Market-based fiscal discipline under evolving decentralisation: the case of Russian regions (1).
Timofeev, Andrey
INTRODUCTION
There are well-established arguments, both pro and con, on the
matter of subnational borrowing. Debt financing has the potential to
achieve intergenerational fairness by spreading the costs of building
local infra structure over the entire period during which benefits from
this investment occur. At the same time, subnational borrowing can be
abused to shift the costs of local public services to future generations
or other jurisdictions in excess of what would be justified by possible
spillover of benefits. The common solution to this dilemma is to allow
subnational borrowing subject to certain safeguards such as borrowing
limits and explicit hierarchical authorisation for issuing debt. In
countries where subnational governments are free from legislative or
regulatory borrowing constraints by higher-level governments, they
arguably face borrowing constraints imposed by lenders (Lane, 1993).
Capital markets can discipline governments by charging a higher
risk premium as the volume of outstanding debt (explicit borrowing and
payables) becomes too large relative to the expected revenue stream
(Capeci, 1994). At some level of indebtedness the borrower will not be
offered further credit at any interest rate. The economic literature
identifies a number of general conditions for market-based fiscal
discipline to work, the most critical of which is no expectations of a
bailout. The latter is in part determined by intergovernmental arrangements that delineate competences and taxing powers between the
levels of government.
Market-based discipline argument takes on new twists in
transitional countries. On the one hand, at the early stages of
transition a naive faith in the laissez-faire approach favoured
market-based fiscal discipline in those countries. This trend was
reinforced with the political drive for subnational autonomy, which
among other things included borrowing powers. Therefore, many
transitional countries have allowed subnational borrowing under very
liberal regulations. On the other hand, the very conditions that are
crucial for market-based fiscal discipline to work are often lacking in
those countries. Thus, financial markets are often underdeveloped and
lack liquidity. In addition, the institutions of local governance are
immature and thus might not be conducive to fiscal policies responsive
to rising borrowing costs.
For developed economies, empirical studies have documented
market-based discipline in the form of positive relationship between the
level of governments' indebtedness and their cost of borrowing
(Bayoumi et al., 1995; Poterba and Rueben, 2001, for US state bonds;
Capeci, 1994, for New Jersey municipal bonds). Although, the
effectiveness of market-based fiscal discipline is particularly relevant
for transitional economies as explained above, so far it has not been
studied in the context of transition. Our study is the first to examine
the performance of this market mechanism under the evolving institutions
of decentralised governance in a transitional country. There are
conjectures that market-based fiscal discipline might fail in the
context of transition similar to the remarkable failure of coupon
privatisation under the poor institutions of corporate governance in
transitional economies.
The major challenge to an empirical test of market-based discipline
is obtaining a consistent measure of market yields on the credit
obligations of different jurisdictions. We have been able to identify
one debt instrument that was utilised by a majority of Russian regions
under standard conditions. These securities, called agrobonds, were
issued by 69 out of a total of 89 regional governments in 1997-1998 to
convert their outstanding liabilities to the federal government, who
eventually auctioned off these bonds to private investors. We argue that
the agrobonds' yield spread over the federal bond yield reflects
the creditors' assessment of the risk that the issuer would not be
able (or willing) to honor the obligation of servicing its agrobonds.
Over the last decade Russia has shifted from a permissive stance on
subnational borrowing, which solely relied on market-based discipline,
to administrative and rule-based controls on subnational borrowing
(Martinez-Vazquez et al., 2006). This study attempts to shed some light
on whether tightening of borrowing constraints had been warranted by
incomplete decentralisation or whether it only reflects a change of
political fashion.
The rest of this paper is organised as follows. In the next
section, we examine the variation in intergovernmental arrangements
faced by different regions in Russia. In particular we attempt to
identify characteristics of a region that determine availability of a
central government bailout. Section 3 reports the empirical evidence on
the impact of these characteristics on the formation of risk premia by
private lenders. Our conclusions follow.
INTERGOVERNMENTAL FISCAL ARRANGEMENTS IN RUSSIA
Similar to other countries, for the markets to effectively
discipline governments in Russia a number of general conditions must be
in place: free and open markets for credit; availability of information
on the borrowers' accounts; the borrower's ability to promptly
respond to market signals; and no expectations of a bailout. The latter
condition 'appears to be the Achilles' heel of market
discipline' according to policy studies (Lane, 1993). In addition
to weakening the responsiveness of the borrower to market signals, the
low credibility of the no-bailout policy also makes lenders discount the
expected losses, which results in a failure to charge an adequate risk
premium.
Russia has had some problems with each of the aforementioned
conditions for market-based discipline, especially the credibility of
the no-bailout policy (Martinez-Vazquez et al., 2006). However, the
sensitivity of the federal government to local fiscal woes is limited to
specific political concerns, such as wage arrears or disruption of vital
services (eg central heating). The informal influence of subnational
governments over the court system and weak enforcement of court
judgments effectively means that regional government defaults can hardly
lead to the disruption of vital services. At the same time the fact that
in the recent past the federal government itself defaulted on its
domestic bonds reveals its low concern over reputational or financial
spillovers, which often prompt a central government bailout in other
countries. Thus, ex ante the prospects of a federal bailout are
uncertain and to a large extent depend on certain characteristics of a
particular region, which we attempt to identify in this section.
The economic literature suggests that the credibility of the
no-bailout policy is determined by a combination of factors related to
either the central government's pay-off from bailing out a locality
or the local government's costs of inflicting a fiscal crisis on
itself (Inman, 2003). In particular, policy studies suggest that
political costs of a local fiscal crisis (both to the local and central
governments) depend on the relative responsibility of each level of
government stemming from the division of authority in the system of
intergovernmental fiscal relations (Rodden and Eskeland, 2003). Thus,
sustainability of the no-bailout condition is in part determined by
intergovernmental arrangements that delineate competencies and taxing
powers between the levels of government.
For a bailout to occur, political arrangements should be such that
at some point the central government cannot resist the pressure to help
out a locality while the local officials can shift the blame to somebody
else. This can happen when the central government shares responsibility
for the public goods provided at the local level because it provides the
bulk of local government revenue or when local governments do not have
enough autonomy to undertake fiscal adjustments in response to a fiscal
crisis. Voters might hold the central government responsible, because it
has the means to resolve the crisis, unlike the local government, which
may have never be given sufficient tax autonomy or which may have
diverted or wasted all resources by the time of the crisis.
