Corruption and the institutional environment for growth.
Heckelman, Jac C. ; Powell, Benjamin
INTRODUCTION
The development policy community widely believes that reducing
corruption would improve growth rates in less developed countries. Since
1996, the World Bank has supported more than 600 anticorruption programs
and governance initiatives developed by its member countries and
publicly sanctioned 338 firms and individuals for corrupt practices. The
World Bank also maintains an Institutional Integrity Department that
investigates corrupt practices with a staff of more than 50 employees
and consultants, and expenditures of more than $10 million annually
(World Bank, 2007). (1) According to Institutional Integrity Department
director Suzanne Rich Folsom, 'Corruption has a devastating impact
on the capacity of governments to function properly; on the private
sector to grow and create employment; on the talents and energies of
people to add value in productive ways; and ultimately on societies to
lift themselves out of poverty' (World Bank, 2007). (2)
Other development agencies express similar sentiments. For example,
according to USAID:
Corruption ... undermines economic development. In the private
sector, corruption increases the cost of business through the price
of bribes themselves, the management cost of negotiating with
officials, and the risk of breached agreements or detection.
Although some claim corruption reduces costs by cutting red tape,
an emerging consensus holds that the availability of bribes induces
officials to contrive new rules and delays. (USAID) (3)
Despite these widely held beliefs, some economists, going back to
at least Left (1964) and Huntington (1968), believe that corruption can
enhance growth by allowing individuals to pay bribes in order to
circumvent inefficient rules and bureaucratic delays. Simply put, in
much of the third world corruption is needed to get things done. If
corruption is reduced without corresponding changes to eliminate
inefficient rules, business activity and economic growth may slow down.
If a first best solution of 'good rules' is unavailable then
corruption that avoids some of the restrictions created by bad rules
becomes a second best solution and an alternative path to growth.
To investigate this hypothesis we examine the empirical
relationship between corruption and growth when we interact political
and economic institutions with corruption. Previous studies (Aidt et
al., 2008; Mendez and Sepulveda, 2006; Meon and Sekkat, 2005) have
examined, with mixed results, how political institutions impact the
relationship between corruption and growth. We directly build on this
literature by first including proxies for political institutions into
our analysis and then interacting them with a measure of corruption. We
find the results differ dramatically depending on the type of
institutions considered. In particular, corruption is found to be more
beneficial to growth for greater levels of democracy, a seemingly
perverse result, but one that is consistent with Mendez and Sepulveda
(2006). The reverse, however, is found when considering economic
institutions; corruption is more beneficial when economic freedom is
low, and the benefits diminish as economic freedom improves. We also
find that among the different types of economic freedom, this result is
driven primarily by the size of government and extent of regulatory
burdens.
Our paper proceeds as follows. In the next section we discuss other
studies that have examined the relationship between corruption and
growth and in particular we focus on the recent studies that have
incorporated political institutions into their empirical analysis and
describe how our study differs. A description of our data follows in the
subsequent section. Our empirical methodology and results are presented
in the penultimate section. The final section highlights specific
findings and offers suggestions for further research in this area.
LITERATURE REVIEW
Corruption and growth
Numerous academic articles give credence to the development policy
community's views about corruption. On the theoretic level Shleifer
and Vishny (1993) argue that, for example, when it is necessary to get
permission from many individuals for a project, and each has veto power
over approval, the cost of corruption will rise and slow economic
growth. Myrdal (1968) argues that corrupt officials may use their
arbitrary power to create delays and barriers that would not otherwise
exist in order to collect more bribes. Krueger (1974) represents a
classic study of socially inefficient rent-seeking through corrupt trade
restriction enforcement. In cases of corruption such as these, the de
facto institutional environment would restrict economic activity more
than the de jure legal restrictions on the official books.
However, there is also reason to believe that corruption could be
good for economic growth. Lui (198S) shows that corruption can shorten
the amount of time waiting in queues. (4) In the face of bureaucratic
delays that slow business formation or restrictions that prevent
businesses and consumers from exploiting potential gains from trade,
corrupt officials who circumvent inefficient rules could actually
enhance growth. Some positive level of corruption may even be
growth-maximizing in countries with relatively efficient rules because
as corruption decreases it becomes increasingly costly to eliminate it
entirely, much like crime in general (Klitgaard, 1988). Colombatto
(2003) also analyzes corruption theoretically in a variety of different
institutional environments and finds that in some cases corruption can
be efficient in developed countries as well as in totalitarian ones.
The empirical literature using cross-country data to estimate how
corruption affects growth is mixed, reflecting the various offsetting
theoretic effects corruption may have. Mauro (1995) produced the seminal
study for empirically investigating corruption's impact on growth
for a wide cross-section of countries. He found that higher levels of
corruption significantly decrease both investment and economic growth,
but his findings were sensitive to the choice of specification. Poirson
(1998) and Leite and Weidmann (1999) found that corruption has a
negative effect on growth. Mo (2001) found that corruption decreases
growth after controlling for investment, but that the effect of
corruption becomes insignificant once education is controlled.
Gyimah-Brempong (2002) found that corruption decreased growth rates and
increased income inequality among a sample of exclusively African
nations. However, Brunetti et al. (1997) found inconclusive results and
Wedeman (1997) found that many corrupt countries have rapid growth
rates. In Svensson's (2005) survey article on corruption, he
updated Mauro's calculations and although he found corruption did
have a negative coefficient it was not statistically significant.
Svensson concluded that 'to the extent we can measure corruption in
a cross-country setting, it does not affect growth' (p. 39). (5)
Our hypothesis is that the empirical literature is unable to sort
out whether corruption is beneficial or harmful to growth in a
cross-country setting because most earlier studies have not controlled
for institutional quality. In countries where the institutional
environment is relatively good, we expect that corruption will mainly
take the form of rent-seeking activities that slow growth. In contrast,
when the institutional environment presents a low level of economic
freedom, we expect that entrepreneurs will use bribes to circumvent
cumbersome regulations and thus corruption will promote growth) Next we
review the few existing studies that have examined how corruption
effects growth while including measures of institutional quality and
explain how we add to that literature.
Controlling for institutions
Recent empirical studies have begun to examine corruption's
impact on economic growth contingent on a country's institutional
environment. Typically political, rather than economic, institutions
have been the focus. Mendez and Sepulveda (2006) use the Freedom House
democracy index, which measures civil liberties and political rights.
After splitting countries into groups classified as 'free' or
'not-free', they find no relationship between corruption and
growth in 'not-free' countries but a small, positive,
growth-maximizing level of corruption in 'free' countries.
Aidt et al. (2008) control for political institutions using the
voice and accountability index, one of five indicators of governance
constructed by Kaufmann et al. (1999). This index attempts to measure
the degree to which citizens participate in the selection of their
government and have the ability to hold government officials responsible
for policy outcomes. Aidt et al. also find a nonlinear relationship
between corruption and growth once political institutions are
controlled, but the pattern is somewhat different from the findings of
Mendez and Sepulveda (2006). Aidt et al. conclude that when political
institutions are of 'low quality', corruption has little
impact on growth. However, unlike Mendez and Sepulveda, they find that
'high quality' political institutions result in corruption
being harmful to growth.
Meon and Sekkat (2005) examine whether corruption 'greases the
wheels' or 'sands the wheels' of economic growth when
institutional quality and corruption interact. Their measure of
institutional quality combines both political and some economic
institutions. They use all five of Kaufmann et al.'s (1999)
indicators of governance, namely: (A) 'voice and
accountability', (B) 'lack of political violence', (C)
'government effectiveness', (D) 'regulatory burden',
and (E) 'rule of law'. Meon and Sekkat find that the
'regulatory burden' and 'voice and accountability'
measures are not significant in any of their specifications when they
interact them with corruption. They find, however, that the 'rule
of law' and 'government effectiveness' measures are
consistently statistically significant when interacted with corruption,
and that as institutional quality decreases corruption becomes more
harmful to growth. They conclude that, on net, net corruption
'sands the wheels' of economic growth, supporting the
conventional view, rather than 'greasing the wheels' by
allowing individuals to circumvent bad governance.
