Inflation targeting, policy rates and exchange rate volatility: evidence from Turkey.
Akyurek, Cem ; Kutan, Ali M.
INTRODUCTION
Facing a sudden reversal of capital inflows, Turkey had to exit
from its 13-month-old exchange rate peg and adopt a floating exchange
rate regime in February 2001. The after effects were devastating, as the
nominal exchange rate nearly doubled in 2 months, inflation more than
doubled in 6 months and the economy contracted significantly with the
collapse of the banking system. The crisis led to a new economic
programme funded by the IMF and a new approach to monetary policy
(Akyurek, 2006). Accordingly, in January 2002 the Central Bank of Turkey
(CBT) began implementing an implicit inflation targeting framework
(IIT), which encompassed core attributes of an inflation targeting (IT)
regime including, among other requirements, the announcement of a formal
target for inflation. Coupled with fiscal discipline and economic
reforms, under the IIT framework, inflation declined from over 70% to
below 8% by year-end 2005 while the CBT consistently outperformed its
year-end point targets measured by the consumer price index (CPI). In
due course, the CBT cut its overnight policy rate from 59% to 13.5%. It
seemed more or less that during this period of disinflation, structural
transformation and transitional dynamics, the CBT was searching for an
equilibrium real interest rate commensurate with lower inflation.
Given successful disinflation, improvements in fiscal conditions
and the banking system in particular, the CBT introduced full-fledged IT
at the beginning of 2006, which brought further transparency to the new
framework. During the first year of full-fledged IT, year-end inflation
(9.86%) exceeded the target (5%) by a wide margin. The year saw a sudden
reversal of capital inflows in May-June mainly driven by the
deterioration in investor sentiment towards emerging markets in general.
The exchange rate depreciated by close to 30% and the CBT raised its
policy rate from 13.25% to 17.50%. While inflation returned to pre-shock
levels after about a year, it remained above the path leading to the 4%
year-end target set for 2007.
In this paper, we focus on Turkey's inflation targeting
regime. Turkey's experience is important for several reasons.
First, literature on inflation targeting mainly focuses on developed
countries. (1) More recently, some developing and emerging markets have
adopted a regime of inflation targeting and their experience is examined
by some recent studies. (2) Many new member states of the European Union
(EU) have also adopted inflation targeting regimes. (3) However, there
is scant work on inflation targeting regime for Turkey. We believe that
Turkey's experience may provide valuable lessons for emerging
European and other developing economies. In addition, Turkey is a
candidate for the EU membership, and inflation targeting is consistent
with the Maastricht criteria for joining the European Monetary Union.
The paper has three simple objectives. Firstly, in the second
section, we provide a short description of the IIT period in Turkey
including a discussion of the evolution of the new monetary framework
and the conditions prevailing during the period of its implementation.
Here we emphasise the challenges facing the conduct of monetary policy
in this new environment and also discuss the changes to the framework
with the transition from IIT to IT. The third section provides a
discussion of theoretical issues concerning interest rate policy in
small open economies under the IT regime. The section provides a brief
discussion of monetary transmission with an emphasis on issues
concerning the dynamics of monetary channels in emerging markets and
implications for monetary rules. The fourth section provides a
discussion and empirical analysis of the path of policy rates in Turkey
where the main drivers of policy changes seen under the new framework
are formally investigated. As such, a Taylor rule is estimated for
2002-2007. In the section Exchange rate pass-through, capital inflows
and monetary policy: 2002-2007, the results of an empirical analysis of
exchange rate pass-through to inflation is presented, including an
investigation of changes, if any, in the process since the introduction
of IIT. The next subsection includes a brief discussion of monetary
policy reaction to sudden stops during 2002-2007. Concluding remarks are
presented in the last section.
THE NEW MONETARY POLICY FRAMEWORK AND PRELIMINARY CHALLENGES
The literature provides a long list of requirements that countries
should meet if their IT framework is to operate successfully. (4) Some
are structural requirements and seem more IT-specific when taken as
indispensable parts of the framework. These include (i) public
announcement of medium-term inflation targets; (ii) institutional
commitment to price stability as the primary goal of monetary policy, to
which other goals are subordinated; (iii) increased communication with
the public and markets about the plans and decisions of the central
bank; and (iv) increased accountability of the central bank for
attaining its inflation objective. In this context, Mishkin (2000)
emphasises the finding that IT entails much more than a public
announcement of numerical targets for inflation for the year ahead and
that it is particularly important for emerging market countries to
establish all other conditions if their IT regimes are to be sustainable
over the medium term. The IT regime has the potential to reduce the
likelihood that the central bank would fall into the time-inconsistency
trap if it increases transparency and the accountability of the central
bank, particularly for emerging market countries with a long history of
monetary mismanagement and credibility issues. Other requirements often
cited for a successful IT regime, which seem as desirable features for
successful operation of all available monetary policy frameworks,
include (i) a strong fiscal position; (ii) a well-developed financial
system; (iii) a reasonably well-developed ability to forecast inflation;
and (iv) a well understood transmission mechanism between monetary
policy instruments and inflation.
The new monetary framework of Turkey was introduced as part of a
comprehensive IMF-supported economic programme following the February
2001 crisis during which the exchange rate peg was replaced by a
floating exchange rate. For the balance of 2001, a transition period
before the IIT, IMF programme monetary performance criteria were set as
quantitative limits on net domestic assets (NDA) and net international
reserves (NIR). Yet, an indicative target was set for base money, which
the CBT indicated would be the main operational target of monetary
policy during 2001. With the commencement of the IIT framework in 2002,
the overnight interest rate became the operating target while monetary
indicators also remained as performance criteria and indicative targets.
Turkey's IIT regime encompassed many of the core institutional
attributes of the full-fledged IT framework. Multi-year point CPI
inflation targets were announced and new legislation gave legal
independence to the CBT, as achieving and maintaining price stability
was declared as its primary objective. The CBT was also fully authorised
to choose its monetary policy instrument. Communication with the public,
transparency of monetary policy and accountability of the CBT improved
significantly with the establishment of a monetary policy committee
(MPC), communication of the rationale for policy changes through press
releases, the start of regularly published inflation and monetary policy
reports and frequent public appearances by CBT officials. Inflation
targets were announced as 20%, 12% and 8% for 2002, 2003 and 2004,
respectively, based on the CPI index after inflation had declined to 29%
at end-2001 for which the official projection was 35%. The advantage of
setting the target on broadly defined headline inflation was that it is
better understood by the public, while the disadvantage was that its
movement could reflect factors other than monetary policy measures, and
could be a more difficult target to hit. The CBT preferred to set CPI
targets but also relied on narrowly defined indices of inflation, such
as those excluding supply shock effects, to assess the path of inflation
and to communicate inflation conditions to the public.
The unfavourable economic developments that forced Turkey out of
its peg and motivated the shift to an IT-like regime posed risks for its
credibility. Recurrence of factors that led to economic crises could
force monetary policy to subordinate the newly established inflation
objectives. In this respect, there were some key features of the economy
in general and characteristics of inflation dynamics in particular were
significant obstacles to the success of the new monetary regime at the
onset. Turkey had suffered from high and volatile inflation, as average
inflation over the past 20 years had registered at 61.5% with a standard
deviation of 26%. Inflation had a strong fiscal component, and yet
several studies of its dynamics indicated the existence of a strong
inertial component, which had progressively strengthened over the years.
Additionally, movements in the exchange rate had a profound effect on
inflation due to high pass-through from the former to the latter and
monetary policy had accommodated several external shocks over the past
two decades. (5) The exchange rate-based stabilisation programme
introduced in January 2000 failed to achieve the intended results on the
inflation front and the forced exit from it resulted in a more than
doubling of the nominal exchange rate within a couple of months, which
raised inflation to 74% at the beginning of 2002 from 36% at end-2000.
Inflation targeting frameworks had not been used to engineer major
disinflation from a starting point of high inflation and in this respect
the practice of IT in Turkey would be a challenge.
Schaechter et al. (2000) emphasise exchange rate stability as being
important for the successful operation of IT regime and, in this
context, argue that stability can be defined as a policy framework with
an exchange rate value credible enough to convince the markets that the
inflation target will not be threatened by currency crisis. The sharp
real depreciation in the aftermath of the 2001 crisis and the role IMF
support would play to weather pressures on the currency going forward
were two factors that provided some comfort regarding stability in the
exchange rate at least initially. Yet, past experience with capital
inflows and exchange rate volatility was concerning.