The Russian experience of fiscal reforms presents a typical example
of incomplete and evolving decentralisation. At the start of transition
Russia inherited a huge public sector, responsible for the provision of
major social services including housing, transportation, healthcare, and
education. (2) Trying to balance its fiscal accounts, the central
government shifted the most onerous expenditure responsibilities down to
regional governments (Bahl and Wallich, 1995, p. 347). (3) As
subnational governments had no direct access to the central bank, and
thus could not monetize their deficits, they were expected to accomplish
the politically costly job of fiscal adjustment. This spontaneous
decentralisation resulted in a lack of clearly defined competences of
respective governments in the provision of affected services.
At the same time subnational governments have been given little
revenue-raising authority. Although, regional and local governments may
collect revenues from some taxes authorised by the federal government,
they must fit their bases to the federal law, and may levy rates only
within federal limits. In an average region, about 70% of the regional
government revenues come from federal taxes, either through tax revenue
retention at the point of collection or through redistribution via
intergovernmental fiscal flows (see Table 1). Thus, on the margin,
subnational governments have little capacity to mobilise revenues in
response to a fiscal crisis. Therefore, as hypothesised by von Hagen and
Eichengreen (1996), concentration of taxing authority at the central
level can make the central government ultimately responsible for local
fiscal outcomes.
This being said, we nevertheless should not expect all regional
governments to engage in irresponsible borrowing and eventually be
bailed out by the federal authorities. Indeed, the coefficients of
variation presented in Table 1 reveal significant differences among
regions in the extent of revenue autonomy. The category of
'own-source' revenue encompasses all revenue sources whose
yield can be affected at the margin by regional governments, using their
discretion to determine taxable bases or rates, or discretion to
introduce the tax, or any combination of these three. By exercising this
form of fiscal discretion, regional governments can respond to changes
in the costs of service delivery and economic fluctuations. (4)
Different forms of revenue sharing also have different implications
for the creditworthiness of regional governments. The category of
'assigned sources' of revenue refers to legislated long-term
entitlements to (a share of) the regional yield from tax instruments
over which regional officials have no discretion. (5) The category of
'regulated revenue' has historically referred to tax revenue
sharing determined by the higher-level government as part of its annual
budget process. However, since 1994, tax-sharing rates have been de
facto standardised across regions and thus the regulated tax revenue
effectively became akin to assigned revenue. The only discretion that
subnational governments have with respect to the assigned revenue
sources is deferring tax payments or offsetting tax liabilities with
government payables. Although assigned revenue cannot be affected on the
margin by regional governments, it possesses intertemporal
predictability. This feature of assigned revenues helps regional
governments to better budget and plan for future obligations and
projects.
The final category, grants, is comprised of all intergovernmental
transfers to regional governments whether formula-based or completely
discretionary. Of course, these sources of revenue bring the least
revenue autonomy to regional governments. (6) Figure 1 shows the growing
importance of non-discretionary grants (equalisation grants,
subventions, subsidies) in the total composition of federal transfers to
regional governments. As can be seen from Figure 1, the share of
non-discretionary grants in total federal transfers increased from 60%
in 1995 to over 70% in 1999. (7) The remaining share is mostly accounted
for by 'mutual settlements', which are typically not budgeted
ex ante, but rather result ex post from emergency situations and
political lobbying (Martinez-Vazquez and Boex, 2001). The relative
decline of mutual settlements over time is an indication of improvements
in the objectivity, stability and predictability of the federal-regional
transfer system.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
In summary, the Russian system of intergovernmental relations
affects the credibility of the no-bailout policy. The unclear division
of responsibilities between the levels of government, both in the
legislation and voters' minds, makes the central government
partially responsible for local fiscal outcomes. Furthermore, the
centralisation of taxing authority at the federal level weakens the
credibility of the central government's no-bailout commitment
because the central government is both sensitive to local fiscal woes
and possesses the means for rescuing troubled jurisdictions. Moreover,
different regions seem to face different prospects of a federal bailout
due to a wide variation in their characteristics that determine the
availability of a federal bailout.
Thus, there is a wide variation among regions in their reliance on
'own-source' revenue and the incidence of ad hoc transfers
from the federal government. It can be argued that regions with a
smaller yield of their own sources of revenue are more likely to be
bailed out because they lack flexibility for fiscal adjustment. In
addition, regions receiving larger ad hoc transfers are more likely to
be bailed out because the fiscal outcomes in these regions are
presumably of higher concern for the federal government.
TESTING MARKET-BASED FISCAL DISCIPLINE HYPOTHESIS
The ultimate effectiveness of market-based fiscal discipline in
Russia would manifest itself in sustainable volumes of debt accumulated
by regional governments. This seems to be the case in most of Russian
regions according to estimates reported in various studies (for a
survey, see Martinez-Vazquez et al., 2006). The official figures, which
became available only after the Budget Code of 2000 had required
subnational governments to maintain debt ledgers, indicate that the
total amount of explicit subnational debt has been below 5% of GDP. This
is around one-third of the annual pre-transfer revenues of regional and
local governments. Implicit debt, such as government guarantees and
overdue payables, accounted for additional 2%-3% of GDP (this should
also include extra-budgetary borrowing guaranteed by the government).
(8) Thus, by all estimates, Russia's subnational debt falls below
the levels observed in many other countries. (9)
While the average subnational debt has been rather low, several of
Russia's regions have accumulated a stock of debt significantly
exceeding the amount of their annual revenues. An extreme example is in
the Republic of Tyva, where the stock of explicit debt exceeds
pre-transfer revenue by a factor of five. Given that the maturity of
debt that can be accommodated by the Russian credit markets is rather
short, such debt-to-revenue ratios are hardly sustainable. For policy
applications, it would be interesting to determine which component of
the market mechanism failed in those regions. That is, it would be
useful to see whether the markets failed to send corrective signals to
the governments, or the regional governments failed to respond to these
signals. Furthermore, it would be of practical interest to determine
whether the cause of this failure lies in the design of
intergovernmental arrangements.
Empirical Strategy and Testable Hypotheses
Our goal is to determine whether intergovernmental arrangements
indeed interfere with the fiscal discipline imposed on regional
governments by credit markets in Russia. Following previous studies, the
risk premium on regional debt may be approximated with the following
linear function: (10)
[[pi].sub.j] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[beta].sub.j] +
[[alpha].sub.2][[sigma].sub.j] + [X'.sub.j][beta] + [u.sub.j] (1)
where j indexes jurisdictions; b stands for the volume of
outstanding debt normalised by the amount of recurrent revenues; [sigma]
is the intergovernmental parameter signaling the probability of the
central government bailout in the case of local government insolvency;
[X.sub.i] is a vector of factors positively affecting the ratio of the
fiscal surplus to the amount of recurrent revenues; and [u.sub.i] is the
error term. The predictions are that [[alpha].sub.1] > 0, while
[[alpha].sub.2], [[beta].sub.k] < 0. That is, higher levels of
bailout signal [sigma] observed for the given jurisdiction at the time
of lending result in lower risk premia charged by lenders.