Each of these three studies furthers our knowledge of how political
institutional quality impacts the relationship between corruption and
growth. Mendez and Sepulveda (2006) and Aidt et al. (2008) both find no
relationship between corruption and growth in countries with low quality
political institutions but they reach conflicting conclusions in
countries with high quality political institutions. Meon and Sekkat
(2005) find that corruption is harmful for growth overall and that it is
even more harmful in countries with low quality political institutions.
None of these studies support the view that corruption can increase
growth in countries with low quality institutions.
However, none of these studies directly control for the role of
economic institutions while investigating the interplay between
corruption and democracy. Furthermore, only Meon and Sekkat (2005)
examine the connection between economic institutions and the effect of
corruption on growth, but their measure of economic institutions is
quite limited.
We build on the current corruption-institutions growth literature
by examining the relationship between corruption and growth while
controlling for, and interacting, both the quality of political
institutions and economic institutions. Existing studies have advanced
our understanding by pointing to a nonlinear relationship between
corruption and growth contingent on institutional quality. Our main
interest is in testing specific areas in which corruption may be able to
grease the wheels to circumvent inefficient regulations and improve
growth. We expect that if corruption is to grease the wheels of growth,
this would occur in places in which the economic freedoms beneficial to
growth are restricted and barriers prevent voluntary exchange from
exploiting the gains from trade. (7) When economic, rather than
political, freedom is low, corruption is most likely to improve growth.
To test this, we interact both general levels of economic freedom and
specific sub-areas of economic freedom with corruption, while
controlling for the overall level of democracy. Our results are the
reverse of those found for the interrelationship between democracy and
corruption growth. We find that corruption 'greases the
wheels' of growth when economic freedom is low but the benefit of
corruption diminishes when economic institutions improve. Among the
different areas of economic freedom (described below), this effect is
driven primarily by the separate categories of government size and
regulation.
DATA
Our empirical focus is on the differential impact of corruption on
growth, dependent upon the level of economic freedom. We first describe
our measures of corruption, democratization, and economic freedom, and
compare them against other measures in the literature. We then briefly
describe our other variables.
Our measure of corruption comes from Transparency
International's (1995-2000) Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI),
which has been utilized in many studies. The CPI is an 'index of
indexes' that averages scores from 16 different surveys of the
perceived level of corruption in a country. A nation must have a score
for at least two of the surveys to be included in the CPI. The index is
scaled from 0 (most corrupt) to 10 (most clean). In our empirical
analysis we have inverted the index so that greater values represent
more, rather than less, corruption. The recent studies that examine
corruption and growth while controlling for political institutions (Meon
and Sekkat, 2005; Mendez and Sepulveda, 2006; Aidt et al., 2008) use a
variety of different measures of corruption, but the CPI is the only
measure used in all of them. Thus, our choice of the CPI as a measure of
corruption better enables comparison of our results with these studies.
The CPI has been calculated on an annual basis since 1995. The
underlying survey scores on which the CPI is based are not available,
however, and the number of surveys used to calculate the index and the
number of countries covered varies from year to year. The original 1995
index covered only 41 countries, but by 2000 it included 90 countries.
The CPI was chosen as our measure of corruption because of data
availability, country coverage, and ability to compare our results to
prior studies. Although the index is not consistently measured over
time, due to the varying number of surveys included, the fact that the
CPI is based on multiple surveys with different methodologies helps to
reduce measurement error associated with a single survey. We add a
robustness check replicating our main regression with only 2000 index
values to account for the changes in the index.
Alternative indexes of corruption are available from the Institute
for Management Development (IMD) and the International Country Risk
Guide (ICRG). The IMD index covers only 50 countries, however. The ICRG
measures the risk involved in corruption rather than the perceived level
of corruption. These two proxies for corruption can conceivably differ
from each other because public attitudes toward corruption vary between
countries (Svensson, 2005, p. 22). However, Mendez and Sepulveda (2006)
have shown that for the countries in which the three indexes overlap,
the CPI is highly correlated with both the ICRG index (0.91) and the IMD
index (0.96), thereby suggesting that the choice of corruption index is
unlikely to greatly influence the estimation results. Indeed, in their
comparative study, Mendez and Sepulveda (2006) showed their fundamental
results were robust across all three measures.
There may also be some concern that there could be problems with
relying on the CPI and related indexes because they are based on
subjective perceptions. Unfortunately, as noted by Svensson (2005),
'hard evidence' on corruption is available for only a limited
set of countries. The strong correlations noted above among the standard
indexes at least suggest that our results from using the CPI will not be
driven by a particular form of subjectivity.
Our measure of political institutions is the traditional Polity IV
index. The Polity IV index ranks a country's political institutions
by giving each country a score from -10 to 10, ranging from pure
autocracy to consolidated democracy. Polity IV scores are based on: the
presence of institutions and procedures through which citizens can
express their preferences; presence of institutionalized constraints on
the executive; civil liberties for citizens in political participation
and their daily lives; the extent of suppression of competitive
political participation; and whether chief executives are chosen in a
regularized process within the political elite. For ease of comparison
to our economic freedom variable described below, and for interpreting
interaction coefficients involving this democracy proxy, we have
rescaled the Polity IV data to range from 0 to 10.
We chose to measure democracy using Polity IV data rather than the
index of political rights and civil liberties from Freedom House used by
Mendez and Sepulveda (2006). (8) The political rights index incorporates
a direct measure of corruption, which would hinder estimation of an
independent relationship between corruption and democracy. Similarly,
the civil liberties index is based in part on respect for the rule of
law, which many economists treat as a proxy for economic institutions in
its own right to measure property rights (Knack and Keefer, 1995; Barro,
1997; Aron, 2000), and is part of the index we use to measure the
quality of economic institutions. Given that we want to specifically
differentiate between democratic and economic institutions with separate
proxy variables, relying on the civil liberties index would be
problematic. (9) Still, for our sample, the Polity values are strongly
correlated with both the political rights index (0.91) and civil
liberties index (0.83). (10)
Our measure of economic institutions comes from Gwartney and
Lawson's (2006) Economic Freedom of the World Annual Report. Their
economic freedom of the world (EFW) index currently uses 37 criteria to
measure freedom levels in five broad areas: size of government; legal
structure and property rights; access to sound money; freedom to
exchange with foreigners; and regulation of credit, labor, and business.
Each area score is based on the average value of the different
components in that area (see Appendix A). Each component is assigned a
value from 0 (least freedom) to 10 (most freedom). The overall index
value is the simple average of the five area scores. (11)
The EFW index provides a more direct measure of restrictive
policies for which the 'grease the wheels' form of corruption
would be necessary to circumvent. Meon and Sekkat's (2005) measures
of government effectiveness, regulatory burden, and rule of law have
come the closest thus far to measuring the inefficient economic
institutions that corruption might circumvent. Indeed, proxies for the
latter two are included as part of the EFW index. However, Meon and
Sekkat's government effectiveness measure also includes variables
that could themselves be proxies for measures of corruption, such as the
independence of the civil service from political pressures and the
credibility of the government's commitment to policies. Their
regulatory burden measure seems more directly related to the form of
corruption that could potentially grease the wheels of development, but
it is never statistically significant in their regressions. Area 5 of
the EFW provides a broader measure of regulation that represents 14
specific components of regulation across the areas of credit, labor, and
business. One of the five components of business regulation represents
'irregular payments' (C.v.), which could be considered a
measure of corruption. As such, this component is dropped from the EFW
index we use. (12) Area 2 of the EFW index includes five measures of the
legal structure and protection of property rights similar to Meon and
Sekkat's rule of law measure.
