonesia
Iran
Iraq
Ireland
Israel
Italy
Jamaica
Japan
Jordan
Kazakhstan
Kenya
Kiribati
Korea (North)
Korea (South)
Kuwait
Kyrgyzstan
Laos
Latvia
Lebanon
Lesotho
Liberia
Libya
Liechtenstein
Lithuania
Luxembourg
Macedonia
Madagascar
Malawi
Malaysia
Maldives
Mali
Malta
Marshall Islands
Mauritania
Mauritius
Mexico
Micronesia
Moldova
Monaco
Mongolia
Morocco
Mozambique
Namibia
Nauru
Nepal
Netherlands
New Zealand
Nicaragua
Niger
Nigeria
Norway
Oman
Pakistan
Palau
Panama
Papua New Guinea
Paraguay
Peru
Philippines
Poland
Portugal
Puerto Rico
Qatar
Romania
Russian Federation
Rwanda
Saint Kitts and Nevis
Saint Lucia
Saint Vincent
Samoa
San Marino
Saudi Arabia
Senegal
Serbia/Montenegro
Seychelles
Sierra Leone
Singapore
Slovakia
Slovenia
Solomon Islands
Somalia
South Africa
Spain
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Suriname
Swaziland
Sweden
Switzerland
Syria
Taiwan
Tajikistan
Tanzania
Thailand
Togo
Tonga
Trinidad and Tobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Turkmenistan
Tuvalu
Uganda
Ukraine
United Arab Emirates
United Kingdom
United States
Uruguay
Uzbekistan
Venezuela
Vietnam
Yemen
Zambia
Zimbabwe
Acknowledgements
The author thanks the editor and three anonymous reviewers for
their helpful suggestions, and Bayar Tumennasan for his methodological
assistance.
REFERENCES
Ass, N and Beck, M. 2005: Foreign direct investment in post-Soviet
and Eastern European transition economies. The Business Review 3(2):
13-20.
Bandelj, N. 2002: Embedded economies: Social relations as
determinants of foreign direct investment in Central and Eastern Europe.
Social Forces 81 (2): 411-444.
Benacek, V. 2008: Management of the policies of development in the
Czech Republic: Czechlnvest as an example of public administration
competence. Proceedings of the 16th NISP Acee Annual Conference.
Bratislava, Slovakia,
http://wwwl.ceses.cuni.cz/benacek/Benacek-NISPA_Bratislava.pdf, accessed
10 November 2009.
Berglof, E (Chief Economist, Editor). 2008: Transition report:
Reforms, growth, and the macroeconomy. London: European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development.
Bevin, AA and Estrin, S. 2004: The determinants of foreign direct
investment into European transition economies. Journal of Comparative
Economics 32: 775-787.
Beyer, J. 2002: 'Please invest in our country'--how
successful were the tax incentives for foreign investment in transition
countries? Communist and Post-Communist Studies 35(2): 191-211.
Bitzenis, A. 2004: Explanatory variables for low western investment
interest in Bulgaria. Eastern European Economics 42(6): 5-38.
Blonigen, B. 2005: A review of the empirical literature on FDI
determinants. Atlantic Economic Journal 33(December): 383-403.
Brada, JC, Kutan, AM and Yigit, TM. 2006: The effects of transition
and political instability on foreign direct investment flows: Central
Europe and the Balkans. Economics of Transition 14(4): 649-680.
Brenton, P, Di Munro, F and Lucke, M. 1998: Economic integration
and FDI: An empirical analysis of foreign investment in the EU and in
Central and Eastern Europe. Kiel Working Paper #890. Available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/downloaded 12 October 2006.
Breznitz, D. 2007: Innovation and the state: Political choice and
strategies for growth in Israel. New Haven and London: Yale University
Press.
BusinessInfo.cz. 2006: (Czech Business Web Portal). Bank of
Tokyo-Mitsubishi UFJ opens a branch in Prague,
http://businessinfo.cz/en/articles/czech-republic-business-news, last
accessed 17 October 2006.