Measuring the Risk Premia
The major challenge to an empirical test of market-based fiscal
discipline is obtaining a consistent measure of market yields on the
credit obligations of different jurisdictions. Although the bulk of
regional debt in Russia is in the form of commercial lending, it is
dominated by bank loans. Unlike for publicly traded securities,
information on interest rates charged by banks is not publicly
available. Fortunately, there is one debt instrument that was utilised
by a majority of Russian regions under standard conditions (see the
Annex for details). These securities, called agrobonds, were issued by
69 regional governments in 1997-1998 as a means to cover their
guarantees on the commodity credits provided by the federal government
to local agricultural producers in 1996. As Russian farmers conceived
government credits as another form of subsidy, not many of them intended
to repay the credits and thus regional government guarantees became due.
Nine regions opted for paying off the guaranteed credit upfront, but the
majority converted it into securities hoping that the federal government
would not press too hard for repayment. However, the federal government
auctioned off these bonds on the private market, which had had a 4-year
experience with trading federal bonds (GKOs) totaling USD 32 billion.
Each region made three agrobond issues of equal size: of 1-, 2-,
and 3-year maturity. All bonds had the same nominal value (RUR 10
thousand) and an annual coupon of 10%. On 20 June 1997, the federal
government started offering agrobonds of different regions along with
the minimum prices during special auction sessions at the Moscow
Interbank Currency Exchange. (11) As can be seen from Figure 2, at the
beginning the minimum prices set by the federal government for agrobonds
of different regions were very close so that the associated yield
ceilings clustered around the value of 6% points over the federal
bonds' yield. (12) As a result, for the most creditworthy regions
the entire issue was sold during one trading day while for others no
bids exceeded the initial minimum prices. Figure 2 reveals how the
federal government eventually had to lower the minimum prices (and thus
raise yield ceilings) trying to sell some of the least demanded
agrobonds. The federal government followed the same pricing strategy for
most of the regions--daily incrementing the yield ceiling until it hit
the market valuation. (13) It took on average 12 trading days for the
yield ceiling to increase from the level of 6% points to 10% points over
the GKO yield.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
At the end, agrobonds of 26 regions were completely sold out and
those of additional 31 regions were partially sold at the auctions. Out
of almost RUR 7 billion (USD 1.2 billion) in agrobonds, roughly
one-third of the agrobonds ended up held by foreigners, with another
one-third held by Russia's largest banks and investment firms,
while the federal government held the remaining unsold agrobonds
(S&P, 2003). Thus, for 12 regions, agrobonds were not demanded under
the imposed yield ceilings (going as high as 18% points over the federal
bond yield).
Our strategy is to use the information on the discount rates at
which agrobonds of a particular region were sold in auctions to
approximate the default premium that this regional government would face
in the credit market at that time. (14) We argue that the yield spread
over the federal bond yield reflects the lenders' assessment of the
risk that the issuer would not be able (or willing) to honor the
obligation of servicing its agrobonds. Thus, our dependent variable is
the agrobond yield spread averaged across all trading days in proportion
to the fraction of this agrobond issue sold on each day. For the issues
that did not register a single trade we only know that the market yield
was above the ceiling imposed by the federal government. For such
regions we set the dependent variable equal to the maximum yield ceiling
that creditors were offered. (15) Thus, our dependent variable is
essentially censored from above. Moreover, the censoring limits vary by
region. This is because auction purchases stopped in the fall of 1997 as
the world financial crisis hit the Russian market. This means that for
those regions that issued their agrobonds late in August 1997, the
federal government did not have enough time to complete the gradual
incrementing of the yield ceilings to the clearing levels. (16)
We perform our empirical analysis on the sample of 1-year
agrobonds--the largest sample (52 regions including 19 limit
observation) out of the three maturities in our data set. (17) We have
to acknowledge a sample selection problem due to several factors. First
of all, 10 regions did not have any liabilities on the federal credits
to be converted into agrobonds (eg cities of Moscow and St Petersburg).
Second, nine regions opted for paying off the guaranteed credit upfront
rather than converting it into securities. Finally, 16 regions issued
their agrobonds after September 1997 and thus are not covered by our
data set of the auction results. These 16 cases include both wealthy
regions such as Nizhny Novgord and poor ones such as Dagestan. Thus, for
eight of these 16 regions agrobonds were completely sold out by May
1998, while for the other eight regions the leftovers remained in
federal ownership. Overall, we cannot see any pattern in the selection
of our sample, and do not expect the sample selection to bias our
results one way or another.
The auction results imply that on average investors felt that a
Tambov Region agrobond should have a market yield only 5.05% points
above the federal bond yield, while a Rhakasia Republic agrobond should
bear a yield 14.55% points higher than the federal bond. For those
regions whose agrobonds were at least partially sold at the auctions,
the mean spread over the federal bond yield was 8.39% points, with a
standard deviation of 2.35% points.
Measures of Indebtedness
The other major data requirement for this study is a measure of
regions' indebtedness. The first official figures on the volume of
outstanding explicit debt appeared in 2000 regional budget reports
prepared in accord with the new Budget Code. The reported debt stock is
broken down into commercial loans and intergovernmental loans. Before
year 2000, budgetary reports had quoted only the annual flow of deficit
financing broken down into detailed subcategories. Therefore, we
construct the January 1997 stock of outstanding debt by subtracting the
flows of deficit financing accumulated in the past from the recent
figures on outstanding debt stock. (18)
To derive the measure of the relative size of debt, the nominal
debt numbers are divided by the amount of a region's recurrent
revenues (that is, total revenue excluding ad hoc grants). In our
sample, the average relative debt is about 133%, half of which is
accounted for by commercial lending. The standard deviation is 106%. The
coefficient of correlation between commercial debt and intergovernmental
loans is negative (-0.25). The Republic of Sakha, with the largest
explicit debt, had a market yield of 9.17% points above the federal bond
yield, which is 1% point higher than the average for the regions whose
agrobonds were (partially) sold at the auctions. By contrast, Tambov
Region, whose agrobonds were sold at the smallest yield spread, had
relative debt of slightly above 50%, which is almost half of the average
indebtedness. On the other hand, Khakasia Republic, whose agrobonds were
sold at the largest yield spread, had relative debt around 36%of its
recurrent revenues--only a quarter of the average indebtedness. Thus,
the relation between indebtedness and interest rates is not
straightforward and in fact can be part of multivariate relations.