The EFW index also has the advantage over the Kaufmann et al.
(1999) index in its coverage of the size of government (Area 1), which
includes measures of government spending, transfers, ownership of
enterprises and investment, and tax rates. Clearly, there are
opportunities for corruption in these areas that could either grease or
sand the wheels of development. The inclusion of measures for access to
sound money (Area 3) and freedom to trade with foreigners (Area 4) in
the EFW index provide additional areas of institutional variation in
which corruption could potentially grease the wheels. Meon and Sekkat
(2005) do include a measure of trade openness but do not interact it
with corruption. Also, their measure includes exports and imports as a
percent of GDP, which reflects non-regulatory factors, such as
geography, in which corruption could not lead to greasing the wheels of
development. (13) The EFW index focuses directly on trade barriers in
which corruption could potentially increase efficiency and growth. It
uses various measures to assess tariff and regulatory barriers to trade,
and exchange rate and capital controls. In all of these areas,
corruption has the potential to actually improve economic growth. For
example, if the de jure rule is a 500% tariff rate, and customs
officials can be bribed to allow goods in for less than that,
international trade, and potentially growth, could increase. Thus, we
focus on a measure of institutions that, although still imperfect, more
directly measures the types of economic policies for which corruption
could potentially minimize the harm done by restrictions and thus
promote growth. Because separate area scores are available, we can
further investigate which, if any, of the economic institutions affect
the relationship between corruption and growth.
Although most of the components comprising the EFW index are based
on objective data, a variety of subjective measures are used to
determine Area 2 for legal structure and protection of property rights
in which objective measures are less readily available. These measures
are collected from outside sources published by ICRG and Global
Competitiveness Report. Thus, all the component scores that comprise the
EFW are at least easily verifiable, which is not true of several other
indexes (eg, Heritage Foundation Index of Economic Freedom) that have
been used to proxy for the extent of economic freedom. It is important
to note that many of the economic environment data used by Meon and
Sekkat (2005) are also based on subjective evaluations.
Our base regression also includes the starting level of GDP per
capita and investment to GDP ratio, both taken from the World
Bank's World Development Indicators. Another standard determinant
of growth is the extent of human capital. Country coverage for such
variables is often incomplete. As such, our primary regressions do not
include any controls for human capital, but we do consider the effect of
including an education variable from Barro and Lee (2000) as a
robustness check. Finally, we also include a set of regional dummies to
control for any remaining unobserved heterogeneity that may differ
systematically by geographic location. (14)
ANALYSIS
Descriptive statistics
Our period of analysis is determined by the availability of CPI
data, which begins in 1995, therefore, like Aidt et al. (2008), we are
limited to explaining short-run growth rates. To avoid the potential for
single-year anomalies, we use average values for the explanatory
variables (except starting year GDP to capture the 'catch-up'
effect). Averages over several years are also important for our main
variables of focus because corruption and economic freedom are likely
long-term phenomena that only change slowly and also because our
measures of corruption are surveys of peoples' opinions, which are
likely influenced by many prior years' experience with corruption.
(15) To ensure a sufficient number of years for both averaging the
independent variables and still avoiding as much endogeneity as possible
by not overlapping with the growth period used as the dependent
variable, we use 1995-2000 values to explain per capita growth over
2000-2005. Thus, like the prior studies we compare our results to, we
are limited to cross-sectional analysis rather than panel estimations
due to data availability.
Some concern remains about the possible simultaneity of corruption
and growth. We make a modest attempt to minimize the problem by using
independent variables from 1995-2000 to explain 2000-2005 growth.
However, the possibility remains that there is a longer-term omitted
variable that impacts both corruption in the late 1990s and growth in
the early 2000s. At this point, data limitations do not allow us to do
more to address the issue, so due caution is in order when interpreting
our results.
The corruption variable is the average of all the years from
1995-2000 in which a country was rated. The economic freedom variable is
the average value of 1995 and 2000 (annual data are not available until
after 2000). The investment and democracy variables are the average for
all years from 1995-2000. Initial GDP is measured in constant 2000
international dollars PPP. Our preliminary, complete data set includes
82 countries (see Appendix B). Finally, for the education variable we
use the average for the number of years of schooling for 1995 and 2000
from the Barro-Lee data set. (16) Including education reduces the sample
to 72 countries (see Appendix B).
Descriptive statistics for the full set of 82 countries appear in
Table 1. Among the economic freedom categories, freedom is highest on
average for Area 3 (sound money) and Area 4 (international trade) and
lowest for Area 5 (regulatory burden) and Area 1 (size of government).
The other four columns stratify the sample by mean levels of democracy
and economic freedom. Countries are evenly divided on their levels of
economic freedom, with the mean approximately equal to the median, but
the distribution is much more skewed in terms of the level of democracy,
with the median democratic nation well above the average level.
The average levels in both the higher democracy (III) and higher
economic freedom (V) samples are higher for initial wealth and
investment, but lower for growth and corruption, compared to the
respective lower level samples (II and IV). In the higher democracy
(III) compared to lower democracy (II) samples, economic freedom is
higher overall and in each separate category, except for Area 1
(government size) in which it is basically the same. The average level
of democracy is also higher for countries with above average level of
economic freedom (IV versus V). Every area of economic freedom is higher
on average when the overall level of economic freedom is above average.
In our regression analysis, we will keep the five areas of economic
freedom distinct, as studies have shown that their marginal impacts on
growth differ (Carlsson and Lundstrom, 2002; Heckelman and Knack, 2008).
Table 2 presents the correlation matrix among corruption, democracy, and
the areas of economic freedom. The areas of economic freedom are not
highly correlated with each other. The highest correlation is only 0.61,
between Area 2 (legal structure and property rights) and Area 4
(international trade). Area 1 (government size) is the least correlated
with other areas of economic freedom, with only very weak positive
correlations of 0.23 to Area 5 (regulation) and 0.12 to Area 3 (sound
money), and inverse correlations of 0.13 to Area 4 (international trade)
and 0.43 to Area 2 (legal structure and property rights). Others have
shown that even the various components within each area are often not
highly correlated with each other and may be more highly correlated with
freedom components grouped into other areas (Caudill et al., 2000;
Heckelman and Stroup, 2000). For the current version of EFW, 38 distinct
pieces of data comprise the index components and subcomponents,
therefore it is impractical to include each component variable
separately in the regression analysis. As a compromise, we separate out
the five areas of economic freedom in the regressions, keeping in mind
that misspecification is still possible if the underlying components of
each area have different marginal effects on growth. (17)
Democracy is correlated with the overall economic freedom index at
the moderate level of 0.49. The highest correlation is with Area 4
(international trade) at only 0.57, and there is basically no
correlation with Area 1 (government size), registering only at 0.02.
Consistent with the large differences in average corruption level
presented in Table l, Table 2 shows that corruption is highly inversely
correlated with the overall EFW index, and with four of the five
individual economic freedom areas. In particular, the correlation
between corruption and freedom Area 2 (legal structure and property
rights) is -0.93. Corruption is positively correlated only with Area 1
(government size), but the correlation is modest at 0.30. The inverse
correlation between corruption and democracy (-0.53) is also much weaker
than between corruption and overall economic freedom.
Regression analysis for corruption, democracy, economic freedom,
and growth
As described above, the independent variables include log initial
GDP, investment, democracy, corruption, and a set of regional dummies to
control for other inter-regional heterogeneity. A White test rejected
the null of no heteroskedasticity. (18) A general White robustness
correction did not affect the standard errors very much. A similar issue
confronted Clarke (1995) and Folster and Henrekson (1999) in their
growth regressions, so they adopted Weighted Least Squares (WLS) as
their preferred estimator. Because they used panel data, their weights
for each country observation were based on the standard deviation of the
country residuals. In a pure cross-section format such as ours, we are
unable to follow suit.
