The S-curve in emerging markets.
Bahmani-Oskooee, Mohsen ; Kutan, Ali ; Ratha, Artatrana 等
INTRODUCTION
The relationship between trade balance and terms of trade or trade
balance and real exchange rate continues to be of substantial interest
in trade literature and by policy makers. There are three distinct
methods of investigating the link between trade balance and real
exchange rate or terms of trade, which includes testing the
Marshall-Lerner condition, the J-curve, and the S-curve.
The Marshall-Lerner condition is an indirect method of assessing
the effectiveness of devaluation in improving trade balance. It asserts
that as long as the import and export demand elasticities add up to more
than unity, a decline in terms of trade or a real devaluation will have
a favourable impact on trade balance. While a seminal work by Houthakker
and Magee (1969) used standard econometric methods in estimating the
import and export demand elasticities, more recent studies by Rose
(1990), Bahmani-Oskooee and Niroomand (1998), and Bahmani-Oskooee and
Kara (2005) have relied upon cointegration analysis and estimated the
elasticities for different countries (developed as well as less
developed).
The above studies have shown that the Marshall-Lerner condition is
satisfied in most countries. However, there have been circumstances
under which trade balance has continued to deteriorate despite the fact
that the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied. See Magee (1973), Junz
and Rhomberg (1973), Meade (1988), Bahmani-Oskooee (1985), and Rose and
Yellen (1989) for examples. Given that the Marshall-Lerner condition is
a long-run condition, this occurrence shifted the emphasis to the
short-run dynamics that traced the post-devaluation time path of trade
balance to the widely known concept of the J-curve. The argument put
forward by researchers is that there are adjustment lags between the
time that a currency is devalued and the response of trade balance.
Thus, a short-run deterioration is consistent with a long-run
improvement in trade balance and seems like a necessary feature of
devaluation. For an extensive review of the literature, see
Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha (2004).
More recently, another body in the literature has emerged that
concentrates on analysing the cross-correlation function between trade
balance and terms of trade. Using the cross-correlation function, Backus
et al. (1994) were the first to show that trade balance is negatively
correlated with current and future movements in terms of trade but
positively correlated with past movements. They labelled this finding
for OECD countries as the S-curve because of the asymmetric shape of the
underlying cross-correlation function. Following the same logic and
analysis, Senhadji (1998) investigated the pattern for 30 less developed
countries and recovered the same empirical regularity in most cases. An
important question that we address in this paper is, given the evidence
for developed and less developed countries, whether a similar S-pattern
could be observed for emerging economies as well. Evidence supporting
such a pattern would suggest that similar dynamic, general equilibrium models could also be applied to these economies. Besides the general
interest on the topic among policy circles, studying the link between
terms of trade and balance of trade for emerging economies is quite
important for several other reasons as well.
First, these new emerging markets of Europe have had a huge surge
in their trade flows since the beginning of market reforms starting in
the early 1990s. At the beginning, real exchange rates initially
appreciated in all these economies. During the initial years of the
transition, the key economic goal was to achieve a stable inflation
environment, instead of competitiveness, because the elimination of
government restrictions in general, and trade liberalisation measures in
particular, increased aggregate demand, putting pressure on prices.
Bahmani-Oskooee and Kutan (2007) find that over time, competitiveness,
measured by terms of trade fluctuations, has played a much more
important role as inflation was controlled and price convergence with
the European Union (EU) is achieved. Some countries undertook a series
of official devaluations, while others have switched to more flexible
exchange rate policies. (1) Over the years, there has been a significant
increase in trade flows, particularly to the EU. An important question
then is whether there has been a significant link between movements in
the terms of trade and trade balance during this time period.