Nevertheless, we can note that the average indebtedness of those regions
whose agrobonds were not demanded at the auctions was 30% points higher
than the average indebtedness of other regions.
In addition to explicit borrowings, regional government liabilities
also include overdue payables to employees and suppliers. For 1997, we
have consolidated regional-local figures on overdue payables, which are
broken down into salaries and payroll charges, transfers to population,
and utility bills. (19) Relative to the regional government recurrent
revenues, the total amount of regional-local budget arrears is not
high--about 31%. This ratio is somewhat higher in regions whose
agrobonds did not sell at the auctions--about 43%. Moreover budget
arrears are weakly correlated with explicit debt: the coefficient of
correlation is only 0.29.
Given the indirect way of measuring 1997 stock of outstanding debt,
we also include an alternative measure of indebtedness: interest
payments relative to the recurrent revenues in 1997. The coefficient of
correlation between commercial debt and interest payments is 0.35. As a
ratio to the regional government recurrent revenues, the average
interest burden is about 1.26%, with the standard deviation of 2.17%.
The average interest burden of those regions whose agrobonds did not
sell at the auctions is only half of that for other regions. This could
be indicative of either less borrowing or poorer payment discipline.
Bailout Signals
We use three complementary signals for the probability that the
central government would provide a bailout if a regional government
becomes insolvent. As pointed out by yon Hagen and Eichengreen (1996),
the lack of revenue autonomy of subnational governments limits their
ability to cope with a fiscal crisis on their own. These scholars argue
that, given the inability of regional governments to undertake fiscal
adjustment, the central government commitment to the no-bailout policy
would not be rendered credible by lenders. Based on this argument, we
use the share of 'own-source' revenue in the total revenue of
the regional government as a signal for the probability that the central
government would bail out this region. (20)
Our second signal for the availability of a bailout to the
jurisdiction is its share in the national population. Wildasin (1997)
predicts that availability of a bailout is negatively related to the
fragmentation of local jurisdictions because externalities from
discontinuation of local services are likely to be positively related to
the locality's size. Moreover, his calculations provide at least
one class of examples where there is a clear inverse relationship between jurisdiction size and availability of bailout. (21) At the same
time larger localities are less likely to induce a debt crisis because
they bear a larger share of the national government costs of a bailout
(Goodspeed, 2002). In our sample, the average share of a region in the
national population is 0.95 %, with a standard deviation of 0.76%. For
those regions whose agrobonds did not sell at the auctions, the average
population share is less than half of the other regions' average.
Finally, we use transfer dependence of regional governments as our
third proxy for the availability of a bailout to the jurisdiction. Using
Wildasin's (1997) framework, it can be shown that the amount of
matching grants received by a jurisdiction reflects its
spillover-generating capabilities and thus the central government's
concern about the jurisdiction's fiscal outcome. We can also make
an informal argument that, beyond matching grants, non-budgeted
discretionary grants received by a region represent its political clout
in the national capital. Even when the transfer size does not reflect
the region's fiscal position but its bargaining power, the latter
can be potentially utilised by the region to negotiate a bailout should
a fiscal crisis occur. Thus, within Wildasin's framework, a larger
transfer to a jurisdiction can signal to creditors a higher willingness
of the central government to bailout a given jurisdiction.
However, in Russia not all grants are driven by the federal
government's political concerns. As shown in Section 2, two-thirds
of federal grants are accounted for by equalisation transfers, which are
allocated based on the need/capacity formula. Indeed, the coefficient of
correlation between the 'own-source' revenue yield and
transfer dependence is 0.88. However, the share of discretionary (ad
hoc) grants in the total amount of federal transfers received by a
region is likely to better capture political favours of the federal
government. Plainly, the discretionary component of transfers might in
fact represent a bailout targeting distressed regions. The coefficient
of correlation between the share of discretionary (ad hoc) grants and
"own-source' revenue yield is 0.33.
For those regions whose agrobonds did not sell at the auctions, the
average share of 'own-source' revenue in their total revenue
was less than half of that observed in other regions. Also, in the
regions with unsold agrobonds, the average share of discretionary grants
in the total amount of federal transfers is only two-thirds of the share
observed in the other regions. The 'own-source' revenue yield
is negatively correlated with budget arrears on wages and social
benefits (with a correlation coefficient of -0.3).
Econometric Issues
Given that the dependent variable is censored, OLS is an
inappropriate technique for the estimation because it produces biased
estimates. Compared to the most common alternative technique, MLE, OLS
estimates are smaller in absolute value. (22) However, given that OLS
coefficient estimates are not affected by other likely econometric
issues, such as heteroskedasticity and non-normality, it can serve as a
benchmark for evaluating estimates produced by alternative techniques.
By contrast, for the Tobit model, a standard MLE technique to estimate
equations with censored dependent variables, the consistency hinges on
the assumption of normally distributed and homoskedastic errors.
Moreover, some simulation evidence suggests that heteroskedasticity
causes greater bias in maximum likelihood estimation than non-normality
(eg Powell, 1986). To address this issue we estimate a Tobit model
allowing multiplicative heteroskedasticity in the form of
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.i] = [[sigma].sup.2]exp(2[gamma][z.sub.i]), where
[z.sub.i] is the region i's share in the federal tax base.
By regressing regional governments' costs of borrowing on
their levels of indebtedness along with other regional characteristics,
we assess the effectiveness of the supply side of the market mechanism.
That is, we check whether credit markets indeed send corrective signals
to borrowers. However, there is a reverse causality from the costs of
borrowing to government demand for credit. In non-censored models, in
order to eliminate the endogeneity bias, we would have to instrument
regional governments' demand for credit with some exogenous variables. That is, we would have to find variables that affect regional
governments' costs of borrowing only through the default risk
stemming from the level of indebtedness. Any discrepancy in estimates
obtained with instrumented and non-instrumented regressions would
indicate some responsiveness of subnational borrowing to rising interest
rates.
Unfortunately, in limited dependent variables models, it is very
difficult to deal with endogeneity. Unless strong assumptions are made
on the exact relationship between the endogenous regressors and the
instruments, it is generally not possible to apply instrumental variable
techniques. Thus, our strategy is to include the endogenous level of
debt among our explanatory variables hoping that the endogeneity would
not bias coefficient estimates for variables other than the debt level.