Instead, we note that Folster and Henrekson (1999) suggested growth
will tend to vary less among larger countries because growth is measured
as the average of growth in subregions, and subregions in larger
countries tend to be more economically integrated, which, due to
regional policy, factor mobilization, and other reasons, will tend to
smooth growth, compared to smaller countries. On the basis of this
rationale, we use country population as our proportional weighting
variable. (19) This estimation technique was also used by Heckelman and
Knack (2008) for their growth regressions.
Table 3 presents the WLS regressions. (20) In column I, each
estimated variable has the expected sign and is statistically
significant at the 5% level. The negative coefficient on initial GDP
supports evidence for conditional convergence, and higher levels of
investment, democracy, and corruption are all shown to promote growth.
Column II includes measures of economic freedom. These estimates
show that not all areas of economic freedom have the same impact. In
particular, only freedom in Areas 2 and 5 are significantly beneficial
to growth, while an increase in freedom in Area 1 is marginally harmful
to growth. On the basis of the relative magnitudes of the area
coefficients, the net impact from an equal across-the-board increase in
every area of economic freedom is positive for growth overall.
A comparison of estimates from regressions I and II also shows the
importance of controlling for economic freedom. The signs and
significance for initial GDP, investment, and corruption remain the
same, but in regression II the impact of initial GDP and corruption are
now enhanced, while the effect for investment is reduced (but still
statistically significant). Because of the high degree of inverse
correlation between corruption and economic freedom, failure to control
for economic freedom can lead to a bias in the estimated impact of
corruption. In additional regressions not presented in the table, we
also find that if only one area of economic freedom is included at a
time, the estimated coefficient for corruption remains positive and
significant for Areas 1, 2, and 5 at 5%, and Area 4 at 10%. The
estimated coefficient for corruption is also positive but not quite
significant at 10% when controlling only for Area 3 freedom. Thus, no
matter which area of economic freedom was included, corruption was never
found to reduce growth, and typically benefits growth. The increased
impact of corruption shown in column II appears to be driven primarily
by controlling for Area 2 (legal structure and property rights), as the
coefficient on corruption jumps to 6.3 (t-statistic = 5.3).
The other major change between estimates from columns I and II is
the effect of democracy is now negative, and weakly significant at the
10% level. Thus, controlling for economic freedom reverses the impact of
democracy on growth. Even when controlling for just one area of economic
freedom at a time (additional regressions not reported in the table) the
impact of democracy is always reduced, and falls below the 5% level of
significance for Area 3, and below 10% for Area 4. Again, Area 2 appears
to be the critical area needed to be controlled to generate the negative
and significant coefficient on democracy (t-statistic = -2.1). Using the
Freedom House index of democratic freedoms and the overall EFW Index,
Gwartney et al. (1999) find that economic freedom significantly benefits
growth when controlling for democracy, but the reverse does not hold.
Depending on the particular area of economic freedom controlled, and the
level of statistical significance accepted, our results can be
interpreted as broadly supportive of their findings.
Differing effects of corruption on growth
In separate samples, Mendez and Sepulveda (2006) found the effect
of low levels of corruption to be small but beneficial in countries
rated democratically 'free' by Freedom House, and that it had
no impact in 'not free' countries, suggesting a relationship
on the interplay of democracy and corruption, which they hypothesize
might follow Klitgaard's (1998) theory. We can assess the findings
of Mendez and Sepulveda in our framework by interacting our Polity
democracy variable with corruption. The coefficient on corruption by
itself captures the effect of corruption in a purely autocratic nation
(democracy = 0), and the coefficient on the interaction term captures
changing effects of corruption as democracy begins to improve.
Our estimates, presented in column III, are roughly in accord with
Mendez and Sepulveda (2006), but stronger overall. We find that at the
lowest levels of democracy, corruption is harmful to growth but becomes
less harmful and eventually beneficial as the level of democracy
increases. The point at which the net impact of corruption becomes
positive occurs at a democracy level of only 6.5, which is below the
mean level of democracy in our sample (see Table 1). Note that
investment is no longer statistically significant using this
specification.
The effect of corruption found so far appears to be somewhat
counterintuitive. Our analysis in the opening sections suggests that the
positive impact from corruption would be greatest when economic freedom
is limited. To test this hypothesis, we interact our measures of
corruption and economic freedom in column IV.
As expected, the estimated coefficient for corruption is positive
and statistically significant, indicating that corruption benefits
growth when other institutions and policies repress economic freedom to
the maximum level possible (EFW = 0). In contrast, when economic freedom
improves, the interaction term suggests corruption becomes less
beneficial. Eventually, corruption does become harmful, but only at a
high EFW Index value of 9.6, which, while theoretically possible, is not
matched by any country in our sample. (21) At the mean level of EFW, if
an average level of corruption country such as Greece (inverted
corruption average = 5.15) were to reduce its corruption down to United
States levels (2.36), then, ceteris paribus, its growth rate would be
expected to fall by roughly two standard deviations over the 5-year
period. If, on the other hand, a country with a top EFW score of 10 were
to do the same, its growth would be expected to increase an additional
2.6 percentage points above its norm.
We also find that replacing democracy by economic freedom in the
interaction term returns the significant impact of investment, perhaps
further indicating the democracy interaction was a misspecification.
Finally, note also that the estimated coefficients and t-statistics on
the separate economic freedom areas all become more positive than in
either columns II of III, with Areas 3 and 4 now also considered
statistically significant. Only Area 1 has a negative coefficient, but
contributes a negligible effect. These findings are consistent with the
view that when a country has poor economic institutions, corruption can
allow individuals to avoid inefficient rules that would otherwise slow
growth even more. (22) Our analysis is in direct contrast to Mendez and
Sepulveda (2006), who found low levels of corruption had no impact in
'not free' countries but a small amount of corruption was
beneficial in 'free' countries, when they investigated only
political rather than economic freedom.
Thus far we have treated the index values as cardinal, rather than
ordinal. If the index values are viewed as strictly ordinal in nature
then the interaction terms created and marginal impacts we estimate do
not have much meaning. An alternate method to interactions is to split
the sample based on the EFW values and determine if corruption has a
different estimated coefficient across the samples. We do not have
enough observations to run quantile regressions, so instead we split the
sample into halves. A simple dummy for the democracy index is used to
indicate if the polity value is greater than its median. To allow for
greater differentiation on our primary variable of interest, a series of
dummy variables are used to indicate if the corruption index is in any
particular quartile. Results for this regression are presented in Table
4. (23)
Among the low EFW sample countries, greater values of corruption
result in higher growth rates, with the fourth quartile of corruption
yielding a statistically significant coefficient. The least corrupt
countries have the lowest expected growth, with each successive quartile
increasing growth monotonically. Moving from the lowest to highest
quartile of corruption would increase growth by roughly a third of the
standard deviation in growth. (24)
For the high EFW sample countries, every corruption quartile
generates a negative coefficient suggesting corruption is always harmful
on average. However, none of the coefficients are statistically
significant.
Thus, these results generally support the findings from column IV
of Table 3, which treated the indexes as continuous variables. More
corruption aids growth only when economic freedom is low.
Robustness
We also tested the sensitivity of the corruption effect on growth
found previously to different specifications. To conserve space, Table 5
reports only the coefficient and t-statistics on the corruption and
interaction term for each modification, but the control variables
otherwise remain the same as the final specification in column IV of
Table 3.