Capik, P. 2007: Organising FDI promotion in Central-Eastern
European regions. Place Branding and Public Diplomacy 3(2): 152-163.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. 2008: Better the devil you don't know:
Types of corruption and FDI in transition economies. Journal of
International Management 14: 12-27.
Czech National Bank. 2007: Balance of payment statistics--Foreign
Direct Investment. Available at
http://www.cnb.cz/en/statistics/bop_stat/fdi/, last accessed 12 December
2009.
CzechInvest. 2009: CzechInvest homepage,
http://www.czechinvest.org/en, last accessed 10 November 2009.
Deichmann, JI. 2004: The origins of foreign direct investment in
Poland, 1989-2001. Journal of Business and Economic Studies 10(1):
12-28.
Dikova, D and van Witteloostuijn, A. 2007: Foreign direct
investment mode choice: Entry and establishment modes in transition
economies. Journal of International Business Studies 38: 1013-1033.
Drahokoupil, J. 2008: The investment-promotion machines: The
politics of foreign direct investment in Central and Eastern Europe.
Europe-Asia Studies 60(2): 197-225.
Dunning, J. 1980: Toward an eclectic theory of international
production: Some empirical tests. Journal of International Business
Studies 11: 9-31.
Dunning, J. 2001: The eclectic (OLI) paradigm of international
production: Past, present, and future. International Journal of the
Economics of Business 8(2): 173-190.
Eckert, S and Rossmeissl, E 2005: Consequences of
convergence--Western firms' FDI activities in Central and Eastern
Europe at the dawning of EU-enlargement. Journal for East European
Management Studies 10(1): 55-74.
Frankel, J. 1997: Regional trading blocs in the world economic
system. Washington DC: Institute for International Economics.
Frelich, B. 2006: Personal interviews with CzechInvest's
Chicago director. Chicago, IL, and telephone discussions, March and
April.
Froot, K and Stein, J. 1991: Exchange rates and foreign direct
investment: An imperfect capital markets approach. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 106(4): 1191-1218.
Grosse, R and Trevino, L. 1996: Foreign direct investment in the
United States: An analysis by country of origin. Journal of
International Business Studies 27(1): 139-155.
Grosse, R and Trevino, L. 2005: New institutional economics and FDI
location in Central and Eastern Europe. Management International Review
45(2): 123-145.
Head, CK, Ries, JC and Swenson, DL. 1999: Attracting foreign
manufacturing: Investment promotion and agglomeration. Regional Science
and Urban Economics 29: 197-218.
Head, K, Ries, J and Swenson, D. 1995: Agglomeration benefits and
location choice: Evidence from Japanese manufacturing investment in the
United States. Journal of International Economics 38(3-4): 223-247.
Hunya, G. 2000: Home country patterns of foreign direct investment
in Central and Eastern European countries. Russian and East European
Finance and Trade 36(2): 87-104.
Janicki, HP and Wunnava, PV. 2004: Determinants of foreign direct
investment: Empirical evidence from EU accession candidates. Applied
Economics 36: 505-509.
Johanson, J and Wiedersheim-Paul, R 1975: The internalization of
the firm--Four Swedish cases. Journal of Management Studies 12 (3):
305-322.
Kinoshita, Yand Campos, NF. 2003: Why does FDI go where it does?
New evidence from the transition economies. William Davidson Institute
Working Paper Number 573, June.
Knickerbocker, F. 1973: Oligopolistic reaction and multinational
enterprise. Boston: Harvard University.
Linnemann, H. 1966: An econometric study of international trade
flows. North-Holland: Amsterdam.
Luo, Y. 1998: Strategic traits of foreign direct investment in
China: A country of origin perspective. Management International Review
38(2): 109-132.
Mallya, TJS, Kukulka, Z and Jensen, C. 2004: Are incentives a good
investment for the host country? An empirical evaluation of the Czech
National Incentive Scheme. Transnational Corporations 13(1): 110-148.
O'hUallachain, B and Reid, N. 1992: Source country differences
in the spatial distribution of foreign direct investment in the United
States. The Professional Geographer 44: 272-285.
Pavlinek, P. 2004: Regional development implications of foreign
direct investment in Central Europe. European Urban and Regional Studies
11(1): 47-70.