Apart from the endogeneity, the estimation procedure is further
complicated with censoring limits varying by region. Indeed, we observe
risk premia resulting from the auction only if they fit the maximum
allowed yield spread as determined by the minimum price set by the
federal government for a particular agrobond issue on that particular
day. Unfortunately, many censored models (such as semiparametric
censored models) assume a uniform censoring threshold. (23) Therefore,
our primary technique is Tobit with multiplicative heteroskedasticity,
which allows for varying censoring limits.
Estimation Results
As we do not have many observations, we have to be parsimonious about the number of regressors included. Many of our variables are
correlated between each other, which results in insignificant estimates
of individual impacts when these variables are jointly included in the
regression. Figure 3 shows the statistical relations among our variables
in the form of a principal component biplot chart. (24) The biplot
display is a commonly used multivariate method for graphing row and
column elements (in this case, regions and their characteristics
correspondingly) using a single display (Gabriel, 1971). The rays
originating from the center of the graph are linear projections of our
variables onto the two-dimensional space defined by the two principal
components--two largest eigenvalues of our data set. Thus, most
variability in the original multidimensional data set occurs in the
chosen two-dimensional space. Variable rays representing uncorrelated
variables are orthogonal. The smaller the inner angle between rays, the
higher is the positive correlation between the values of the
corresponding variables. For negatively correlated variables, the inner
angle is greater than 90[degrees]. Longer rays represent variables with
larger standard deviations.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The goodness of fit of our two-dimensional projection, defined as
the fraction of the sum of squares of singular values accounted for by
the two largest singular values, is 0.476. Using the above stated rule
of thumb for interpreting a biplot chart, we can conclude that the share
of 'own-source' revenue, per capita revenue relative to the
subsistence level, the share of ad hoc grants, and population size are
positively correlated. In addition, transfer dependence of regions is
almost perfectly correlated to the share of 'own-source'
revenue with a negative sign. Therefore, while including in the
regression equation only those among the related variables whose
coefficient estimates have the highest statistical significance, we
should remember that these estimates also capture the effect of other
related variables.
Thus, the share of 'own-source' revenue is not included
in the final regression because of being statistically insignificant
when included jointly with per capita revenues. Similarly, none of the
different types of implicit liabilities are included in the presented
regressions as they were not statistically significant in any of the
employed specifications. Out of various control variables suggested in
earlier studies (per capita revenue, unemployment, volume of the bond
issue), our final regressions include only the per capita amount of
pre-transfer revenues adjusted for the regional subsistence level.
The biplot chart also suggests that the yield spread has only
little positive correlation with the stock of commercial debt and the
burden of debt service. Also, the yield spread has only little negative
correlation with intergovernmental loans and social arrears. Thus unless
the statistical relations change in a multivariate setup, we can expect
some of our proposed regressors to have little explanatory power for the
yield spread. Note however a strong correlation between outstanding debt
and outlays on debt service, which provides us some comfort regarding
the indirect way of measuring debt. Later in this section we will use
the biplot chart again to identify clusters of similar regions.
The second column of Table 2 reports estimation of Eq. (1) by means
of OLS with White's standard errors. The impact of the commercial
debt stock--measured relative to the annual recurrent revenue--is not
statistically significant. Interest expenditures relative to the annual
recurrent revenue are positively related to the yield spread and this
relation is statistically significant at the 10% level. Adjusted per
capita revenue has a negative coefficient, which is statistically
significant at the 10 % level The other bailout signals--the share of
the discretionary grants in the total grants received and the
region's share in the national population--have no statistical
impact on the yield spread.
The fourth column of Table 2 reports the results of estimating Eq.
(1) using the homoskedastic Tobit model. This estimation produces
10%-significant coefficients only for population size and per capita
revenue. (25) Both coefficients are negative, which is consistent with
our arguments regarding the bailout availability in the first case and
observed capacity to generate a fiscal surplus in the latter case. The
results of the heteroskedastic Tobit estimation are reported in the last
column of Table 2. In addition to the negative coefficients for the
population size and per capita revenue, the heteroskedastic Tobit also
produces 10%-significant coefficients for the commercial debt and
discretionary grants. However, the signs of these coefficients--negative
and positive correspondingly--are counter to our predictions.
For the purpose of comparability, we also re-estimated the linear
regression under the assumption of multiplicative heteroskedasticity
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.i] = [[sigma].sup.2]exp(2[gamma][z.sub.i]) and
presented the results in the third column of Table 2. The results are
roughly consistent with those from the heteroskedastic Tobit except that
the positive coefficient of the interest expenditures becomes
statistically significant at the 1% level. Note that in accordance with
common wisdom, the Tobit model produces larger estimates in absolute
value than the linear regression.
Overall, the econometric results do not provide a clear-cut answer
regarding the causalities between the indebtedness and interest costs.
The negative coefficient on the commercial debt can be due to the
reverse causality from lower interest rates to larger borrowing.
Similarly, while representing past borrowings, the current interest
payments can be affected by reverse causality from the current default
premia in the case of autocorrelation exhibited by the latter.
There is however more clarity in our results on the bailout
signals, which is the focus of this study. According to our results,
lenders do not see ad hoc grants as a reason to discount risks of a
possible default. Instead, lenders seem to favour large and affluent
regions. This general pattern can be also seen from the biplot chart
(Figure 3). The individual points in the chart are linear projections of
our observations labeled with corresponding region codes. As the
variables are standardised by subtracting the mean and dividing by the
standard deviation, data points located in the center of the graph
represent regions with average values of the variables. Data points
located away from the center in the direction of some variable ray
represent regions with values of that variable that are distinct from
the average.
We can identify two clusters of observations on the chart. The
first, larger cluster represents regions with higher dependence on
federal transfers, larger amounts of overdue utility bills and larger
yield spreads on agrobonds. Note that the most troublesome region
(Republic of Tyva, code 70) protrudes the furthest from the average
along the yield spread ray on the biplot graph. The second, smaller
cluster gathers regions with a larger share of own-source revenue,
larger per capita revenue relative to the subsistence level, and also a
larger share of discretionary grants in total federal transfers. These
latter regions also happen to have larger population.