As such, capital inflows (outflows) have been the catalyst for
booms (busts), as evidenced by the correlation between net capital
movements, exchange rate movements and GDP growth over the past several
years. Episodic capital inflows relieved the fundamental foreign
exchange bottle neck of the economy, cheapening imports of essential
intermediate products, and facilitating an expansion of the domestic
financial system and bank credit, which led to periodic outbursts in
growth. These episodes were unequivocally followed by a sharp weakening
in the exchange rate, higher inflation and lower growth.
The fiscal conditions at the start of the IIT framework certainly
provided a challenge for monetary policy. Prior to the 2001 crisis, and
even more so in the aftermath, the level of public sector debt and
concerns regarding its rollover had become the focus of markets. Bonds
issued to recapitalise the banking system, the sharp fall in output and
rising real rates caused the public sector debt ratio to rise sharply.
Additionally, the Treasury issued large sums of foreign exchange
denominated and linked bonds as well as floating rate notes, which
increased the sensitivity of debt service to fluctuations in short-term
interest rates and exchange rates. (6)
The government responded to rising real interest rates following
the crisis by doubling the public sector primary surplus (to over 6% in
2001 and 2002), and IMF funding helped significantly to allay rollover
concerns. Yet fiscal dominance remained a challenge for the new monetary
regime. In the period following the commencement of the IIT regime,
there were several episodes of dramatic change in market sentiment and
overall expectations of economic agents evidenced by the size and
frequency of volatility in domestic bond yields and the nominal exchange
rate, the positive covariance of these variables, and abrupt swings in
real sector expectations (see Figures 1 and 2). This volatility largely
stemmed from changes in market perception of the public sector debt
outlook, which depended heavily on the availability or lack thereof of
some external support. (7) To the extent that such fluctuations would
affect the future path of inflation and growth, they presented serious
challenges for monetary policy under a framework that was at its infancy
stage. Additionally, there were concerns regarding the sustainability of
fiscal discipline, as the turnaround in the primary surplus was largely
due to low quality measures and sustainability depended on completion of
reforms in challenging areas. (8)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Nevertheless, the fiscal conditions gradually improved and became
more supportive to monetary policy, as the government performed well on
the primary surplus. The debt ratio declined significantly (by 32
percentage points by end-2005), the instrument composition of domestic
debt and its maturity improved and the movements in the exchange rate
and bond yields decoupled as volatility in markets declined
substantially.
The banking sector was weak at the start of IIT and its
vulnerability improved gradually. Depreciation of the Turkish Lira, high
funding costs and economic contraction eroded the capital base of banks,
as non-performing loans mounted. In May 2001, the Banking Sector
Regulatory Agency (BRSA) announced a rehabilitation programme and with
immediate action public sector banks were re-capitalised, as their
accumulated hidden losses were recognised. Among other obvious benefits
for banking and the policy environment in general, this was an important
step that provided immediate support to the CBT's monetary policy,
as public sector banks were heavy net borrowers in the overnight market,
which put upward pressure on interest rates. Yet, restructuring of the
private banking sector was a gradual process that spread over several
months, as recapitalisation was largely left to voluntary capital
injection by owners or through mergers carried out by the State Deposit
Insurance Fund. (9) The supervisory BRSA role was improved in several
ways, which improved risk management and helped to reduce overall risks
in the banking sector. (10) Thus, whereas the weakened banking system
may have been a challenge for the IIT framework in its early stages, the
overall improvement in the sector, particularly the progress in balance
sheet risks, gradually eased the concerns of the CBT. (11) The arrival
of foreign banks was also a positive development for the banking sector,
as between 2002 and mid-2005, foreign ownership of bank shares increased
from 3.1% of the total to 12.3%. (12)
Putting all this together, during 2002-2005 the economic
environment seemed to have improved progressively for better support of
the IIT framework. The improvement in fiscal dominance and provision of
official funding together with the higher credibility achieved through
outperforming of inflation targets laid the groundwork for an effective
monetary policy framework going forward.
At the start of 2006 these positive developments led to the
announcement of the full-fledged IT providing further transparency to
the monetary policy framework and change in IMF conditionality adding
more flexibility to monetary policy.
* The role of the MPC changed from being an 'advisor to the
Governor' to 'decision maker'. The targeted index
remained as headline CPI and a [+ or -] 2% tolerance band around the
inflation path leading to the central target was established. (13) The
CBT announced that monetary policy would accommodate the first round
effects of inflationary supply shocks (oil price increases, changes in
indirect tax rates, etc.) to the extent that forecast inflation remains
within the tolerance margin and will react to these shocks only if they
lead to second-round effects through deteriorating inflation
expectations. Positive shocks to inflation were to be treated in the
same manner such that the CBT will react opportunistically and may allow
inflation to decline to the bottom of the band while not easing monetary
policy.
* Under IIT, the IMF programme conditionality in the monetary area
relied on two performance criteria: a ceiling on CBT's NDAs and a
floor on its NIR. (14) With full-fledged IT, the NDA target was
eliminated. (15) The additional flexibility introduced to the monetary
framework through the elimination of NDA performance criteria and base
money indicative targets was a significant change to the regime. Given
the reverse currency substitution that took place in Turkey during
2002-2005, inflation and base money growth rates decoupled since
mid-2003. Thus, while keeping a close eye on developments in monetary
aggregates was still important, the increased flexibility to the regime
improved the CBT's ability to follow an information inclusive
strategy in which many variables could be used for the setting of its
overnight interest rate policy tool. (16)
* The changes in 2006 increased the CBT's accountability as
well. The CBT began to issue inflation forecasts and in the event of a
difference between the inflation outcome and the target, the CBT was
obliged to publish a report explaining the underlying causes to the
public. Should the CBT project a difference for the period ahead, it
would also submit a report to the government explaining the reasons for
this variance including a set of measures to be taken to bring inflation
back in line with the target path.
OPEN ECONOMY IT REGIME: REVIEW OF SOME POLICY ISSUES FOR EMERGING
MARKETS
As demonstrated in Eichengreen (2002), IT monetary rules are
generally derived from the following representation of the economy:
[JI.sub.t+1] = [JI.sub.t] + [alpha]]([y.sub.t] - [y.sup.*)] +
[[epsilon].sub.t+1] (1)
[y.sub.t+1] - [y.sup.*] = [lambda]([y.sub.t] - [y.sup.*)] -
[beta]([r.sub.t] - [r.sup.*)] + [[eta].sub.t+1] (2)
Equation 1 is an accelerationist Phillips Curve, where next
period's inflation (JI) is determined by this period's gap
between actual output ([y.sub.t]) and potential output ([y.sup.*),] the
current inflation level and a disturbance term ([[epsilon].sub.t+1]).
Equation 2 is an aggregate demand function where next period's
output gap is determined by the deviation of the real interest rate
([r.sub.t]) from its normal level ([r.sup.*)] in the current period,
current period's output gap and a disturbance term
([[eta].sub.t+1]).
The key feature of this closed economy representation is that
policy rate changes effect inflation through the aggregate demand
channel only, which occurs with a lag of two periods. The monetary
policy implication of this is that optimal policy under strict inflation
targeting calls for setting the inflation target ([JI.sup.*)] two
periods ahead, as next period's inflation cannot be influenced by
policy rate changes in the current period. Given these assumptions, the
optimal central bank reaction function leads to the following well-known
Taylor rule, which assigns positive weights on deviations of inflation
from target and output from its potential level:
[r.sub.t] = [r.sup.*] + [phi] (JI - JI) + [chi]([y.sub.t] -
[y.sup.*)] (3)
where [phi] and [chi] depend on parameters of equations 1 and 2.