Our main comparison has been to differentiate between freedom for a
nation based on its level of democracy versus its type of economic
institutions and policies. We therefore drop democracy from the
specification to allow the corruption-economic freedom interplay to be
independent of the degree of democratization. Dropping democracy also
allows for the inclusion of two additional country observations for
Iceland and Luxembourg, which were missing Polity data. As shown in row
1 of Table 5, the results remain substantially the same to this
alteration.
We also note that Mo (2001) found the effect of corruption to
differ depending on whether investment or education levels were
controlled. As shown in row 2, dropping investment has no appreciable
effect on either the corruption or interaction term.
Next we added a control for education in row 3. Using the Barro-Lee
data dropped 10 observations (Appendix B denotes the lost country
observations by an asterisk), but results remained substantively the
same. We present results using the average number of years of schooling
as the human capital proxy, but alternative variables from Barro and Lee
(2000) were also utilized with similar results.
The degree of corruption may differ systematically in different
parts of the world (Clague, 2003; Aidt et al., 2003), in which case the
regional dummies may be obfuscating the direct effects from corruption.
As a check, in row 4 the regional dummies are removed. Dropping the set
of regional dummies suggests the impact of corruption will turn negative
at a slightly lower level of overall economic freedom, but still above
the highest rated nation in our sample.
These results show that the effects of corruption interacted with
economic freedom estimated in column IV of Table 3 are robust to the
previously described specification changes. The effects of corruption,
interacted with democratization reported in column III of Table 3, are
not. In unreported regressions, we repeated each of the specification
changes described in rows 2-4 of Table 5 when the interaction term
involved democratization, as in column III of Table 3. Doing so always
yielded the same estimated signs for corruption (negative) and the
interaction term (positive) as presented in column III of Table 3, but
significance levels varied dramatically. Dropping investment does not
alter significance of either term, but neither is significant when
adding the education variable, and the corruption term by itself is not
significant when dropping the regional dummies, although the interaction
term remains significant. Thus, not only does the interaction of
corruption with economic freedom alter previous findings of the effect
of corruption which utilized democracy as the proxy for institutional
quality, but the results are more robust as well.
The remaining rows in Table 5 consider if the effect of corruption
is dependent on the particular type of economic freedom. We expect
corruption to be more beneficial when the economic institutions
necessary for growth are lacking. Judging from the results in Table 3,
this appears to be most evident when freedom in Areas 2 and 5 are low.
Thus we expect the effect of corruption to be positive when these areas
in particular are low but eventually to become negative when freedom
reaches a high enough level.
Conversely, the positive impact on growth from Areas 3 and 4 was
less robust. Thus, our expectations on how corruption effects growth
dependent on these types of freedom are much more tentative. Similarly,
because larger values for Area 1 reduce growth at the margin (although
generally not to a significant degree), we might speculate that the
effect of corruption relative to the level of freedom in Area 1 would be
the reverse of Areas 3 and 4. However, given that the negative impact of
freedom in Area 1 is basically absent in the preferred specification
(IV), this reverse effect is likely to be absent as well.
The estimated effects of corruption dependent upon the specific
category of economic freedom are presented in the last five rows of
Table 5. We find that freedom in Areas 2-4 does not affect corruption,
and that corruption is only found to have a significant impact at all
when the interaction is with Area 4. Although greater freedom in Area 4
would reduce the benefits of corruption, the estimated t-statistic on
the interaction term suggests this reduction is not statistically
significant. For Areas 1 (size of government) and 5 (regulation),
however, corruption is again shown to be beneficial in the absence of
freedom in these areas, but the benefit falls rapidly as economic
freedom improves and eventually becomes harmful to growth. The estimated
turning point of corruption occurs when freedom in Area 1 is close to
its mean and median values. For Area 5, this occurs at a somewhat higher
level; although the estimated value of 6.7 would appear to be feasible
for a great number of countries, even the top-rated countries in this
area just barely manage to miss this threshold. (25)
Our results suggest that when freedom from big government and
regulations are low, corruption appears to be a beneficial way to
circumvent growth-retarding government presence and regulations that
would otherwise hinder productivity. When government size is small or
freedom from regulation is already high, corruption becomes harmful to
growth. The interpretation of our result for Area 5 (freedom from
regulation) is straightforward. When there are pervasive regulations
that limit potential gains from trade, corruption allows entrepreneurs
to bypass official regulations and further capitalize on growth
opportunities. As economies become freer from regulation, corruption
serves this beneficial purpose less often. The interpretation of our
result for Area 1 (government size) requires greater elaboration. Area 1
measures government consumption spending as a percent of total
consumption spending, transfers, and subsidies as a percent of GDP,
government enterprises and investment as a percent of total investment,
and marginal tax rates. One might theorize that corruption in this area
of government would divert government spending away from the optimal
provision of public goods and toward private interests while reducing
growth in the process. Our results do not support such a view.
Alternatively, if the political process predominantly serves private
interests anyway, perhaps the introduction of explicit corruption
actually enhances the process of allocating government funds by
directing funds to those most willing to pay for the transfer rather
than the most politically connected or largest voting bloc. If the
highest bidder is best able to make efficient use of the resource, then
corruption in Area 1 might actually move resources to their highest
valued use and thus promote growth. Our results are consistent with this
perspective but this conjecture remains more speculative than our
conclusion regarding freedom from regulation. (26)
CONCLUSIONS
In theory, corruption can be either harmful or beneficial to
growth, depending on the quality of the institutional environment.
Several cross-country studies have found that corruption slows growth,
but these findings are not universally robust. Recent attempts to
control for the quality of institutions when examining the impact of
corruption on growth have pointed to a potential nonlinear relationship
among them that depends on the quality of the institutions. However,
most of the institutional measures previously employed control for the
quality of political rather than economic institutions. By directly
examining how controlling for economic freedom impacts corruption's
effect on growth, we have more directly tested some areas in which
corruption may allow entrepreneurs to circumvent bad economic policies
that would otherwise reduce growth.
Our initial findings are that corruption can have a positive effect
on growth, most likely by allowing people to circumvent inefficient
public policies. We further find that the benefits of corruption fall as
the economic institutional environment improves. By breaking down the
economic freedom index into each of its five areas, we find that
corruption is only significantly growth enhancing when countries have
low levels of freedom in the areas of government size, freedom to trade
internationally, and regulation of credit, labor, and business. When
economic freedom in the areas of government size and regulations
improve, the benefits of corruption for growth significantly decline,
and eventually turn negative.
These findings suggest that policy efforts to lower corruption
across the board may not always improve economic growth rates. Instead,
the particular form of corruption and the institutional quality of the
country need to be addressed. In some cases, eliminating corruption may
improve growth. But in other instances, such as in which inefficient
rules limit entrepreneurial opportunities, ending corruption by solving
principle agent problems might not improve growth. In these cases
corruption with inefficient institutions is a second best result.
Efforts at reform should instead focus on improving economic freedom to
reduce the need for corruption rather than ending the discretion of
decision-makers. Only after strong economic institutions are in place
would reducing corruption be likely to improve growth prospects. On the
basis of our regression analysis, reducing the size of government and
decreasing the regulation of credit, labor, and business would do the
most to alleviate the need for corruption to enhance growth.
Furthermore, improvements in the legal structure and property rights,
sound money policies, and freer trade, would also have direct benefits
to growth independent of corruption.
Much research remains to be done. Current measures of corruption
limit our ability to measure the specific forms of corruption occurring
in different countries. More detailed measures of corruption could prove
quite illuminating. Given that changes in institutions and policies
often affect growth through an investment channel, further studies of
the effect of the direct effect of corruption on investment when
controlling for, and interacting with, economic freedom could also prove
useful. Most importantly, additional research is necessary to deal with
simultaneity issues. We attempt to minimize simultaneity issues by using
1995-2000 corruption to explain 2000-2005 growth, but long-term
underlying factors, such as culture and other informal institutions,
could influence both corruption and growth. Future research might make
use of instrumental variables to address this issue. Finally, additional
research could also examine in what instances the opportunity for
corruption leads public officials to create inefficient institutions in
the first place.