In summary, we seem to detect that larger and wealthier regions
receive more grants in the ad hoc form and undertake more borrowing at
smaller interest rates and as a result incur more interest expenditures
relative to their recurrent revenue. Moreover, after we control for the
size and revenue capacity, we detect a positive relation of the yield
spread to interest expenditures and ad hoc grants. This pattern is
compatible with some of our predictions but runs counter to others. The
results call for further testing when better data become available.
CONCLUSIONS
In theory, credit markets can potentially correct irresponsible
fiscal behaviour by charging adequate risk premia or excluding a
profligate jurisdiction from further borrowing altogether. However, to
be effective in a particular country, market forces require several
general conditions to be present in its system of intergovernmental
fiscal arrangements. This study evaluates the impact of
intergovernmental arrangements on the performance of market-based fiscal
discipline in Russia. To our knowledge, this is the first test of
market-based fiscal discipline on data from a transitional country.
Although some caution should be taken due to the limitations of the
available data, certain conclusions can be drawn from the results.
The impact of intergovernmental factors on the formation of risk
premia by the credit markets seems to go beyond the prospects of a
bailout. In fact, a greater revenue sufficiency of regional governments
appears to lower their costs of borrowing. This is consistent with other
studies finding a positive relation of the borrowing costs to transfer
dependence (Capeci, 1994) and a negative relation to the revenue base
(Capeci, 1994) and primary surplus (Caselli et al., 1998). This is
despite the fact that debt is measured relative to the revenue base and
thus the latter should not matter for risk assessment. Thus, it appears
that creditors favour wealthier jurisdictions notwithstanding their debt
burden.
One can argue that larger revenue autonomy is interpreted by the
lenders as the ability of the borrower to undertake a revenue-raising
effort and generate fiscal surplus sufficient for the repayment of the
debt. Thus, although relatively large revenue autonomy makes a federal
bailout less likely for such a region, the lenders might still favour
this borrower because he is less likely to become insolvent in the first
place.
While the negative relation between a region's size and its
borrowing costs detected in this study can be indicative of the bailout
prospect ('too big to fail'), it can also be explained with
the fact that larger regions tend to be wealthier and thus have better
ability to pay. (26) This is also consistent with the observation by
Petersen and Huertes (2003) stating that 'in the absence of
information and experience, the 'name' and size of a
subnational government have had disproportionate importance'.
Overall, we can conclude that even if the intergovernmental factors had
some effect on the formation of risk premia, it was too weak to override
the low creditworthiness of poorer regions.
The major policy implication of this study is that incomplete
decentralisation in Russia did not justify suppression of the market
discipline with administrative controls. Even when intergovernmental
arrangements suggested possibility of a bailout, lenders chose not to
count on such a possibility and denied credit to those regions. It
appears that rather than constraining market borrowing, the central
government needs to commit itself to limit intergovernmental loans
provided to those less creditworthy regions. Indeed, we find that
commercial debt has almost perfect negative correlation with
intergovernmental loans. Moreover, we uncover the strategy that allows
regional governments to obtain intergovernmental loans. We see that
intergovernmental loans are closely correlated with arrears on wages and
social payments such as stipends.
This study also suggests that larger regions might require more
stringent hierarchical supervision because lenders seem to discount
default risks for such regions compared to smaller regions with a
similar level of indebtedness.
Annex
Agrobonds
Agrobond securities were issued by 69 regional governments during
19971998 as a means to cover regional guarantees on commodity credits
provided by the federal government to local agricultural producers in
1996. As Russian farmers viewed government credits as another form of
subsidy, not many of them intended to repay the credits and thus
regional government guarantees became due. Some regions opted for paying
to the federal government upfront the credits that they had guaranteed,
but the majority converted it into securities hoping that the federal
government would not press too hard for payment. However, the federal
government auctioned off these bonds to private investors, at a discount
of about 20%. Out of almost RUR 7 billion in agrobonds, roughly
one-third ended up held by foreigners, with another one-third held by
Russia's largest banks and investment firms and the rest (unsold)
held by the federal government.
Each region made three agrobond issues of equal size: 1-year,
2-year, and 3-year bonds. The bonds were not collateralised but
unconditionally secured with all the assets of the borrower. All bonds
had the same nominal value (RUR 10,000) and an annual (or two
semiannual) coupon of 10%. It follows from this that all issues of
agrobonds should have been redeemed by June 2001. However, by December
2001 only 42 regions had paid off the principal and the interest on the
1-year issue. Moreover, only 27 regions paid off the principal and both
coupons of the 2-year issue. As for the 3-year issue, only 24 regions
paid the principal and all three coupons. Twelve regions did not make a
single payment on any of the agrobond issues.
In July 1998, agrobond holders complained to federal authorities
about the regional governments' delay in payments. In response, the
federal Ministry of Finance declined to intervene, citing the budget
autonomy of regions. The only concession made by the federal government
on the issue was easing the regions' debt burden by restructuring
regional liabilities on the portion of agrobonds that remained in
federal ownership.
With the exception of the Karachayevo-Circassian Republic, none of
the 12 regions whose agrobonds failed to find buyers at the auctions and
thus remained completely in federal ownership have made a single payment
on these liabilities. The Karachayevo-Circassian Republic presents an
exception as the liabilities of its agrobonds were offset against
special federal budget appropriations for drought aid to the Republic in
1998.
Out of 26 regions whose securities were completely sold out at the
auctions, only 18 had cleared them all by December 2001. Many regions
whose agrobonds were partially sold in 1997 have cleared the securities
held by private investors while refusing to service the portion held by
the federal government. This can be explained in part by the fact that
some law firms buy defaulted agrobonds for pennies on the secondary
market and aggressively seek settlement through courts with varying
degrees of success. In addition, regional governments' debtors
often buy agrobonds at a significant discount to pay off their debt to
regions at face value. It should be mentioned that the ruble devaluation of 1998 significantly reduced the real value of agrobonds.
REFERENCES
Bahl, RW and Wallich, CI. 1995: Intergovernmental fiscal relations
in the Russian federation. In: Bird, RM, Ebel, RD and Wallich, CI.
(eds). Decentralization of the Socialist State: Intergovernmental
Finance in Transition Economies. Regional and Sectoral Studies. World
Bank: Washington, DC.
Bayoumi, T, Goldstein, M and Woglom, G. 1995: Do credit markets
discipline sovereign borrowers? Evidence from US states. Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking 27: 1046-1059.
Capeci, J. 1994: Local fiscal policies, default risk, and municipal
borrowing costs. Journal of Public Economics 53(1): 73-89.
Caselli, F, Giovannini, A and Lane, T. 1998: Fiscal discipline and
the cost of public debt service: Some estimates for OECD countries.