Transparency International. 2007: Corruption perceptions index,
http://www.transparency.org/policy_research/surveys_indices/cpi,
accessed 12 August 2007.
UNCTAD. 2007: World investment report 2007 New York and Geneva:
United Nations. Also available at
http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/wir2008_en.pdf, accessed 15 December 2008.
UNCTAD. 2008: FDI inward stock, by host region and economy,
1980-2006, http://stats.unctad.org/FDI/, accessed 15 December.
Vernon, R. 1966: International investment and international trade
in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics 81: 190-207.
WAIPA. 2008: World association of investment promotion agencies.
Members List. Available at http://www.waipa.org/members.htm, accessed 15
December.
Wilson, A. 2009: Czech republic sees FDI drop-off. Eastern European
Times. Available at www.eetinres.eu/eastern_Europe, accessed 22 July.
World Bank. 2008: Key development data and statistics,
http://web.worldbank.org/, data obtained 20 July.
Zhao, H and Zhu, G. 2000: Location factors and country-of-origin
differences: An empirical analysis of FDI in China. Multinational
Business Review 8(1): 60-73.
(1) UNCTAD defines FDI as direct investment made to acquire lasting
interest of at least 10% ownership in enterprises operating outside of
the economy of the investor, and reports annual and cumulative national
inflows at http://stats.unctad.org/FDI/.
(2) Poland's PAIiIZ, Hungary's ITDH, Russia's NAPI,
for example; a complete list is available at
http://www.waipa.org/members.htm.
(3) See, for example http://www.tax-consultants-international.com/.
(4) For example, Spain is the leading origin for 2005 only because
of Telefonica's $4.8 billion investment. All other Spanish
investment totals about $500 million.
(5) A collinearity matrix has been generated as is available from
the author. In the interest of space, it has been omitted from this
paper.
(6) The correlation between the two dependent variables (logFDI0005
and logFDI06) is 0.720, significant at the 0.01 level.
JOEL I. DEICHMANN
Global Studies Department, Bentley University, 175 Forest Street,
Waltham, Massachusetts 02452, USA. E-mail: jdeichmann@bentley.edu
Table 1: Leading cumulative origins of
FDI in the Czech Republic through 2005
Rank Country Value ($mil)
1 Germany 14,099.64
2 Netherlands 10,583.38
3 Spain 5100.23
4 Austria 4473.49
5 France 3759.42
6 United States 2459.52
7 United Kingdom 2232.54
8 Switzerland 1598.99
9 Belgium 1491.94
10 Slovakia 1089.89
11 Japan 981.57
12 Sweden 926.68
13 Poland 715.84
14 Luxembourg 671.06
15 Italy 529.98
16 Denmark 511.20
17 Cyprus 391.48
18 Canada 318.91
19 Liechtenstein 166.06
20 Norway 140.44
21 Hungary 135.06
22 Russia 128.02
23 Ireland 122.99
24 Finland 81.37
25 Malta 75.93
26 Portugal 69.29
27 China 51.17
28 Mexico 48.94
29 Seychelles 45.29
30 Slovenia 37.88
Source: Czech National Bank (2007)
Table 2: Summary of empirical research on origin effects
Authors (Year) Context Variables
Froot and Stein (1991) USA Exchange Rates (-)
O'hUallach6in and Reid (1992) USA Geographic distance Local
knowledge (+)
Grosse and Trevino (1996) USA Imports (-), exports (+),
home GDP (+), geographic
distance
cultural distance
(-), home risk (+),
exchange rates (-)
Brenton et al. (1998) CEE Geographic distance (-),
population (+), trade (+)
Head et at. (1999) USA Agglomeration by origin
(+), offices abroad (+)
Zhao and Zhu (2000) China Cultural similarities (+)
Hunya (2000) CEE Geographic distance (-),
population (+)
Bandelj (2002) CEE Cultural relations between
investors and hosts (+),
including trade (+)
Deichmann (2004) Poland GNP (+), trade (+), EU
membership (+), migration
(+), distance (-)