APPENDIX A
Components of economic freedom of the world
Area 1: Size of government: Expenditures, taxes, and enterprises
(a) General government consumption spending as a percentage of
total consumption
(b) Transfers and subsidies as a percentage of GDP
(c) Government enterprises and investment as a percentage of total
investment
(d) Top marginal tax rate and threshold at which it applies
(i) top marginal income tax rate (and threshold)
(ii) top marginal income and payroll tax rate (and threshold)
Area 2: Legal structure and property rights
(a) Judicial independence
(b) Impartial courts
(c) Protection of intellectual property
(d) Military interference in rule of law and the political process
(e) Integrity of the legal system
Area 3: Access to sound money
(a) Average annual growth of the money supply in the last 5 years
minus average annual growth of real GDP in the last 10 years
(b) Standard inflation variability during the last 5 years
(c) Recent inflation rate
(d) Freedom to own foreign currency bank accounts domestically and
abroad
Area 4: Freedom to trade internationally
(a) Taxes on international trade
(i) Revenue from taxes on international trade as a percentage of
exports plus imports
(ii) Mean tariff rate
(iii) Standard deviation in tariff rate
(b) Regulatory barriers to trade
(i) Non-tariff barriers
(ii) Compliance cost of importing and exporting
(c) Actual size of trade sector compared to expected size
(d) Difference between official exchange rate and black-market rate
(e) International capital market controls
(i) Foreign ownership/investment restrictions
(ii) Restrictions on the freedom of citizens to engage in capital
market exchange with foreigners
Area 5: Regulation of credit, labor, and business
(a) Credit market restrictions
(i) Ownership of banks--percentage of deposits held in privately
owned banks
(ii) Competition--domestic banks face competition from foreign
banks
(iii) Extension of credit--percentage of credit extended to private
sector
(iv) Avoidance of interest rate controls and regulations that lead
to negative real interest rates
(v) Interest rate controls
(b) Labor market regulations
(i) Impact of minimum wage
(ii) Hiring and firing practices (determined by private contract)
(iii) Share of labor force whose wages are set by centralized
collective bargaining
(iv) Unemployment benefits
(v) Use of conscripts to obtain military personnel
(c) Business regulations
(i) Price controls
(ii) Burden of regulation
(iii) Time with government bureaucracy
(iv) Ease of starting a new business
(v) Irregular payments (omitted from this study because it is a
measure of corruption)
APPENDIX B
See Table B1.
Table B1: Sample of countries
Albania (a) Latvia (a)
Argentina Lithuania (a)
Australia Malawi
Austria Malaysia
Bangladesh Mauritius
Belgium Mexico
Bolivia Morocco (a)
Botswana Namibia (a)
Brazil The Netherlands
Bulgaria New Zealand
Cameroon Nicaragua
Canada Nigeria (a)
Chile Norway
China Pakistan
Colombia Paraguay
Costa Rica Peru
Cote d'Ivoire (a) Philippines
Croatia (a) Poland
Czech Republic Portugal
Denmark Romania
Ecuador Russia (a)
Egypt Senegal
El Salvador Slovak Republic
Estonia (a) Slovenia
Finland South Africa
France South Korea
Germany Spain
Ghana Sweden
Greece Switzerland
Guatemala Tanzania
Honduras Thailand
Hungary Tunisia
India Turkey
Indonesia Uganda
Ireland Ukraine (a)
Israel United Kingdom
Italy United States
Jamaica Uruguay
Japan Venezuela
Jordan Zambia
Kenya Zimbabwe
(a) Missing education data from Barro-Lee.
Acknowledgements
We thank participants at the 2007 Southern Economics Association,
and the 2007 Association of Private Enterprise conferences, the editor,
and two anonymous referees, for valuable comments, Robert Lawson for
providing a recalculated index of economic freedom with its corruption
component removed, Lisa Verdon for providing data, and Kyle Jackson for
excellent research assistance. The usual caveat applies.
REFERENCES
Aidt, T. (2003): Economic analysis of corruption: A survey.
Economic Journal 113: 632-652.
Aidt, T, Dutta, J and Sen& V. (2008): Governance regimes,
corruption and growth: Theory and evidence. Journal of Comparative
Economics 36: 195-220.
Aron, J. (2000): Growth and institutions: A review of the evidence.
The World Bank Research Observer 15: 99-135.
Ayal, EB and Karras, G. (1999): Components of economic freedom and
growth: An empirical study. Journal of Developing Areas 32: 327-338.
Bardhan, P. (1997): Corruption and development: A review of issues.
Journal of Economic Literature 35: 1320-1346.
Barro, R. (1997): Determinants of economic growth. MIT Press:
Cambridge, MA.
Barro, R and Lee, J-W. (2000): International data on educational
attainment: Updates and implications,
http://www.cid.harvard.edu/ciddata/ciddata.html, accessed March 2007.
Brunetti, A, Kisunko, G and Weder, B. (1997): Credibility of rules
and economic growth--Evidence from a world wide private sector survey.
Background paper for the World Development Report 1997, The World Bank:
Washington, D.C.
Carlsson, F and Lundstrom, S. (2002): Economic freedom and growth:
Decomposing the effects. Public Choice 112: 335-344.
Caudill, SB, Zanella, FC and Mixon Jr, FG. (2000): Is economic
freedom one dimensional? A factor analysis of some common measures of
economic freedom. Journal of Economic Development 25: 17-40.
Clague, C. (2003): The international campaign against corruption:
An institutionalist approach. In: Heckelman, JC and Coates, D (eds).
Collective Choice: Essays in Honor of Mancur Olson. Springer-Verlag:
Berlin.
Clarke, GRG. (1995): More evidence on income distribution and
growth. Journal of Development Economics 47: 403-427.
Colombatto, E. (2003): Why is corruption tolerated? Review of
Austrian Economics 164: 363-379.
Folster, S and Henrekson, M. (1999): Growth and the public sector:
A critique of the critics. European Journal of Political Economy
15:337-358.
Goel, R and Nelson, M. (2005): Economic freedom versus political
freedom: Cross-country influences on corruption. Australian Economic
Papers 44: 121-133.
Graeff, P and Mehlkop, G. (2003): The impact of economic freedom on
corruption: Different patterns for rich and poor countries. European
Journal of Political Economy 19: 605-620.
Gwartney, J and Lawson, R. (2006): Economic freedom of the world:
2006 annual report. The Fraser Institute: Vancouver, Canada.
Gwartney, J, Lawson, R and Holcombe, R. (1999): Economic freedom
and the environment for economic growth. Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics 155: 643-663.
Gyimah-Brempong, K. (2002): Corruption, economic growth, and income
inequality in Africa. Economics of Governance 3: 183-209.
Heckelman, JC and Knack, S. (2008): Foreign aid and market
liberalizing reform. Economica 75: 524-548.
Heckelman, JC and Stroup, MD. (2000): Which economic freedoms
contribute to growth? Kyklos 53: 527-544.
Huntington, S. (1968): Political order in changing societies. Yale
University Press: New Haven, CT.
Jain, AK. (2001): Corruption: A review. Journal of Economic Surveys
15: 71-121.
Kaufmann, DA, Kraay, A and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1999): Governance
matters. Policy Research Working Paper 2195. The World Bank: Washington
D.C.
Klitgaard, R. (1988): Controlling corruption. University of
California Press: Berkeley, CA.
Knack, S and Keefer, P. (1995): Institutions and economic
performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional
measures. Economics and Politics 7: 207-227.