International Monetary Fund Working Paper WP/98/55.
Gabriel, KR. 1971: The biplot graphic display of matrices with
application to principal component analysis. Biometrika 58: 453-467.
Goodspeed, TJ. 2002: Bailouts in a federation. International Tax
and Public Finance 9: 409-421.
Greene, WH. 1999: Econometric Analysis. 4th Edition. Prentice-Hall:
New York.
Inman, RP. 2003: Transfers and bailouts: Enforcing local fiscal
discipline with lessons from US federalism. In: Rodden, J, Eskeland, G
and Litvack, J. (eds). Fiscal Decentralization and the Challenge of Hard
Budget Constraints. MIT Press: Cambridge and London.
Lane, TD. 1993: Market discipline. International Monetary Fund
Staff Papers 40(1): 53-88.
Lipkovich, I and Smith, EP. 2002: Biplot and singular value
decomposition Macros for Excel[C]. Journal of Statistical Software 7: 5.
Martinez-Vazquez, J and Boex, JLF. 2001: Russia's Transition
to a New Federalism. WBI Learning Resources Series. The World Bank:
Washington, DC.
Martinez-Vazquez, J, Timofeev, A and Boex, JLF. 2006: Reforming
Regional-Local Finance in Russia. WBI Learning Resources Series, The
World Bank: Washington, DC.
Myazina, E. 2005: Renewed interest in regions. Vedomosti. 29 April
2005.
OECD. 1999: Revenue Statistics: 1965-1998: Special Features, Taxing
Powers of State and Local Government, the Interpretation of Tax-to-GDP
Ratios, the Impact of GDP Revisions on Reported Tax Levels. Organization
for Economic Co-operation and Development: Paris.
Petersen, J and Huertes, M. 2003: Designing and implementing credit
assistance to subnational governments. In: Mila, F, Petersen, J. (eds).
(2004) Sabnational Capital Markets in Developing Countries: From Theory
to Practice. World Bank, Oxford University Press: Washington, DC, New
York and Oxford.
Poterba, JM and Rueben, KS. 2001: Fiscal news, state budget rules,
and tax-exempt bond yields. Journal of Urban Economics 50(3): 537.
Powell, JL. 1986: Symmetrically Trimmed Least Squares Estimation of
Tobit Models. Econometrica 54: 1435-1460.
Rodden, J and Eskeland, G. 2003: Lessons and conclusions. In:
Rodden, J, Eskeland, G and Litvack, J. (eds). Fiscal Decentralizatinn
and the Challenge of Hard Budget Constraints. MIT Press: Cambridge and
London.
Standard & Poor's. 2003: Surviving after default: The
experiences of local governments in Argentina and Russia, 25 February
2003.
von Hagen, J and Eichengreen, B. 1996: Federalism, fiscal
restraints, and European Monetary Union. American Economic Review 86(2):
134-138.
Wildasin, DE. 1997: Externalities and bailouts: Hard and soft
budget constraints in intergoverrunental fiscal relations. Policy
Research Working Paper WPS1843. The World Bank: Washington, DC.
(1) I am grateful to Olga Shirokova, Econometric Unit Vedi (Moscow)
for supplying some of the information used in this study. I am also
grateful to Roland Anderson, Andrew Austin, Stepan Jurajda, Jorge
Martinez-Vazquez, Saloua Sehili, Jan Svejnar, and participants of Ronald
Coase Institute's Workshop in Institutional Analysis, 2002, and the
61st Congress of the International Institute of Public Finance, 2005,
for helpful comments and discussions. All remaining errors are solely
mine.
(2) In 1992, consolidated budget expenditures accounted for about
30% of GDP. In fact, the extent of public provision was even larger, in
the Soviet system many basic goods and services were provided by
state-owned enterprises as fringe benefits to their employees. Hence,
before being privatised such enterprises maintained huge social assets:
housing, kindergartens, hospitals, and recreation facilities.
Privatisation was accompanied by the process of divestiture, meaning a
transfer of social assets and the responsibility for their financing to
municipalities.
(3) In turn, regional governments had complete discretion to
download these responsibilities further to the local level.
(4) With an average share of 'own-source' revenue equal
to 21% of total revenue in 1997, Russian regions had considerably less
revenue autonomy than their counterparts in the US, Switzerland, and
Belgium, but nevertheless more than in Spain, Germany, and Mexico (OECD,
1999).
(5) These statements would need to be qualified if the local
authorities can affect the behaviour and diligence of federal tax
agents, who are responsible for collecting revenues to all levels of
government. Although tax policy and tax administration are highly
centralised according to the formal system, local authorities could use
their informal influence on federal tax agents to affect the rigour of
tax enforcement towards local enterprises.
(6) Strictly speaking not all grants should be considered as
equally negative in terms of revenue autonomy. For example, an
equalisation grant based on stable formulas for both funding and
distribution of the funds can bring much more stability and
predictability to local budgets than ad hoc specific grants allocated
every year.
(7) Until 1998, the 'subventions' category reported
compensation to the City of Moscow for the costs related to its status
of a national capital. In 1999, the 'subventions' category
accounted for the federal governments' aid to regions in stocking
up the supplies of necessities in localities of the Far North (being a
relic of the Soviet planners' decision on location, northern
settlements have to be subsidised on humanitarian grounds before
eventual retreat is carried out). The 1999 figures do not sum up to 100%
due to the presence of unidentified 'other' transfers.
(8) Although budget execution at the subnational level is still
reported on a cash basis in Russia, by 1997 many subnational governments
had started reporting accumulated payables to the higher-level
government in a separate file according to the same classification used
for actual outlays. With the adoption of the new Budget Code all
subnational governments have been required to maintain a ledger of
purchases registering terms of order and information about the supplier.
(9) This statement holds even after accounting for the fact that
the ruble devaluation of 1998 significantly reduced the real value of
subnational debt.
(10) Our specification is similar to Capeci (1994). We do not use
Bayoumi et al.'s (1995) nonlinear specification, which was derived
for one functional class of probability distribution. We did however
attempt to include non-linear terms in our equation but did not find any
improvements in estimation.
(11) Data on agrobond trades were provided by the Econometric Unit
Vedi (Moscow).
(12) For the benchmark federal bond (GKO076), the yield was
fluctuating between 18.2% and 20.3% during June-September 1997.
(13) The auction was structured in terms of the agrobond price.
However, our analysis (and presumably investors' decision) is based
on the associated yield spread that is the difference between the yield
to the maturity on the agrobond and the yield on a federal bond of a
similar maturity taken on the day of the auction.