(17) The parameter
values of the inflation gap and output gap variables would then
indicate the degree of flexibility in the IT regime in this closed
economy. (18)
Adding the foreign trade component of the economy to the above
representation yields the following open economy equations:
[JI.sub.t+1] = [JI.sub.t + [alpha]]([y.sub.t] - [y.sup.*]) -
[gamma]([e.sub.t] - [e.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.t+1] (4)
[y.sub.t+1] - [y.sup.*] = [lambda]([y.sub.t] - [y.sup.*]) -
[beta]([r.sub.t] - [r.sup.*]) - [delta][e.sub.t] + [[eta].sub.t+1] (5)
where the exchange rate (e) is defined as the foreign price of
domestic currency. (19)
The inclusion of open economy attributes introduces three key
features to this model of the economy with significant implications for
monetary policy. Firstly, it introduces an additional aggregate demand
channel through which policy rate changes may influence. As such, an
increase in policy rates will depress net export demand, and thus
aggregate demand and inflation, by appreciating the currency. This
indirect aggregate demand channel works with a two-period lag as in the
closed economy aggregate demand channel. Secondly, this additional
aggregate demand channel in the open economy framework increases the
response of inflation to policy rate changes. The policy rate adjustment
required to close a given inflation gap is smaller the more responsive
is the aggregate demand to interest rate changes and the more responsive
is the inflation rate to changes in aggregate demand. (20) Thirdly, a
direct exchange rate effect on inflation, which takes one period, will
occur through a decline in inflation of imported goods as the currency
strengthens. Importantly, the emergence of this direct exchange rate
channel gives the central bank the ability to influence next
period's inflation rate, hence allowing inflation to converge to
its target path faster in the event of an inflation gap.
Under the open economy framework, the question of whether IT
countries should explicitly consider the exchange rate as a variable in
their monetary rule given the existence of these open economy channels
is a somewhat unresolved issue. Particularly, how should an IT central
bank react to shocks that cause a sharp weakening in the exchange rate?
For example how policy rates should be adjusted in response to a sudden
reversal of capital inflows resulting from external factors, which
weakens the exchange rate temporarily? This transitory shock may require
an increase in the policy rate to dampen future demand-induced
inflation, yet the increase should target to dampen only the domestic
component of inflation not the imported component, which is temporary
(Eichengreen, 2002). Likewise Ball (1999) argues that responding to the
domestic component of inflation produces better results when shocks to
the exchange rate are temporary. The logic is that responding to a
problem in the current period that will have disappeared the next
period, using an instrument that takes one period to work, will increase
inflation and output volatility. Note that this assertion is a direct
result of the existence of policy lags such that responding robustly to
a temporary shock destabilises the target variables. If the weakening in
the exchange rate is the result of a real shock to the foreign component
of aggregate demand (to terms of trade or export demand), weaker
aggregate demand will be deflationary in the intermediate term. While
the correction in the exchange rate will be inflationary, the
appropriate response under the IT framework is to allow the exchange
rate to adjust and refrain from increasing the interest rate when the
economy is weakening (Mishkin, 2000). Eichengreen (2002) on the other
hand argues that the central bank may still raise policy rates that will
limit depreciation in the short run, while still allowing the exchange
rate to adjust eventually to its new long-run equilibrium.
Responding to exchange rate shocks become more complicated for
central banks in emerging markets where exchange rate pass-through to
inflation is high and liability dollarisation is widespread. Figures 3-5
show the experience of Turkey (see the fifth section for a detailed
analysis). In most emerging market economies, given lack of credibility
of economic policies and history of high and volatile inflation,
economic agent's often fear that transitory shocks to the exchange
rate will be accommodated by monetary policy. Thus, with faster exchange
rate pass-through the temporary rise in inflation may become permanent.
In the framework presented above high pass-through implies that a change
in the exchange rate has a larger short-run negative impact on inflation
(larger 7 in equation 4) and a smaller short-run positive impact on
output (smaller [delta] in equation 5) since nominal depreciations have
a weaker impact on the real exchange rate. The implication of this is
that it creates a big temptation for the central bank to tighten
monetary policy when facing a temporary weakening in the exchange rate
(Eichengreen (2002). Because if the central bank tightens monetary
policy in response to a weakening in the exchange rate, there is more to
gain from disinflation and less to lose in terms of output due to loss
of competitiveness. Cabellero and Krishnamurthy (2003) argue that
because the principal constraint on output growth in emerging market
economies is a shortage of external funding, raising interest rates
reduces exchange rate depreciation and hence limits inflation, with
limited effects on output beyond the impact of the external constraint.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The existence of currency mismatches in emerging markets leaves
balance sheets of the private and public sectors vulnerable to exchange
rate depreciation. As such, an increase in the exchange rate decreases
net worth of the private sector, which is followed by a decline in
private sector demand and hence output (Cespedes et at., 2000).
Moreover, as the exchange rate depreciation increases the public sector
debt ratio in the existence of public sector foreign debt, fiscal policy
response in the form of lower expenditure and/or higher taxation also
decreases aggregate demand and output. The balance sheet effects also
imply a reduction in the value of 3 in equation 5, the conventional
positive response of output to currency depreciation. (21)
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
The key issue then is that when the exchange rate weakens in
emerging market economies, the coexistence of high pass-through and
liability dollarisation means that there will be a sharp rise in
inflation in the short run but also a strong disinflationary effect in
the longer run, that is, post exchange rate pass-through, as indicated
by Eichengreen (2002) and Gomez (2004). Carranza et al. (2004) show that
inflation may respond negatively to nominal depreciations with this
effect being more intense the higher the level of dollarisation of the
economy and during the recessionary part of the business cycle.
Therefore, in the event of nominal depreciation, an IT central bank
should feel less compelled to raise interest rates in order to
strengthen the domestic currency and limit the short-term rise in
overall inflation due to rising import prices.
Cabellero and Krishnamurthy (2003) argue that the IT central bank
will allow the exchange rate to float freely in the face of an external
shock; this decreases the demand for imported investment, which in turn
decreases the interest rate. Gomez (2004) argues that if central bank
monetary policy looks beyond the short term, the central bank is able to
decrease interest rates. Whereas if the central bank raises interest
rates to minimise the short-term rise in inflation (dubbed fear of
floating by Calvo and Reinhart, 2002), monetary policy reaction combined
with strong balance sheet effects is likely to be procyclical as the
demand for imported investment will increase. This type of reaction by
the central bank may be inconsistent with the long run inflation target.
Gomez (2004) also argues that an IT central bank must emphasise
that inflation will go back to target after the first round effects of
the exchange rate shock. Emphasis on the medium term and the central
bank commitment to the long-term target could be the primary elements of
the communication strategy under the IT framework. Mishkin (2004) also
proposes that under a sharp depreciation, the central bank should focus
on inflation after the shock. While depreciation causes inflation in the
very short term, monetary policy transmission mechanisms, especially the
aggregate demand channel, take about 2 years to effect inflation
sizably. In the face of an unanticipated event such as a sudden stop,
the central bank is unable to attain the inflation target in the short
term. (22)
On the other hand, Ball and Reyes (2004, 2006), Eichengreen (2002)
and Mishkin (2004) also argue that with the IT approach to monetary
policy; movements in the exchange rate will be taken into account
indirectly in setting monetary policy, because the exchange rate affects
price behaviour. This will generally produce a pattern of monetary
tightening when the exchange rate depreciates, a response similar but
not necessarily of the same magnitude, to that which would be undertaken
if the exchange rate were being targeted directly. For this reason, an
IT country may appear to be showing fear of floating behaviour.
Four main points emerge from these papers. Firstly, in the event of
a shock to the exchange rate, the most permanent and thus important
effect of monetary policy on inflation and output depends on the central
bank's reaction. Secondly, in emerging market economies where
exchange rate passthrough is high and liability dollarisation is
widespread, the central bank should focus on the domestic component of
inflation with the aim of returning inflation to the target path in the
longer term when the exchange rate weakens. Thirdly, fear of floating
type of reaction by the central bank to an exchange rate shock controls
exchange rate pass-through during the first year, but at a cost: a
protracted recession in the longer horizon. Finally, there is a fine
line between domestic interest rate increases that are associated with
exchange rate fluctuations but are due to strict adherence to an open
economy IT regime and changes due to fear of floating which imply a
hidden policy goal of managing the exchange rate. The problem addressed
here is one of measurement.