Second, these economies are relatively small open economies,
relying heavily on export revenues in their catching-up efforts with the
EU. On May 2004, among our sample countries, Cyprus, the Czech Republic,
Hungary, Poland, and the Slovak Republic joined the EU. Bulgaria,
Croatia, Romania, and Turkey are the candidate countries. Russia has
also been transforming her economy significantly and may apply for an EU
membership in the future. Thus, real economic convergence towards the EU
standards is the ultimate objective of their economic integration
decision with the EU. Fluctuations in export revenues due to adverse
terms of trade changes may delay the real convergence process, putting
stronger pressure on the real sector of the economy, hurting
competitiveness and ongoing restructuring efforts.
The rest of the paper is organised as follows: A review of the
S-curve literature is provided in the next section. The data,
definitions, and cross-correlation functions between terms of trade and
trade balance are presented in the subsequent section, followed by
concluding remarks and suggestions for future research in the final
section.
REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE
Backus et al. (1994) develop a two-country stochastic growth model
to study the properties of the short-term movements in trade balance and
terms of trade in some OECD countries. They propose a dynamic general
equilibrium model in which both trade balance and terms of trade are
endogenous. Their model produces an interesting pattern, called the
S-curve, describing the relationship between trade balance and terms of
trade in the short run. It is called the S-curve because it resembles
the letter S. According to the S-curve model, a negative correlation exists between trade balance and current and future movements in terms
of trade but a positive correlation with past movements. This S-curve
link between the two variables depends heavily on two key sources of
economic fluctuations, namely, productivity and government purchases
shocks. For example, a one-time positive productivity shock, which is
assumed to be persistent, results in an increase in output and
improvement in terms of trade. This productivity shock raises
consumption spending, but less than output.
However, investment spending rises temporarily by more than
consumption as capital is moved to its most productive location.
Consumption and investment together increase more than output; as a
result, a deficit in the trade balance occurs initially. Over time,
however, the temporary boom in investment spending slows down and the
trade deficit hence turns into a surplus. This response produces a
pattern, resembling an S-curve, tracing the short-run dynamics of trade
balance and terms of trade. Backus et al. (1994) test their model for 11
OECD countries and find that the trade balance is negatively correlated
with current and future movements in terms of trade but positively
correlated with past movements. However, they find relatively weak
evidence for the S-curve for Austria, and Canada and the United States.
Given the evidence for the OECD countries, a natural question to
ask is whether this S-curve may characterise the short-run movements
between trade balance and terms of trade for less developing economies.
Senhadji (1998) takes up this issue for 30 less developed countries. He
develops an international real business cycle theory model that departs
from a small country assumption by assuming a downward-sloping export
demand function. His model builds upon a stochastic growth model of an
open economy which faces productivity shocks as well as shocks to the
trade partner's income. The theoretical model is calibrated to
investigate the link between terms of trade and balance of trade for
less developed countries under different parameter values for
productivity and income shocks. The model is shown to replicate the
S-curve for less developed countries as well. As in Backus et al.
(1994), in Senhadji's (1998) model productivity shocks are shown to
be critical in producing the S-curve.
In a more recent paper, Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha (2007a) wonder
whether the rather weak S-curve evidence found for the United States and
other countries in Backus et al. (1994) is related to the aggregation of
data. They argue that aggregation could not allow us to observe all the
fluctuations observed in bilateral trade flow variables because of the
smoothing-out effects as a country's terms of trade or trade
balance could be weakening with one trading partner but becoming
stronger with another. To deal with this issue, they estimate S-curves
between the United States and her 24 trading partners. Initially, they
present S-curves based on aggregate trade data of the United States. The
results confirm the evidence reported in Backus et al. (1994), which
suggests weak, at best, evidence for S-curve. However, data based on
disaggregated or bilateral trade variables show much better support.
This disaggregation approach has received further support by
Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha (2007b) when they carry out the S-curve
analysis between Japan and her trading partners.
Not many studies investigate the link between terms of trade and
trade balance for the emerging economies of Europe. To our best
knowledge, there have been only three, but indirect, studies. Kemme and
Teng (2000) provide evidence on the impact of real exchange rate
misalignments on export performance. They find that the misalignments
tend to reduce export growth in Poland. Egert and Morales-Zumaquero
(2005) investigate the impact of nominal exchange rate volatility on
export flows in 10 Central and Eastern European transition economies.