(14) While agrobonds give us a unique opportunity to study yield
spreads on a large sample of regions, it also limits our study to the
pre-financial crisis period. Although by 2005 the subnational bond
market completely revived in terms of trading volume, it has never
represented such a broad number of regions. As of 2005, only about 35
subnational governments had its bonds traded on the market (Myazina,
2005). Although the looming financial crisis affected the ability of
central government to bailout regions, the cross-regional nature of our
analysis allows us to control for such common factors while assessing
the impact of cross-regional differences in intergovernmental
arrangements.
(15) Lower yield ceilings set for prior trading sessions for which
no purchases took place do not convey any additional information.
(16) For seven out of the 19 unsold 1-year agrobonds the final
ceilings were around 13% points over the GKO yield. For the remaining 12
issues the final yield ceilings seem to be evenly spread from 9% to 18%
points over the GKO yield. At the same time, for one completely sold
issue the final yield ceilings exceeded 13% points premium: Republic of
Khakasia--14.55% over the GKO yield.
(17) Pulling together observations from the three different
maturities would have added only one region to the sample, while
introducing considerable difficulties in comparing risk premia across
maturities.
(18) As before year 2000 regional governments were not required to
include outstanding debt in their budgetary reports, the relation
between indebtedness and risk premia is a product of creditors'
ability to both obtain this information from other sources and utilise
it for risk assessment.
(19) Post-2000 data indicate that regional governments account for
less than 20% of subnational budget arrears (Martinez-Vazquez et al.,
2006). Nevertheless, consolidated regional-local budget arrears can
serve as a proxy for regional government liabilities to the extent that
they are used by local governments as a strategic tool for extracting
regional assistance. The effectiveness of local governments'
arrears as a tool to squeeze regional funds ranges from quite high for
wages and social payments to rather low for utility bills.
(20) By 'own-source' we mean all revenue sources whose
yield can be affected at the margin by regional governments, using their
discretion to determine taxable bases or rates, or discretion to
introduce the tax, or any combination of these three.
(21) Wildasin's (1997) calculations provide at least one class
of examples where there is a clear inverse relationship between
jurisdictional
size and availability of bailout. However, this is true in a one-shot
game. In a sequential interaction, the central government might choose
to deny a bailout to a large locality in order to send a strong signal
to other jurisdictions and thus build a reputation for fiscal
discipline.
(22) An empirical regularity is that the MLEs can be approximated
by dividing the OLS estimates by the proportion of non-censored
observations in the sample (Greene, p. 697).
(23) Theoretically, we can subtract these varying censoring limits
from both sides of the regression equation and thus arrive to the
uniform (zero) censoring limit. However, because the yield ceilings
gradually approach the clearing levels, they are likely to be correlated
with the same variables that determine the market risk premia (ie,
indebtedness and revenue autonomy). Thus, if the censoring limits were
explicitly accounted for on the RHS of our equation, we would run into
the multi-colinearity problem.
(24) The biplot display is drawn using Excel Macros from Lipkovich
and Smith (2002).
(25) We are interested in the true market yield spread, which is
the latent variable in the Tobit model. Thus, the marginal effects of
our interest are the estimated Tobit coefficients.
(26) Creditors might favour larger jurisdictions because of more
sophisticated financial management and economies of scale in fixed costs of debt transactions.
ANDREY TIMOFEEV
Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, PO
Box 3992, Atlanta, GA 30302-3992, USA. E-mail: atimofeev@gsu.edu
Table 1: Average structure of regional government revenue
1997 1998 1999
Own-source revenue 21.26%# 23.6%# 31.0%#
out of which: (0.70)# (0.67)# (0.60)#
Corporate income tax 11.22% 11.66% 18.12%
(0.80) (0.84) (0.79)
Sales tax -- 0.16% 2.46%
-- (2.89) (0.91)
Enterprise assets tax 8.54% 9.74% 7.08%
(0.84) (0.80) (0.69)
Non-tax 0.99% 1.04% 1.80%
(1.61) (1.02) (1.31)
Assigned revenue 3.66%# 3.26%# 3.99%#
out of which: (2.19)# (2.48)# (2.40)#
Levies on subsoil users 2.65% 2.94% 3.64%
(3.04) (2.76) (2.64)
Regulated revenue 20.76%# 24.01%# 20.67%#
out of which: (0.58)# (0.55)# (0.58)#
VAT 9.61% NA 8.02%
(0.78) NA (0.86)
Personal income tax 4.57% NA 6.20%
(1.02) NA (0.74)
Excises 3.59% NA 5.35%
(1.06) NA (0.99)
Grants 54.32%# 49.12%# 44.37%#
(0.48)# (0.57)# (0.62)#
Note: The main subtotals indicated with #.
Notes: Coefficients of variation are provided in parentheses.
Source: Author's calculation based on data from the Ministry of
Finance.
Bold emphasizes the main subtotals.
Table 2: Estimation results, dependent variable: yield spread
(% points)
OLS Multiplicative
(robust heteroskedastic
errors) regression
Constant 11.72 *** (10.06) 12.29 *** (0.85)
Commercial -0.65 (0.48) -1.07 *** (0.34)
debt
Interest 21.66 * (13.02) 50.6 *** (9.15)
expenditures
Per capita -5.74 * (4.40) -12.46 *** (2.18)
revenue
Population -49.73 (46.61) -89.2 *** (28.5)
share
Soft grants -0.83 (1.50) 2.59 *** (0.89)
[R.sup.2] 0.14
Heteroskedasticity -- -272.14 *** (42.18)
term
[SIGMA] 0.047 *** (0.007)
# of observations 52 52
Out of which 19 19
are censored
Tobit Heteroskedastic
tobit
Constant 14.31 *** (1.40) 14.51 *** (1.53)
Commercial -0.68 (0.85) -1.31 * (0.71)
debt
Interest 18.78 (27.49) 51.20 (32.28)
expenditures
Per capita -10.34 ** (4.98) -16.88 *** (5.97)
revenue
Population -122.65 * (76.16) -153.8 ** (65.35)
share
Soft grants -0.07 (2.82) 3.95 * (2.34)
[R.sup.2]
Heteroskedasticity -- -200.65 *** (41.12)
term
[SIGMA] 0.037 *** (0.005) 0.092 *** (0.030)
# of observations 52 52
Out of which 19 19
are censored
Notes: * statistically significant at the 10% level; ** statistically
significant at the 5% level; *** statistically significant at the 1%
level.