From a policy perspective, it is also important to note that
neither high exchange rate pass-through nor liability dollarisation is
exogenous. Exchange rate pass-through is estimated to be higher in
emerging market economies. (23) Yet it is also true that adoption of IT
has led to lower pass-through in several emerging market economies. (24)
Several factors are known to affect the magnitude and speed of
pass-through from exchange rate changes to inflation. Among others, the
output gap, the type of exchange rate regime in place, the perceived
degree of policymakers' commitment to disinflation, trade openness,
and the level and volatility of inflation influence the dynamics of the
process. The output gap affects the pass-through by reducing the
firm's power to increase prices, as during times of increasing
sales firms find it easier to pass-through increases in costs to final
prices (Goldfajn and Werleng (2000).The inflation level affects the
persistence of cost changes, which is positively correlated with
pass-through (Taylor, 1993). This view, as expressed by Campa and
Goldberg (2002) is that the pass-through of costs into mark-ups is
endogenous to a country's inflation performance, generating a
virtuous circle where low inflation variability leads to reduced mark
ups, less inflationary implications of monetary expansions and continued
low mark ups. Credible monetary authorities are expected to act
according to the inflation stability objective, which keeps low
inflation expectations even in the advent of a large depreciation. Put
differently, enhanced credibility of the monetary framework will tame
the worries regarding the prospect that transitory exchange rate shocks
will be validated and hence become permanent. Output effects of
liability dollarisation (currency mismatches) are also not completely
independent of the type of monetary regime. As such a flexible exchange
rate will encourage hedging by banks and non-banks and discourage
currency mismatches. Flexibility in the exchange rate endogenises
liability dollarisation and currency mismatches can be reduced to some
extent with flexibility and other prudent policies (Goldstein and
Turner, 2004). Cabellero and Krishnamurthy (2003) show that fear of
floating may seem optimal from a contemporaneous perspective, as it
dampens short-term inflation with limited output effects, and yet it is
suboptimal ex ante. The reason for this suboptimality is that the
anticipation of the central bank's tight monetary policy during the
sudden stop has important effects on the private sector's
incentives to insure against sudden-stop events. Simply put, contracting
dollar debt is less costly in an environment where the domestic currency
is expected to be supported in the event of a sudden reversal of capital
inflows. Thus, the anticipation of tight monetary policy leaves the
economy less insured against the sudden stop. (25)
PATH OF POLICY RATES IN TURKEY DURING 2002-2007: TAYLOR RULE
ESTIMATIONS
Four factors in particular seemed to have influenced interest rate
policy in the environment of floating exchange rates and IIT. First, the
vulnerability of public sector debt required excellent coordination
among fiscal policy, public sector debt management and interest rate
policy. When markets are concerned about the sustainability of public
sector debt, as they were increasingly in Turkey in the aftermath of the
2001 crisis, policy rate changes can have a powerful unconventional
impact on expectations. As such, if rates are increased or cuts are
delayed, the markets tend to expect future monetisation of debt in which
case tighter monetary policy could worsen inflation expectations and
lead to higher inflation. Fiscal dominance became lesser of an issue
with declining debt ratio, extending maturity and strict adherence to
large primary surpluses. Secondly and closely related to the fiscal
issue, the perception of risks regarding the adherence to the IMF
programme targets and the implementation of structural reforms at times
heavily dominated market expectations, particularly in the early stages
and seemed to be a key variable affecting policy rate decisions. (26)
Thirdly, there were ambiguities regarding the transmission mechanism
from interest rates to economic activity and inflation, as indicated by
the CBT on several occasions. The effectiveness of the impact of
interest rate changes on inflation through the aggregate demand channel
was questionable given the relatively low level of financial
intermediation. Moreover, the existence of a relatively stable and
predictable link between the output gap and inflation was in question as
well. Finally, the real exchange rate appreciated strongly (by 38%
during 2002-2005), which was due to strong capital inflows and partial
de-dollarisation. This complicated the gauging of monetary conditions,
as the exchange rate channel of monetary transmission was conjectured to
be strong and quick in Turkey. The questions of how much real
appreciation the CBT should have allowed and how monetary policy should
react to occasional sharp corrections in the exchange rate became
important issues shortly after the introduction of IIT.
The CBT's successive rate cuts brought the overnight policy
interest rate from 59% to 13.75% during January 2002-April 2006. In the
meantime, inflation decreased from 70% to 7.08% by mid-2004 before
climbing up to 8.18% in April 2006. In due course, year-end CPI point
inflation targets of 35%, 20%, 12% and 8% for 2002, 2003, 2004 and 2005,
respectively, were outperformed (see Figure 6). Yet, the 4% target for
end-2006 was missed by a wide margin as inflation increased to 9.67% on
the back of a temporary weakening in the exchange rate in mid-2006. In
reaction to the sudden stop that occurred in May-June 2006, the CBT
raised its policy rate to 17.50%.
Eyeballing the data for the entire IT period seems to suggest that
the pace of CBT's nominal policy rate changes more or less
reflected the pace of decline in inflation expectations, as rate cuts
appeared to be more aggressive at times of sharper decline in the
credibility gap (inflation expectations less target path) and more
passive (smaller cuts or occasional pause) during slow or no convergence
of inflation expectations (see Figure 7). The IIT period shows that real
rates (forward looking) have remained stationary around a progressively
declining plateau (see Figure 8). Real rates were at around 20%-22%
until mid-2003, thereafter declining to an average 14% till end-2004 and
then to an average slightly below 10% till end-2005 before climbing up
to around 12% in the second half of 2006. Yet, a more formal analysis of
interest rate policy with the estimation of an open economy Taylor rule
provides a simple and easily understood starting point for the analysis
of monetary policy during the IT period.
We specify a Taylor rule for the real interest rate (r), dependent
on the deviation of expected inflation from the inflation target path
(JI-JI*), the output gap (y-y*), the nominal exchange rate depreciation
(e) and Turkey's sovereign debt risk premium (EMBITR). (27) The
latter is added as a proxy of Turkey's risk premium.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[r.sub.t] = [c.sub.1] + [c.sub.2] (JI - JI) + [c.sub.3] (y -
[y.sup.*]) + [c.sub.4]e + [c.sub.5]EMBITR + errorterm (6)
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Our sample period is January 2003-December 2006, which is
relatively short and therefore the results should be interpreted with
some caution. Nevertheless, we believe that the estimations provide
statistical facts that help to explain the path of policy rates in
Turkey during the IT period (see Table 1). Four points stand out in
particular. Firstly, the estimated CBT reaction function tracks the path
of policy rates very closely (Figure 9). Secondly, Turkey's risk
premium has been a very significant factor determining the path of
policy rates during the IT period. Thirdly, results indicate that
nominal exchange rate changes and output gap developments have played a
relatively minor role in interest rate decisions. (28) Finally, the
coefficient of the inflation gap variable is borderline significant.
The significance of the risk premium variable (EMBITR) and the
results in general indicate the role of declining equilibrium real rates
in CBT's policy function. As further improvements towards building
a sustainable fiscal regime and stronger banking sector among other
reforms were completed, Turkey's risk premia declined. It seems
that during this period of structural transformation and transitional
dynamics, the CBT was searching for an equilibrium real rate
commensurate with low(er) inflation. The more comfortable the CBT felt
with progress on these fronts, the easier and quicker have been the move
to lower real rates.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
EXCHANGE RATE PASS-THROUGH, CAPITAL INFLOWS AND MONETARY POLICY:
2002-2007
Exchange rate pass-through: empirical results
Exchange rate movements and inflation expectations have played an
important role in inflation dynamics in Turkey over the past several
years. (29) The past studies have shown that exchange rate pass-through
to inflation in Turkey is relatively quick and high. (30) On the other
hand, recent studies indicate that exchange rate pass-through to both
non-tradable and tradable components of CPI inflation in the IT and
floating exchange rate environment has declined (Kara et al., 2004,
2007). In this section, we estimate exchange rate pass-through with more
up to date data by looking at the dynamic relationships between
inflation, exchange rate depreciation, and output gap. Impulse responses
obtained from this multivariate VAR framework are then used to calculate
exchange rate pass-through. Accordingly the pass-through coefficient is
computed as the ratio of cumulative impulse responses of inflation to
the cumulative impulse responses of exchange rate depreciation to a
shock in the latter. The computation is done for several time intervals
to assess the extent and speed of pass-through. (31) As well, we look at
the change in the dynamics of exchange rate pass-through to overall CPI
inflation and its tradable and non-tradable components during the IT
period.
The model is estimated for the period January 1996-June 2007 and
includes interactive dummy variables for all variables in the system,
which takes the value of zero for the time period prior to the
introduction of IIT (January 1996-December 2001) and the value itself of
the respective variable during the IIT period (January 2002-June 2007).
This would be a convenient method for evaluating changes, if any, in the
size and speed of exchange rate pass-through following implementation of
the IIT framework. Hence, two sets of impulse responses are considered
in calculating pass-through.