Bitzenis (2004) Bulgaria Cultural similarities (+),
geographic distance (-),
historical links (+)
Table 3: Explanation of variables
Variable Definition (units) Valence source
FD70005 FDI value 2000-2005 inclusive Czech National
(thousand US$) Bank (2007)
FD106 FDI inflow during the year 2006 Czech National
(thousand US$) Bank (2007)
GDP Gross domestic product, mean + World Bank (2008)
2000-2004 (million US$)
GNI Gross National Income per capita + World Bank (2008)
(mean 2000-2004)
AGG Cumulative Value of FDI at the + Czech National
end of 1999 Bank (2007)
REER Average annual change in exchange + World Bank (2008)
rate index, 2000-2004
TRADE Imports+Exports with partner i, + Czech National
mean 2000-2004 (in Kc) (a) Bank (2007)
EU Dummy for 15 European Union + www.europa.eu
members in 2004 (1, 0)
CULT Cultural proximity between origin + Deichmann (2004)
i and destination j (most=5,
least=1) (b)
TECH Researchers in science and + World Bank (2007)
engineering (per million)
DIST Distance between leading cities - http://
of country i (as defined by www.mapcrow.info/
Frankel, 1997) and Prague (in km)
CZI CzechInvest offices in origin + CzechInvest (2009)
country i (number: 0, 1, 2)
CPI Corruption Perceptions Index - Transparency
(high value=low corruption) International
(2007)
(a) Initially, the modest were run with imports and exports as
separate variables, in part to investigate Frankel's (1997) finding
that in the USA they behave differently as origin effects. However,
in the Czech context this resulted in collinearity, so a new variable
TRADE' (imports + exports) was calculated. The simple correlation
between imports and exports in the data set was 0.981, and that
between their log transformations was 0.988, both significant at the
0.01 level.
(b) Home countries are assigned scores of 1-5 with reference to
cultural similarities to the Czech Republic, using the proxy of
language and alphabet. '5' is for countries using Slavonic languages
and Latin alphabet lie Poland); '4' is for Slavonic languages and
Cyrillic alphabet (ie, Russia), or Germanic languages and Latin
alphabet (Austria, USA--noting that most Czechs speak English); '3'
is for Romance languages (France); '2' is for all others using the
Latin alphabet as Czechs do (Albania); and '1' is for minimal
similarities (China, Japan).
Table 4: Coefficients and significance
levels of variables in the models
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
coefficients coefficients coefficients
Independent Variable LogFDI0005 LogFDI0005 logFDI0005
Constant -1.046 -0.222 0.645 (a)
logGDP 0.045
GNI 0.00001266
AGG (99/05) 0.941 (a) 0.896 (a) 0.943 (a)
REER 0.000
logTRADE 0.163 (c) 0.175 (a)
EU -0.845 -0.023
CU LT 0.245
TECH -0.000068
DIST 0.000071
CZI -1.214 -0.042
CPI 0.177 0.204 (a)
[R.sup.2] 0.847 (a) 0.839 (a) 0.825 (a)
Model 4 Model 5
coefficients coefficients
Independent Variable LogFDI06 logFDI06
Constant 0.577 (b) -0.856
logGDP
GNI
AGG (99/05) 0.555 (a) 0.426 (a)
REER
logTRADE
EU -1.976 (b) -1.096
CU LT 1.081 (a)
TECH
DIST
CZI 2.437 (b) 2.662 (b)
CPI
[R.sup.2] 0.479 (a) 0.528 (a)
(a) Statistically significant at the 0.001 level (two-tailed).
(b) Statistically significant at the 0.05 level (two-tailed).
(c) Statistically significant at the 0.005 level (two-tailed).
Model 1: All variables entered (through 2005).
Model 2: Stepwise (optimal model, through 2005).
Model 3: Enter (variables of greatest interest, through 2005).
Model 4: Enter (variables of greatest interest, 2006).
Model 5: Stepwise (optimal model for 2006).
Note: AGG is defined as cumulative FDI value through 1999 for
Models 1, 2, and 3 and cumulative value through 2005 for Models 4
and 5