Krueger, A. (1974): The political economy of the rent seeking
society. American Economic Review 64: 291-303.
Left, N. (1964): Economic development through bureaucratic
corruption. American Behavioral Scientist 82: 337-341.
Leite, C and Weidmann, J. (1999): Does mother nature corrupt?
Natural resources, corruption, and economic growth. International
Monetary Fund Working Paper, 99/85.
Lui, FT. (1985): An equilibrium queuing model of bribery. Journal
of Political Economy 93: 760-781.
Mauro, P. (1995): Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 110: 681-712.
Meon, P-G and Sekkat, K. (2005): Does corruption grease or sand the
wheels of growth? Public Choice 122: 69-97.
Mendez, F and Sepulveda, F. (2006): Corruption, growth and
political regimes: Cross country evidence. European Journal of Political
Economy 22: 82-98.
Mo, PH. (2001): Corruption and economic growth. Journal of
Comparative Economics 29: 66-79.
Munck, G and Verkuilen, J. (2002): Conceptualizing and measuring
democracy: Evaluating alternative indices. Comparative Political Studies
35: 3-34.
Myrdal, G. (1968): Asian drama: An inquiry into the poverty of
nations Vol. 2. The Twentieth Century Fund: New York.
Paldam, M. (2002): The big pattern of corruption, economics,
culture and the seesaw dynamics. European Journal of Political Economy
18: 215-240.
Poirson, H. (1998): Economic security, private investment, and
growth in developing countries. International Monetary Fund Working
Paper, 98/4.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999): Corruption and government, causes,
consequences and reform. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK.
Shleifer, A and Vishny, RW. (1993): Corruption. Quarterly Journal
of Economics 108: 599-617.
Svensson, J. (2005): Eight questions about corruption. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 19: 19-42.
Transparency International. (1995-2000): Corruption Perceptions
Index, www.transparency.org/ policy_research/surveys_indices/cpi,
accessed February 2007.
Wedeman, A. (1997): Looters, rent-scrapers, and
dividend-collectors: Corruption and growth in Zaire, South Korea, and
the Philippines. Journal of Developing Areas 31: 457-478.
World Bank. (2007): World development indicators online
www.worldbank.org, accessed February 2007.
(1) Full website address:
http://webworldbankorg/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTPUBLIC-
SECTORANDGOVERNANCE/EXTANTICORRUPTION/0,contentMDK:21205078~menuPK:384461~ pagePK:64020865~piPK:149114~theSitePK:384455,00.html, accessed May
2007.
(2) Full website address given in note 1 above.
(3) Full website address:
www.usaid.gov/our_work/democracy_and_governance/technical_areas/ anti
corruption/, accessed May 2007.
(4) In the quote above, USAID acknowledged that corruption may be
able to reduce costs associated with bureaucratic red tape.
(5) For earlier surveys of the literature on corruption see Bardhan
(1997), Rose-Ackerman (1999), Jain (2001), and Aidt (2003).
(6) We recognize that inefficient institutional environments that
do not allow much economic freedom may in some cases be intentionally
created to allow officials to extract bribes. Furthermore, the
underlying cultural capital could jointly cause both corruption and low
levels of economic freedom.
(7) Paldam (2002), Graeff and Mehlkop (2003), and Goel and Nelson
(2005) have used the indexes of economic freedom to examine how economic
freedom impacts corruption. They have generally found that the more
economic freedom a country has the lower the level of corruption
present; however, their studies did not examine how this relationship
affects growth. As we show below, the inverse relationship between
corruption and economic freedom is important for predicting the impact
corruption will have on growth.
(8) For a general comparison between alternative measures of
democracy, see Munck and Verkuilen (2002).
(9) Scores for each of the separate components of the political
rights and civil liberties indexes are not publicly available, therefore
the Freedom House democracy index cannot be purged of these particular
elements.
(10) The Freedom House scores are based on rank, therefore lower
values represent more freedom. The indexes were inverted in order to
match the Polity method of higher values representing greater democracy,
and thus result in positive correlations.
(11) Because each area contains a different number of components,
this aggregation method (which weights each area equally) does not
weight all the individual components equally.
(12) We thank Robert Lawson for rescaling the Area 5 scores and the
overall EFW index without component C.v. when he sent us the EFW data.
(13) Area 4 (freedom to exchange with foreigners) component C of
the EFW index includes a measure of the actual size of the international
trade sector compared to the expected size. This measure may suffer from
similar problems, but it does take account of structural and geographic
characteristics of the country when calculating the expected size.
Furthermore, it only accounts for 4% of the overall EFW score (20% of a
country's Area 4 score).
(14) The regions include: Latin America, Asia, Europe, Africa, and
Middle East. North America (comprised of Canada and United States;
Mexico is included as part of Latin America) is the default region not
included.
(15) The same is true for some of the components of economic
freedom, described above.
(16) Alternative education measures from Barro and Lee (2000), such
as primary and secondary completion rates, were also utilized but did
not appreciably affect our results.
(17) See Ayal and Karras (1999) and Heckelman and Stroup (2000),
who show differing marginal impacts of the economic freedom components
on growth using earlier versions of the EFW that contained fewer total
components.
(18) The test statistic of 2.36 is distributed as F(13, 68) with p
value of 0.0l. An alternative test statistic of N x R2- 25.52 is
distributed as [chi square] (13) with p-value of 0.02.
(19) Our results do not substantially differ if we applied a
two-step WLS, using the residuals from OLS as the weighting proportion.
(20) WLS contains no constant term, as the intercept is now the
inverse of population (relative to the mean). As such, we do not report
R2 measures because they do not retain their normal interpretation
without a constant term. We also do not report specific estimates for
the various regional dummies (Latin America, Asia, Europe, Africa,
Middle East).
(21) The five highest-rated countries for EFW over the period
1995-2000 are United States (8.28), New Zealand (8.27), United Kingdom
(8.06), Ireland (8.05), and Switzerland (8.00).
(22) As noted earlier, the CPI is not consistently measured over
time due to the changing inclusion of varying surveys. As a check on our
results, we ran another regression matching specification IV, but using
only the 2000 values for all independent variables. This reduced our
sample to 71 nations but our conclusions are similar. The coefficient on
corruption is positive and significant, and the coefficient for the
interaction with the EFW index is negative and significant. The
estimated turning point for when additional corruption becomes harmful
occurs at a slightly lower, but still quite high. rating for EFW at
8.26. roughly in accordance with US levels. The democracy index remains
statistically insignificant.
(23) Neither country from the default region (Canada and US) is in
the low EFW sample. To avoid perfect multicollinearity, one of the
regional dummies used in previous regressions (see note 14) was dropped
for that regression.
(24) The weighted standard deviation of growth in the low EFW
sample is 96.9 with a mean of 25.5.
(25) The highest-rated countries for Area 5 are New Zealand (6.63),
United States (6.60), Namibia (6.59), and United Kingdom (6.57).
(26) Another reason we are less certain about Area 1 than Area 5 is
that the finding of significance of Area 5 was more robust across
specifications in Table 3.