Our analysis shows two important findings. Firstly, results
indicate that pass-through reaches 34% for the CPI index in a 12-month
period with some 86% of that taking place in the first 6 months
following the exchange rate shock during January 1996-June 2007 (see
Figure 3). Secondly, during the IT period the speed (marginally) and
size of pass-through declines. As such, 24% of the exchange rate
depreciation is passed on to consumer prices in 12 months with just
below 80% of that being completed in 6 months (see Figure 3). (32) Kara
et al. (2007) argue that the decline in pass-through is not surprising
given the changes to the monetary policy framework and the institutional
developments taken place including the operational independence of the
CBT.
While lower pass-through is a positive development, Edwards (2006)
argues that this 'inflation-centred' view is too simplistic and it tends to ignore the role of relative prices and the real exchange
rate. As such, for the exchange rate to act as a shock absorber in
general, changes in the nominal exchange rate must be translated into
real exchange rate changes. It is thus important to distinguish between
two notions of exchange rate pass-through: pass-through into
non-tradables and pass-through into tradables. From a policy
perspective, pass-through coefficients for tradables and non-tradables
should be different, with the former being higher than the latter. It
follows then that the adoption of IT regime would improve the shock
absorbing capacity of nominal exchange rates if the pass-through from
exchange rate to non-tradable prices has declined or if the pass-through
to tradable good prices has increased (or, at least, has not declined)
as argued by Edwards (2006).
We used the same methodology to estimate the exchange rate
passthrough to the non-tradable and tradable parts of the CPI and the
impact of the IT regime on the process. (33) This analysis showed two
important results. Firstly and as expected, the exchange rate
pass-through to tradables is much stronger than that to non-tradables
for the entire sample period as well as the IT period. Secondly, there
seems to be a significant decline in the speed and extent of
pass-through to non-tradable prices while the decline in pass-through to
tradable prices seems to be more mild (Figures 4 and 5). While 37.1% and
43.1% of the exchange rate depreciation is passed on to nontradable
prices in 6 months and 12 months during the full sample period, the
respective figures for the IT period are much lower at 15. (2% and
23.4%. (34) The improvement in the speed of exchange rate pass-through
to tradables seems more significant than its magnitude. While
three-month cumulative pass-through in the IT period declined to 18%
from 30%, the corresponding figures for the 12-month horizon are similar
at 42.6% and 46.5%, respectively. While Kara et al. (2007) indicate that
the sharp decline in pass-through to non-tradables is a sign of the
decline in expectations-driven pass-through, they attribute its more
pronounced improvement relative to the tradable CPI component as an
indication of the weakening of indexation-driven pass-through.
In summary, there seems to be strong evidence of a change in the
dynamics of the exchange rate pass-through that has enhanced the
shock-absorbing ability of floating exchange rate regime. The results
presented by others and those shown here suggest that the pass-through
effect should be less of a concern for policymakers in Turkey and
provide a rationale for a relatively weaker reaction of monetary policy
to sharp exchange rate movements in the IT period.
'Sudden Stops' and monetary policy reaction
Following the switch to the new monetary framework, the CBT
repeatedly emphasised, through regularly published reports as well as
through public appearances by officials, that the exchange rate was not
a target for monetary policy. Instead, the CBT announced its intention
to smooth excessive volatility in the nominal exchange rate without
altering the trend movement in the real exchange rate.
Rising confidence in Turkey on the back of disinflation and strong
growth, the start of EU accession talks and favourable global conditions
in general resulted in a surge in capital inflows during the IIT period
(see Figure 10). While foreign investor holdings of Turkish equities and
YTL denominated government bonds increased significantly, inflows from
foreign direct investment increased sharply as well. Equity and
government bond holdings of foreign investor's increased from $3.5
to $42 billion and $3.6 to $21.5 billion, respectively, from the
beginning of 2002 to April 2006 (see Figure 11). While total FDI inflows
were $13.5 billion during the previous 15 years prior to 2002, the
figure from there on to 2007 climbed by another $43 billion. These
developments together with de-dollarisation put downward pressure on the
nominal exchange rate. While resident's foreign exchange deposits
in the banking system stood at over 55% of total bank deposits at
end-2002, the figure declined to below 34% by mid-2006.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
Given the strength in capital inflows, from 2002 to mid-2007, the
CBT's reserve accumulation through discretionary purchases and
pre-announced auctions were US$25.2 and US$23.4 billion (net),
respectively, as CBT reserves increased from US$19 to over US$65 billion
(see Figures 10 and 12). The CBT officials communicated that such
discretionary reserve purchases should not be seen as a result of
CBT's disapproval of the level of the exchange rate and that buying
reserves through auctions mainly reflected the intention to build
reserves given the heavy official debt repayment schedule and the desire
to improve external risk parameters. Moreover, the timing of initiation,
suspension and resumption of auctions was said to be a part of
CBT's strategy to curtail excessive volatility through signalling
effects. Although the markets did feel on some occasions that the sole
purpose of CBT intervention was to prevent the exchange rate from
appreciating more than a certain threshold, as pressure in one direction
was not perceived as volatility. The CBT partly sterilised the expansion
in base money driven by the rise in international reserves (Figure 13).
Yet, base money growth remained high and, on average, was three times
the rate of annual inflation during the IT period, which partly
reflected the rise in demand for real YTL balances.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
While the pressure on the exchange rate was downward in general,
the markets were subjected to four sudden stop episodes during the IT
period, which resulted in sharp corrections in the exchange rate and the
financial markets in general. The first two of these episodes occurred
during the April-May period of 2004 and 2005 during which mild portfolio
outflows were seen following a period of sharply rising inflows (Figure
14). The 2004 episode saw the exchange rate rise by 17.5%; the sovereign
debt yields jump by 190 basis points and benchmark YTL denominated
government bond yields increase from 22% to 30%. While local yields and
sovereign spreads gradually returned to their pre-correction levels by
end-year, the exchange rate saw a volatile period before entering an
appreciation trend in early 2005 and returning to its pre-correction
level roughly a year later than the start of the episode (Figures 15 and
16). In the meantime, CPI inflation, which had steadily declined to
7.87% from over 70% at the start of 2002, increased to 9.35% by end-2004
but remained below the 12% target.
During the April-May 2005 correction in markets, the exchange rate
increased by 9%, sovereign spreads jumped by 235 basis points, while
local yields increased marginally from 16% to 18.3% (see Figure 15).
Normalisation of yields and spreads took about 3 months while the
exchange rate gained back one-third of its loss against the US dollar
within 2 months after the initial shock and remained more or less at its
new level for the following 12 months (see Figure 15). Inflation
continued to decline following the April-May 2005 correction in the
markets, as it fell from 8.18% in April 2005 to 7.72% at year-end.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
Casual observance of the data indicates that the CBT did not react
strongly to the first two externally driven corrections in the IIT
period (see Figure 16). The sudden stop-driven corrections during
April-May in 2004 and 2005 caused the CBT to halt policy rate cuts, as
the credibility gap (inflation target less expectations) widened. Yet
the CBT refrained from intervention in the foreign exchange market to
prevent YTL weakening.
[FIGURE 16 OMITTED]
The mid-2006 episode, the strongest of all sudden stops Turkey was
subjected to under the IT framework, resulted in net total portfolio
outflows of about 4 billion US dollars, equivalent to about half of
cumulative inflows during the prior 12 months of the shock, which led to
a 28% correction in the exchange rate, rise in YTL benchmark yields from
13.7% to 21.3% and sovereign spreads by 150 basis points. The shock was
mainly driven by negative developments in global liquidity, yet the
strength of deterioration in Turkish markets was related to domestic
developments as well. The markets seemed to take into account
Turkey's rising current deficit (from 0.8% in 2002 to over 7.5% by
mid-2006) and its sensitivity to increasing oil prices. But more
importantly, April inflation figures released early May came in much
higher than market expectations after the CBT had lowered its overnight
policy rate on April 27 by 25 basis points. The external shock also
coincided with a period of prolonged uncertainty regarding the
appointment of the new CBT governor. The government's first choice,
which was revealed at the last minute following a period with a
caretaker, a vice governor at the time, was vetoed by the president. The
entire process was handled very poorly and raised doubts regarding the
credibility of the monetary framework shortly after the move to
full-fledged IT.