They find that higher exchange rate volatility hurts export performance,
and the negative effects of exchange rate volatility vary across
countries. Bahmani-Oskooee and Kutan (2007) test the J-curve hypothesis
for 11 European emerging economies and find support for the J-curve
hypothesis in only three of the 11 countries, that is, Bulgaria,
Croatia, and Russia. While in many of the countries real depreciation
had a short-run effect, the short-run effects did not last into the long
run.
DATA, DEFINITIONS, AND CROSS-CORRELATION FUNCTIONS
Monthly data, spanning from 1990M1 to 2005M6 in most cases, are
used to compute the cross-correlation functions. The sample comprises
Bulgaria (1995M1: 2004M6), Croatia (1992M1: 2005M6), Cyprus (1990M1:
2005M6), Czech Republic (1993M1: 2005M6), Hungary (1990M1: 2005M6),
Poland (1990M1: 2005M6), Romania (1991M1: 2005M6), Russia (1993M11:
2005M6), Slovac (1993M1: 2005M6), and Turkey (1990M1: 2005M6). All data
are collected from the International Financial Statistics of the
International Monetary Fund (CD-ROM).
Following the practice in the literature, terms of trade is defined
as the price of imports relative to the price of exports. For emerging
markets no such data are available on a monthly basis. Therefore,
following Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha (2007a) the inverse of the real
effective exchange rate is used as a proxy. Backus et al. (1994) define
trade balance as net exports relative to Gross Domestic Product (GDP).
Again, in the absence of monthly data on GDP, real trade balance is
defined as net exports deflated by the consumer price index. The series
are all detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Figure 1 reports
the results. (2)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
A graphical inspection of the cross-correlation functions in Figure
1 indicates that support for the S-curve is strong in cases of Bulgaria,
Croatia, Poland, and Slovac, and weak in cases of the Czech Republic,
Hungary, and Turkey. There seems to be no support in cases of Cyprus,
Romania, and Russia. Certainly all these economies in our sample have
experienced significant productivity shocks due to restructuring,
including the Balassa-Samuelson type effects, so that the lack of
productivity shocks cannot be the explanation for not detecting the
S-curve. (3) A more plausible explanation is aggregation bias. Despite
this, however, evidence indicates that, in the majority of cases, we
have strong or marginal evidence for the S-curve, suggesting that these
models developed either by Backus et al. (1994) for developed countries
or by Senhadji (1998) for less developed countries may also be
applicable to many emerging economies. More importantly, terms of trade
fluctuations in seven countries seem to have a predictable pattern with
respect to movements in trade balance. Policymakers in emerging
countries may hence learn useful lessons from the experience of
developed and less developed countries where a similar dynamic link
between terms of trade and trade balance has been taking place.
CONCLUDING REMARKS
Backus et al. (1994) found that the cross-correlation function
between terms of trade and trade balance resembles a horizontal S-curve
and labelled this finding the S-curve. Senhadji (1998) confirms this
pattern for a set of developing countries. We contribute to this
literature by adding further support for this pattern from the emerging
market economies. In particular, we find strong evidence of an S-curve
in cases of Bulgaria, Croatia, Poland, and Slovac, weak evidence in
cases of the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Turkey, and no support in
cases of Cyprus, Romania, and Russia.
It is worth noting that empirical regularities based on aggregate
trade data may be biased since aggregation can potentially suppress some
of the patterns observed in trade at bilateral levels. Indeed, by
employing bilateral trade data, Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha (2007a, 2007b)
came up with excellent support for the S-curve for the United States and
Japan. A similar exercise in cases of emerging market economies is
likely to bring in further support for the posited pattern. Of course,
this claim cannot be substantiated until the trade data between each
emerging economy and her trading partners become available. In addition,
future research should test the applicability of the dynamic models
developed by Backus et al. (1994) and Senhadji (1998) to emerging
markets in a more formal way.