JAC C HECKELMAN [1] & BENJAMIN POWELL [2]
[1] Department of Economics, Wake Forest University, Carswell Hall,
Winston-Salem, NC 27109, USA. E-mail: heckeljc@wfu.edu
[2] Department of Economics, Suffolk University, 8 Ashburton PL,
Boston, MA 02108, USA. E-mail: benjaminwpowell@gmail.com
Table 1: Descriptive statistics: Means with standard deviation in
parentheses
Sample Full sample Democracy Democracy
< mean > mean
(I) (II) (III)
Growth 11.87 (11.73) 12.21 (16.19) 11.72 (9.47)
Log initial GOP 8.92 (1.09) 8.07 (0.99) 9.27 (0.93)
Investment/GDP 22.03 (4.72) 21.05 (5.39) 22.44 (4.41)
Corruption index 5.32 (2.27) 6.92 (1.03) 4.66 (2.32)
Democracy 7.94 (2.55) 4.40 (1.83) 9.40 (0.68)
EFW index 6.28 (1.00) 5.59 (0.72) 6.56 (0.97)
Area 1 index 5.55 (1.61) 5.59 (1.33) 5.54 (1.72)
Area 2 index 6.20 (1.75) 5.02 (0.91) 6.69 (1.79)
Area 3 index 7.17 (2.19) 6.10 (1.80) 7.61 (2.19)
Area 4 index 7.05 (1.00) 6.29 (0.84) 7.36 (0.90)
Area 5 index 5.48 (0.57) 5.11 (0.52) 5.64 (0.52)
N 82 24 58
Sample EFW index EFW index
< mean > mean
(IV) (V)
Growth 13.89 (14.81) 9.74 (6.78)
Log initial GOP 8.58 (1.04) 9.27 (1.04)
Investment/GDP 21.58 (5.10) 22.51 (4.31)
Corruption index 6.70 (1.19) 3.88 (2.25)
Democracy 6.65 (2.79) 9.29 (1.31)
EFW index 5.47 (0.59) 7.11 (0.55)
Area 1 index 5.32 (1.50) 5.80 (1.71)
Area 2 index 5.20 (1.04) 7.25 (1.75)
Area 3 index 5.59 (1.81) 8.84 (0.97)
Area 4 index 6.48 (0.95) 7.64 (0.65)
Area 5 index 5.12 (0.45) 5.87 (0.41)
N 42 40
Table 2: Correlations between corruption, democracy, and economic
freedom
Corruption Democracy EFW Area 1 Area 2 Area 3
Democracy -0.529
EFW index -0.760 0.493
Area 1 0.306 -0.024 0.206
Area 2 -0.927 0.500 0.706 -0.430
Area 3 -0.604 0.345 0.898 0.117 0.581
Area 4 -0.670 0.574 0.699 -0.128 0.611 0.537
Area 5 -0.632 0.439 0.781 0.228 0.537 0.590
Area 4
Democracy
EFW index
Area 1
Area 2
Area 3
Area 4
Area 5 0.527
Table 3: Growth regressions
Specification I
Intercept -16.47 (-0.76)
Log initial GDP per capita -3.59 ** (-2.88)
Investment 2.18 ** (8.62)
Democracy 1.12 ** (2.69)
Corruption 3.50 ** (2.93)
Corruption x Democracy
Corruption x EFW index
Economic freedom
Area 1: Size of government
Area 2: Legal structure
Area 3: Sound money
Area 4: Freedom to trade
Area 5: Regulation
Corruption effect turns positive
Corruption effect turns negative
Regression F-statistic 142.47 **
Specification II
Intercept -43.22 (-1.40)
Log initial GDP per capita -5.79 ** (-4.71)
Investment 0.97 ** (2.57)
Democracy -1.21 * (-1.90)
Corruption 6.09 ** (3.73)
Corruption x Democracy
Corruption x EFW index
Economic freedom
Area 1: Size of government -2.31 * (-1.88)
Area 2: Legal structure 5.01 ** (2.30)
Area 3: Sound money 0.05 (0.05)
Area 4: Freedom to trade -0.17 (-0.11)
Area 5: Regulation 9.63 ** (2.26)
Corruption effect turns positive
Corruption effect turns negative
Regression F-statistic 124.86 **
Specification III
Intercept 94.03 * (1.85)
Log initial GDP per capita -5.06 **(-4.32)
Investment 0.50 (1.30)
Democracy -13.98 ** (-3.55)
Corruption -11.13 ** (-2.03)
Corruption x Democracy 1.72 ** (3.28)
Corruption x EFW index
Economic freedom
Area 1: Size of government -1.38 (-1.17)
Area 2: Legal structure 4.93 ** (2.42)
Area 3: Sound money -0.69 (-0.66)
Area 4: Freedom to trade 0.89 (0.61)
Area 5: Regulation 7.36 * (1.82)
Corruption effect turns positive Democracy > 6.48
Corruption effect turns negative
Regression F-statistic 134.18 **
Specification IV
Intercept -190.01 ** (-3.90)
Log initial GDP per capita -5.87 ** (-5.21)
Investment 0.75 ** (2.13)
Democracy 0.07 (0.11)
Corruption 24.57 ** (4.72)
Corruption x Democracy
Corruption x EFW index -2.55 ** (-3.70)
Economic freedom
Area 1: Size of government -0.08 (-0.06)
Area 2: Legal structure 7.94 ** (3.69)
Area 3: Sound money 4.15 ** (2.79)
Area 4: Freedom to trade 6.92 ** (2.92)
Area 5: Regulation 10.62 ** (2.72)
Corruption effect turns positive
Corruption effect turns negative EFW > 9.64
Regression F-statistic 139.59 **
* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%.
Notes: Regressions estimated by Weighted Least Squares 310.00
population. t-statistics in parentheses. Regressions also include
regional dummies not reported. N=82.
Table 4: Growth regressions split sample by EFW
EFW [greater than
Sample EFW < median or equal to] median
Log initial GDP per capita -2.89 * (-2.85) 2.11 (1.06)
Investment 1.60 ** (14.92) 0.68 * (1.89)
Democracy > median 2.92 * (1.84) -4.98 * (-1.53)
Corruption 1st quartile -15.82 (-0.31) -21.34 (-0.95)
Corruption 2nd quartile -7.19 (-0.57) -23.07 (-1.03)
Corruption 3rd quartile 3.67 (0.36) -8.44 (-0.42)
Corruption 4th quartile 19.00 * (1.81) -12.73 (-0.65)
N 41 41
Regression F-statistic 142.47 ** 124.86 **
* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%.
Notes: Regressions estimated by Weighted Least Squares using initial
population. t-statistics in parentheses. Regressions also include
regional dummies not reported.
Table 5: Sensitivity results for the effect of corruption on growth
Specification change N Corruption Corruption x EF
1. Drop democracy 84 24.31 ** (5.32) -2.51 ** (-4.34)
2. Drop investment 82 26.46 ** (5.02) -2.81 ** (-4.03)
3. Include education 72 25.12 ** (4.10) -2.57 ** (-3.04)
4. Drop regional dummies 82 27.26 **( 5.67) -3.05 ** (-5.09)
5. EF Area 1 interaction 82 13.52 ** (7.01) -2.26 ** (-5.45)
6. EF Area 2 interaction 82 3.39 (0.61) 0.30 (0.51)
7. EF Area 3 interaction 82 6.63 (1.54) -0.06 (-0.14)
8. EF Area 4 interaction 82 11.63 ** (1.97) -0.76 (-0.98)
9. EF Area 5 interaction 82 39.29 ** (5.86) -5.89 ** (-5.06)
Specification change Corruption effect
turns negative
1. Drop democracy EFW > 9.69
2. Drop investment EFW > 9.42
3. Include education EFW > 9.77
4. Drop regional dummies EFW > 8.94
5. EF Area 1 interaction EF areal > 5.97
6. EF Area 2 interaction --
7. EF Area 3 interaction --
8. EF Area 4 interaction
9. EF Area 5 interaction EF area 5 > 6.67
* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%.
Notes: Regressions estimated by Weighted Least Squares using initial
population. t-statistics in parentheses. Each regression, except where
otherwise noted, also includes: log initial GDP per capita,
investment, measure of democracy, economic freedom for Areas 1-5, and
a set of regional dummies. The interaction for Corruption x EF uses
the overall Economic Freedom of the World Index except in the last
five rows in which EF is limited to a specific area score.