The policy response by the CBT was much stronger this time around,
as the overnight policy rate was increased by 400 basis points in a
matter of 3 weeks following two emergency MPC meetings on 7 June and 25
June and the CBT sold close to US$2.1 billion in reserves (3.5% of
total). Policy rates were increased by another 25 basis points during
the 20 July scheduled meeting of the MPC bringing the total tightening
to 425 basis points (see Figure 16). By mid-August the exchange rate
regained half of the initial weakness before entering a decisive
appreciation trend, which took the exchange rate to below its
pre-correction level about 12 months later (see Figure 16). Yet, local
debt yields remained high, easing marginally and remaining around 19%
after 12 months while sovereign spreads declined to pre-correction
levels gradually after 12 months (see Figure 15). Inflation increased
from 8.16% in May to 9.67%, more than twice the 4% target set for
end-2006. There were no discussions of amending the 2006 target
following the mid-year external shock and the CBT argued through its
official publications that they expected inflation to come close to its
2007 year-end target of 4% following the tightening of monetary policy.
Their official forecast saw inflation falling between 9.1% and 10.5% by
the end of 2006 with a 70% probability in their third-quarter inflation
report issued on September 2006, which did not provide forecasts for
end-2007. The first report of 2007 issued in March provided a forecast
for end-2007 between 3.6% and 6.6% with a probability of 70%.
The repercussions of a sudden stop of the magnitude, seen in
May-June 2006, can be widespread for Turkey. The two immediate effects
of the exchange rate correction are the short-term rise in inflation
given exchange rate pass-through and slowdown in demand mainly as a
result of the affect of depreciation on balance sheets given widespread
liability dollarisation. Yet, as discussed in the third section, both
where the economy settles in the longer-term and the permanent effect of
capital outflows would be heavily influenced by monetary policy
reaction. With respect to the latter, for the Turkish case particularly,
six issues could have been taken into consideration. Firstly, while
still high, the post-IT developments in exchange rate pass-through were
encouraging and particularly, the sharp decline in pass-through to the
non-tradable component of the targeted CPI index should have provided
some comfort to policymakers in terms of the medium-term path in
inflation following the external shock. Secondly, the weakening in the
exchange rate would likely to generate forces to decrease inflation over
the medium-term through balance sheet effects on economic activity. The
true extent of the currency mismatches and the balance sheet effects can
be difficult to measure. (35) Given the sharp decline in currency
mismatches in the banking sector (from $14.5 billion at end-2001 to $0.6
billion at mid2006), the decline in foreign exchange denominated net
public sector debt (from $88bn at end-2002 to $30bn at mid-2006), and
evidence provided on the foreign currency position of the corporations
and households, the aggregate currency mismatches seem to have improved
since 2002. We conjecture that aggregate mismatches remained at levels
that would unlikely to cause systemic financial distress but that
weakening in the currency would decrease economic activity through the
same dynamics seen over the past several years. The historical
relationship between the real exchange rate and economic growth
indicates that appreciation periods and acceleration in economic
activity go hand in hand. Likewise, sharp slowdowns in growth are
associated with periods of sharp depreciation. Given that the principal
constraint to economic growth has been the availability of external
financing, it is not surprising to see that the parallel movements in
the exchange rate and growth are largely due to fluctuations in capital
inflows. Capital inflows lead to exchange rate appreciation, positive
balance sheet effects and higher economic growth. Moreover, appreciation
has a positive impact on economic activity through lowering production
costs of firms where imported inputs are a large part of the production
process and related costs constitute a large share of production costs.
Likewise, it is through these mechanisms that exchange rate depreciation
causes a decline in economic activity, contrary to the conventional
wisdom. Indeed, Kara et al. (2007) empirically demonstrate these effects
in Turkey. As such, they conclude that the cost channel of the exchange
rate on output gap dominates the demand channel. Akyurek and Kutan
(2006) also find that real exchange rate changes lead to changes in the
output gap in the same direction. Thus, while the sudden-stop-driven
exchange rate depreciation would increase short-term inflation mainly
through the spike in inflation in the tradable component of CPI, its
effects on the output gap would be supportive of disinflation in the
medium term. Thirdly, adherence to a floating exchange rate, as
emphasised repeatedly by the CBT officials on numerous occasions, would
be important in terms of discouraging the expansion of widespread
currency mismatches and encouraging wider use of hedging products.
Fifthly, the policy response should, to some extent, reflect the
awareness of risks associated with carry trade-driven excessive
short-term capital inflows and the resulting liquidity expansion. Simply
put, large interest rate differentials have been a source of conflict
with the IT regime. Finally, given that the 2006 year-end target became
simply unattainable in the aftermath of the mid-year external shock, the
logical move by the CBT and the government should have been to revise
the year-end target. Moreover, given the length of time it takes for the
monetary policy transmission mechanisms to effect inflation, especially
the aggregate demand channel, a revision of the 2007 inflation target
should have been considered as well. Akyurek and Kutan (2006) and Kara
et al. (2007) argue that the impact of policy rate changes on economic
activity and inflation have become more predictable and in the direction
in line with theory, improving the transmission capacity of monetary
policy following the change in the monetary regime to IT. Upward
revision of the 2007 target would have amounted to softening the
targeted disinflation trajectory since the year-end target for 2008 was
set at 4% as well. The CPI inflation climbed from 8.83% in April 2006 to
over 11% within 4 months before declining to the 7.3% level as of August
2006. The return of inflation to pre-shock levels was a welcome
development. And yet, despite the significant tightening of monetary
policy, inflation was still significantly above the path leading to the
4% target. As well and as expected, the deceleration in growth became
visible only in the second quarter of 2007, that is during the third
quarter following the external shock. These developments are supportive
of the argument for the softening of the targeted disinflation
trajectory following the external shock of mid-2006.
These complications highlight the view that monetary policy in the
real world is more of an art than a science and there is very little
doubt that engineering an optimal monetary policy response was a
challenging task under the circumstances following the May-June 2006
sudden stop episode. Yet, increasing interest rates at the speed and
extent they were is a policy response that should be analysed carefully
to the extent that the move seemed to aim at limiting the short-term
temporary spike in inflation and containing negative balance sheet
effects through supporting a recovery in the exchange rate. The issue
addressed here is one of magnitude. Was the policy response associated
with adherence to an open economy IT regime or due to fear of floating
type of reaction which imply a hidden policy goal of managing the
exchange rate? (36) While the extent and scope of monetary policy
reaction in mid-2006 may suggest a defense of the currency during this
episode, particularly when compared to the other three episodes
experienced during the sample period, we have not attempted to test
statistically as to whether the CBT has reacted to exchange rate
corrections above and beyond their effects on inflation. To test this
possibility the dynamic evolution of the policy function must be
analysed and at this stage given the shortness of the data period and
the ongoing structural transformation in the economy, meaningful
statistical analysis is difficult to conduct.
CONCLUSION
Turkey's adoption of an IT-like regime in 2002 occurred when
inflation was on the rise and after banking sector recapitalisation
process had led to a significant jump in public sector debt. Concerns
over public sector debt rollover were dominating the dynamics of
financial markets with strong repercussions on macroeconomic fundamentals. Fiscal discipline, the improvement in the policy
environment and the overall progress in the economy provided
progressively stronger support to the enhancement of the new monetary
regime, which lent support to the CBT's decision of a gradual shift
to full-fledged IT after 3 years. The change provided further
transparency to the monetary policy framework and added more flexibility
to monetary policy.
Evidence from the estimation of a Taylor-like central bank reaction
function shows that the CBT lowered real rates mainly in conjunction
with the decline in Turkey's risk premium, as inflation declined
significantly during 2002-2006. While changes in the exchange rate,
output gap and inflation expectations were found to influence policy
rate changes, during this period of structural transformation and
transitional dynamics, it seems that the more comfortable the CBT felt
with progress on fiscal policy and reforms, the easier and quicker
seemed to be the move to lower real rates.
With the introduction of a comprehensive economic programme,
implementation of structural reforms, completion of large privatisation projects and the start of accession talks with the EU, Turkey attracted
significant amount of foreign capital. As a result of this, during the
inflation targeting and floating exchange rate period, the YTL remained
strong and the real exchange rate appreciated significantly. The latter
together with high growth led to a significant widening of the current
account deficit, which rendered Turkish financial markets susceptible to
external shocks. The markets were subjected to externally driven
reversal of capital inflows on three occasions. While monetary responses
to the shocks in April-May of 2004 and 2005 were relatively limited, a
much stronger reaction was given to the greater turbulence of mid-2006.
The policy reaction of mid-2006 brings the question of whether or not
this response was associated with adherence to an open economy IT regime
or due to fear of floating type of reaction geared towards bringing a
recovery in the exchange rate. Given the extent of tightening in the
policy rate, this question is particularly relevant in the Turkish case
where the exchange rate depreciations have been associated with economic
slowdowns.