REFERENCES
Backus, DK, Kahoe, PJ and Kydland, FE. 1994: Dynamics of the trade
balance and the terms of trade: The J-curve? American Economic Review 84
(1): 84-103.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M. 1985: Devaluation and the J-curve: Some
evidence from LDCs. The Review of Economics and Statistics 67: 500-504.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M and Kara, O. 2005: Income and price elasticities of trade: Some new estimates. The International Trade Journal 19:
165-178.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M and Kutan, AM. 2007: The J-curve in the emerging
economies of Eastern Europe. Applied Economics (forthcoming).
Bahmani-Oskooee, M and Niroomand, F. 1998: Long-run price
elasticities and the Marshall-Lerner condition revisited. Economics
Letters 61: 101-109.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M and Ratha, A. 2004: The J-curve: A literature
review. Applied Economics 36: 1377-1398.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M and Ratha, A. 2007a: The S-curve dynamics of US
bilateral trade. Review of International Economics 15: 430-439.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M and Ratha, A. 2007b: Bilateral S-curve between
Japan and her trading partners. Japan and World Economy 19: 483-489.
Dobrinsky, R. 2003: Convergence in per capita income levels,
productivity dynamics and real exchange rates in the EU acceding
countries. Empirica 30(3): 305-334.
Egert, B, Drine, I, Lommatzsch, K and Rault, C. 2002: The
Balassa-Samuelson effect in central and Eastern Europe: Myth or reality.
Journal of Comparative Economics 31(3): 552-572.
Egert, B and Morales-Zumaquero, A. 2005: Exchange rate regimes,
foreign exchange volatility and export performance in central and
Eastern Europe: Just another blur project?. William Davidson Institute
Working paper no. 782.
Houthakker, HS and Magee, SP. 1969: Income and price elasticities
in world trade. Review of Economics and Statistics 54: 325-347.
Junz, HB and Rhomberg, RR. 1973: Price competitiveness in export
trade among industrial countries. American Economic Review 63: 412-418.
Kemme, D and Teng, W. 2000: Determinants of the real exchange rate,
misalignment and implications for growth in Poland. Economic Systems 24:
171-205.
Kocenda, E and Valachy, J. 2005: Exchange rate volatility before
and after regime switch: A new measure and new evidence from transition.
CERGE-EI Working paper.
Magee, SP. 1973: Currency contracts, pass-through, and devaluation.
Brookings Papers of Economic Activity 1: 303-323.
Meade, EE. 1988: Exchange rates, adjustment, and the J-curve.
Federal Reserve Bulletin 74(10): 633-644.
Rose, AK. 1990: Exchange rates and the trade balance: Some evidence
from developing countries. Economics Letters 34: 271-275.
Rose, AK and Yellen, JL. 1989: Is there a J-curve? Journal of
Monetary Economics 24: 53-68. Senhadji, AS. 1998: Dynamics of the trade
balance and the terms of trade in LDCs: The S-surve. Journal of
International Economics 46: 105-131.
(1) For a comprehensive review of the development in exchange rate
policies in these economies, see Kocenda and Valachy (2005).
(2) For a detailed method of producing cross-correlation functions
and the graphs, see Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha (2007b).
(3) For a discussion of productivity and related issues in these
economies, see, among others, Egert et al. (2002) and Dobrinsky (2003).
MOHSEN BAHMANI-OSKOOEE (1), ALI KUTAN (2) & ARTATRANA RATHA (3)
(1) Economics Department, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee,
MiLwaukee, WI 53201, USA. E-mail: bahmani@uwrn.edu
(2)Department of Economics and Finance, Southern Illinois
University Edwardsville, Edwardsvilie, IL 62026, USA
(3) Economics Department, St Cloud State University, St Cloud, MN
56301, USA