Inflation returned to its pre-shock level within a year, yet after
having overshot the 2006 target, it remained significantly above the
2007 target as well despite the sharp rise in policy rates. The
developments in the inflation rate are supportive of the argument for
the softening of the targeted disinflation trajectory following the
external shock of mid-2006.
REFERENCES
Akyurek, C. 1999: Post-liberalization inflation in Turkey: an
empirical investigation. Yapi Kredi Economic Review 10(2): 31-53.
Akyurek, C. 2006: The Turkish crisis of 2001: A classic? Emerging
Markets Finance and Trade 42(1): 5-32.
Akyurek, C and Kutan, A. 2006: Can inflation targeting be effective
in emerging economies?: The Turkish experience. Working Paper No.
06-0902, Southern Illinois University Edwardsville, Economics and
Finance Department.
Amato, JD and Gerlach, S. 2002: Inflation targeting in emerging
market and transition economies: Lessons after a decade. European
Economic Review 46(4-5): 781-790.
Armenio, F, Goldfajn, I and Minella, A. 2003: Inflation targeting
in emerging economies. NBER Working paper series No. 10019, NBER:
Cambridge, MA, October.
Ball, CP and Reyes, J. 2004: Inflation targeting or fear of
floating in disguise: The case of Mexico. International Journal of
Finance and Economics 9: 49-69.
Ball, CP and Reyes, J. 2006: Inflation targeting or fear of
floating in disguise: A broader perspective. Journal of Macroeconomics,
forthcoming.
Ball, L. 1999: Policy rules for open economies. In: Taylor, J (ed).
Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago Press: Chicago pp. 43-54.
Blejer, M, Leone, AM, Rabanal, P and Schwartz, G. 2001: Inflation
targeting in the context of IMF-supported adjustment programs. IMF
Working Paper, 01/31.
Borensztein, E and De Gregorio, J. 1999: Devaluation and inflation
after currency crises. University of Chile, unpublished manuscript.
Available at http://www.itam.mx/lames/papas/invitses/degregor.pdf.
Brash, DT. 2002: Inflation targeting: New Zealand's experience
over 14 years (2002). The North American Journal of Economics and
Finance 13(2): 99-112.
Brimmer, AF. 2002: Central banks and inflation targeting in
perspective. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 13(2):
93-97.
Cabellero, RJ and Krishnamurthy, A. 2003: Inflation targeting and
sudden stops. NBER Working Papers 9599.
Calvo, GA and Reinhart, C. 2002: Fear of floating. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 117(2): 379-408.
Campa, JM and Goldberg, LS. 2002: Exchange rate pass-through into
import prices: a Macro or Micro phenomenon? NBER Working Paper Series
No. 8934.
Carare, A, Schaechter, A, Stone, MR and Zelmer, M. 2002:
Establishing initial conditions in support of inflation targeting. IMF
Working Paper.
Carare, A and Stone, MR. 2006: Inflation targeting regimes.
European Economic Review 50(5): 1297-1315.
Carranza, L, Sanchez, JEG and Biscarri, JG. 2004: Exchange rate and
inflation dynamics in dollarized economies. Department of Economics,
Universidad de Navarra Working Paper No. 10/04.
Cespedes, LF, Chang, R and Velasco, A. 2000: Balance sheets and
exchange rate policy. NBER Working Paper Series No. 7840.
Choudhri, E and Hakura, D. 2006: Exchange rate passthrough to
domestic prices: Does the inflationary environment matter? Journal of
International Money and Finance 25(4): 614-639.
Dodge, D. 2002: Inflation targeting in Canada: Experience and
lessons. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 13(2):
113-124.
Edwards, S. 2006: The relationship between exchange rates and
inflation targeting revisited. Central Bank of Chile Working Papers No.
409.
Eichengreen, B. 2002: Can emerging markets float? Should they
inflation target?. University of California: Berkeley.
Goldfajn, I and Werleng, S. 2000: The pass-through from
depreciation to inflation: A panel study. Working Paper 423, Potifical
Catholic University of Rio de Janeiro.
Goldstein, M and Turner, P. 2004: Controlling currency mismatches
in emerging markets. Institute for International Economics: Washington,
DC April 2004.
Golineli, R and Rovelli, R. 2005: Monetary policy transmission,
interest rate rules and inflation targeting in three transition
countries. Journal of Banking and Finance 29(1): 183-201.
Gomez, J. 2004: Inflation targeting, sudden stops, and the cost of
fear of floating. The Central Bank of Columbia.
Goncalves, CES and Salles, JM. 2008: Inflation targeting in
emerging economies: What do the data say? Journal of Development
Economics 85(1-2): 312-318.
Honda, Y. 2000: Some tests on the effects of inflation targeting in
New Zealand, Canada, and the UK. Economics Letters 66(1): 1-6.
Johnson, DR. 2002: The effect of inflation targeting on the
behavior of expected inflation: Evidence from an 11 country panel.
Journal of Monetary Economics 49(8): 1521-1538.
Jonas, J and Mishkin, FS. 2003: Inflation targeting in transition
countries: Experience and prospects. NBER Working Paper 9667.
Kara, H, Kucuk-Tuger, H, Ozlale, U, Tuger, B and Yucel, EM. 2007:
Exchange rate regimes and pass-through: Evidence from the Turkish
economy. Contemporary Economic Policy 25(2): 206-225.
Kara, H and Ogunc, F. 2004: Exchange rate pass-through in Turkey:
It is slow but is it really low? Central Bank of Turkey Working Paper
05/10.
Kara, H., Ogunc, F., Kucuk-Tuger, H., Ozlale, U. and Sarikaya, C..
2007: Estimating the output gap in a changing economy. Central Bank of
Turkey Working Paper.
Leigh, D and Rossi, M. 2002: Exchange rate pass-through in Turkey.
IMF Working Paper No. 204.
McCarthy, J. 1999: Passthrough of exchange rates and import prices
to domestic inflation in some industrialized economies. BIS Working
Paper No. 79.
Mishkin, FS. 2000: Inflation targeting in emerging market
countries. NBER Working Paper Series, http://www.nber.org/papers/w7618.
Mishkin, FS. 2004: Can inflation targeting work in emerging market
countries. NBER Working Paper No. 10646.
Nogueira Jr, RP. 2006: Inflation targeting, exchange rate
passthrough and fear of floating Department of Economics, University of
Kent Studies in Economics No.0605.
Orlowski, LT. 2004: Money rules for monetary convergence to the
euro. Journal of Policy Modeling 26(7): 817-837.
Orlowski, LT. 2005: Monetary convergence of EU accession countries to the eurozone: A theoretical framework and policy implications.
Journal of Banking and Finance 29(1): 203-225.
Orlowski, LT and Rybinski, K. 2006: Implications of ERM2 for
Poland's monetary policy. Economic Systems 30(4): 346-365.
Saatcioglu, C and Korap, L. 2006: Determinants of Turkish
inflation. Discussion Paper No. 7, Turkish Economic Association.
Schaechter, A, Stone, MP and Zelmer, M. 2000: Adopting inflation
targeting: practical issues for emerging market countries. Occasional
Paper No. 202, IMF.
Schmidt-Hebbel, K and Tapia, M. 2002: Inflation targeting in chile.
The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 13(2): 125-146.
Schmidt-Hebbel, K and Werner, AM. 2002: Inflation targeting in
Brazil, Chile, and Mexico: Performance, credibility, and the exchange
rate. Central Bank of Chile Working Papers.
Siklos, PL and Abel, I. 2002: Is Hungary ready for inflation
targeting? Economic Systems 26(4): 309-333.
Taylor, J. 1993: Discretion versus policy rules in practice.
Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39: 195-214.
Tortes, A. 2003: Monetary policy and interest rates: Evidence from
Mexico. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 14(3):
357-379.
(1) Recent studies include Brimmer (2002), Dodge (2002), Johnson
(2002) and Carare and Stone (2006).
(2) For individual country experiences, see Brash (2002) and Honda
(2000) for the New Zealand; Armenio et al. (2003) for Brazil; and Torres
(2003) for Mexico. Ainato and Gerlach (2002) provide evidence from many
developing countries and emerging markets. More recently, Goncalves and
Salles (2008) provide evidence from 36 emerging markets and they find
that those countries that followed an IT regime did have a better
economic performance than those that did not.
(3) The following studies study the experience of the new member
states: Amato and Gerlach (2002), Siklos and Abel (2002), Jonas and
Mishkin (2003), Golineli and Rovelli (2005), Orlowski (2004, 2005) and
Orlowski and Rybinski (2006).
(4) See Schaechter et al. (2000), Jonas and Mishkin (2003) and
Carare et al. (2002) for a discussion of requirements for a successful
IT regime.
(5) For an analysis of the role of exchange rate movements and in
particular of external shocks on inflation dynamics, see Akyurek (1999).
(6) The gross debt ratio increased from 63% at end-2000 to 101% by
end-2001, as the share of floating rate notes and foreign exchange
denominated and linked debt in total domestic bonds reached 75%.
(7) During the first half of 2002, the IMF programme was on hold
and at the same time the US had offered Turkey a financial package that
could have provided in excess of US$30 billion in return for passing a
parliamentary motion allowing US troops' entry to Iraq through
Turkey. The rejection of the motion came as a big surprise and caused
extreme volatility in the Turkish markets.
(8) Sharp increases in the primary surplus were achieved by
increases in indirect taxation and cutting investments in the past
during difficult economic times. Yet, fiscal discipline unraveled
shortly after conditions stabilised, as challenging reforms regarding
taxes and social security were never completed, which were also a part
of the ongoing IMF programme at the time IIT was introduced. It was
important for the CBT to be able to disentangle temporary from permanent
influences on the budget balance in order to gauge the medium-term
orientation of fiscal policy.
(9) The costs of recapitalising public sector and private sector
banks were approximately 15% of GDP for each, as the total reached 35%.
(10) Major improvements included the incorporation of market risks
in capital adequacy calculations, imposing strict limits on newly
defined related-party lendings, setting of new rules and supervisiory
practices to limit/control foreign exchange exposure, implementation of
new provisioning rules and limits on non-financial participations.
(11) Short foreign exchange positions of the banking sector
declined significantly from US$15 billion in 2000 to US$0.6 billion in
2002.
(12) Major takeovers/mergers involved big European names such as
Unicredito of Italy (50% of Koc Financial Services), Fortis of Belgium
(100% of Disbank), BNP paribas of France (50% of Turkiye Ekonomi
Bankasi) and Rabobank of Netherlands (36.5% of Seker Bank) as well as
USA-based GE Consumer finance (26% of Garanti Bank).
(13) Inflation targets for year-end 2006, 2007 and 2008 were set at
5%, 4% and 4%, respectively, with the year-end target for 2009 also kept
at 4%.
(14) In this type of set up, the main role of the NIR floor is to
indicate whether the programme is likely to achieve its external
objective, while the ceiling on NDA seeks to ensure that this objective
is not jeopardised by excessive credit expansion and sterilised
intervention (Blejer et al., 2001).
(15) This change seems to have led to the need to adapt different
monetary conditionality to take into account the specific features of
the full-fledged IT framework. Accordingly, an inner and an outer
tolerance band is established around the central target path for
conditionality purposes. The former is 1% and if it is breached (at
quarter-end or year-end), this will require an informal consultation
with the IMF on policy response. The outer band is 2% around the central
path and if it is breached there will be a formal review of policies by
the IMF Board.
(16) The IT regime has an advantage such that a stable relationship
between money and inflation is not critical to its success. The strategy
does not depend on such a relationship, but instead uses all available
information to determine the best settings for the instruments of
monetary policy.
(17) Note that [phi] = 1/([alpha][beta]) and [chi] = (1 +
[lambda])/[beta].
(18) A value of zero to [chi] would correspond to a strict IT
regime.
(19) The starting point of the derivation of open economy equations
is the interest parity condition: [e.sub.t] = E([e.sub.t+1]) = [r.sub.t]
- r' + [V.sub.t], where E is an expectations operator and r'
and [V.sub.t] are foreign interest rate and pure portfolio disturbances
(Eichengreen, 2002).
(20) Likewise the adjustment in the policy rate to a given output
gap would be smaller, the more sensitive aggregate demand is to interest
rate changes and the weaker is the level of persistence in output.
(21) Eichengreen (2002) also argues that liability dollarisation
may lead to an extreme case where balance sheet effects are so large
that [delta] turns (-) and [delta] > [beta]. When the exchange rate
depreciates by a large amount the balance sheet effects may dominate,
but when it depreciates by a small amount the favorable competitiveness
effects may dominate. In other words, for a range of depreciations, the
weakening in the domestic currency may have an expansionary affect on
output whereas depreciations above a threshold may lead to contraction
in output. The latter case occurs when the sharp depreciation does
little to enhance competitiveness because of the speed with which it is
passed through to inflation. So if the exchange rate weakens
sufficiently the CB will react strongly to bring back the currency and
avoid severe balance sheet effects on banks and non-banks. If the
depreciation is mild then the response will be mild as well where the CB
will allow the exchange rate to adjust to a new long-run equilibrium.
(22) Cabellero and Krishnamurthy (2003) argue that the central bank
could target inflation in non-tradables. The advantage of this is that
it prevents the central bank from giving excessive attention to the
exchange rate on inflation in the short-term, and it enables the central
bank to pay due attention to inflation in the medium term and
countercyclical monetary policy. Another policy option is to introduce
escape clauses to the IT framework allowing for the target to be amended
in the face of shocks to the exchange rate.
(23) See Borensztein and De Gregorio (1999), Goldfajn and Werleng
(2000), Schmidt-Hebbel and Tapia (2002).
(24) See for example Nogueira (2006) and Choudhri and Hakura
(2006).
(25) They model the sudden stop as a tightening of international
financial constraints.
(26) There were significant delays in completion of IMF programme
reviews during 2002-2006.
(27) Real rates are obtained by deflating nominal overnight policy
rates by 12-month forward-looking inflation expectations based on
CBT's survey among private sector economists. Monthly output gap
values were derived from quarterly figures provided by the CBT using a
quadratic matching of the average.
(28) Although we thank an anonymous referee for pointing out that
the fact that the risk premium could change in response to inflation,
output and exchange rate developments, these factors may have still
affected policy rate decisions.
(29) See Saatcioglu and Korap (2006) for a comprehensive review of
the literature on Turkish inflation.
(30) See for example Leigh and Rossi (2002).
(31) For example pass-through after 12 months corresponds to the
ratio of the cumulative impulse responses of inflation to cumulative
impulse responses of depreciation during the 12 periods following the
exchange rate shock. This methodology, based on McCarthy (1999), has
been widely used and was also the approach adopted by the CBT research
department.
(32) Our results are similar to those of the CBT (see Kara and
Ogunc, 2004).
(33) Since the State Institute of Statistics does not report a
tradable and non-tradable breakdown of the CPI index, we used our own
estimates.
(34) Our findings are similar to those of Kara et al. (2007) in
terms of the change in the dynamics of pass-through for the overall CPI
index as well as for its tradable and non-tradable components.
(35) The proper measurement, the aggregate effective currency
mismatch, as defined by and presented in Goldstein and Turner (2004),
shows that mismatches have peaked in Turkey in 2002 (page 50).
(36) Schmidt-Hebbel and Werner (2002) show that countries may
exhibit a temporary fear of floating during particular periods or
events.
CEM AKYUREK (1) & ALI M KUTAN (2)
(1) Istanbul, Turkey. E-mail: cemakyurekl@gmail.com
(2) Department of Economics and Finance, Southern Illinois
University Edwardsville, Edwardsville, IL 62026-1102, USA. E-mail:
akutan@siue.edu
Table 1: Estimates of the Central Bank reaction function--equation 6
Dependent variable: REALRATE
Method: Least squares
Sample (adjusted): 2003:04, 2007:06
Included observations: 51 after adjustments
Variable Coefficient Std. error t-Statistic
C 0.03886 0.01187 3.2754
Inflation Gap 0.42715 0.26236 1.6281
Exchange rate Depreciation 0.04403 0.02214 1.9884
Output Gap 0.24680 0.09180 2.6884
Risk Premium (EMBITR) 2.29398 0.38783 5.9150
AR(1) 1.06049 0.15322 6.9215
AR(2) -0.27058 0.14433 -1.8747
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.964445 F-statistic 227.04
Variable Prob.
C 0.002
Inflation Gap 0.111
Exchange rate Depreciation 0.053
Output Gap 0.010
Risk Premium (EMBITR) 0.000
AR(1) 0.000
AR(2) 0.068
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.000