The Size of Nations.
Gardner, Roy
The Size of Nations Alberto Alesina and Enrico Spolaore, MIT Press:
Cambridge, MA, 2003, 261pp.
Imagine that the typical 50-page limit was removed from a journal
article, not once but twice, giving the authors room to roam. That is
basically what one has with this very interesting book. If you have
already read Alesina, Spaolare, and Wacziarg, 'Economic Integration
and Political Disintegration,' American Economic Review, 2001, and
Alesina and Wacziarg, 'Openness, Country Size and the Government,
'Journal of Political Economy, 1998, you won't find any big
surprises in this book. The same basic model, economic agents
distributed uniformly along the unit interval, is used to deliver useful
results on the optimal size of jurisdictions--here thought of as
states--when determined by majority rule, as well as when determined by
rent-maximising autocrats (the leviathan model).
The basic insight is easily comprehended. Size is beneficial: a
bigger state can deliver more public goods (especially security and
defence) and has greater weight in international affairs, such as trade
negotiations. The extreme case of a big state is a hegemon, a role
currently held by the USA. One of the very interesting implications of
the model, which the authors could have pushed much further, is the
foreseeable end of American hegemony. Once the USA no longer has the
world's biggest economy--an event that should take place well
before 2050--its current hegemony would cease.
At the same time, size brings with it heterogeneity costs. The
further one is from the centre of a state, the more remote and
peripheral one is. This has cost consequences. A remote region is much
more likely to want to secede from a state than a central region. This
implication of the model has convincing practical applications. Take
France in the past two centuries. The restless parts of France have been
places like Brittany and Corsica, far from the centre, while Paris has
never even considered leaving France. The equilibrium size of a state is
driven by the trade-off between public goods economies of scale and
rising heterogeneity costs. So don't expect One World anytime soon!
All this will be familiar to readers of the two articles, but book
length gives the reader more context and more applications. By far the
most convincing to this reader is the analysis in Chapter 12, 'The
European Union.' The authors first describe the policy competences
of the EU, in four categories (economic/social, sectoral, external,
justice/home affairs) and at three levels (extensive, shared, limited).
They find a considerable mismatch between public goods economies of
scale, which the model predicts the EU would be best suited for, and
heterogeneity areas, which the EU's own principle of subsidiarity suggests would be best suited for national and regional governments.
Part of the explanation for this mismatch is the EU's
'relatively uncontrolled bureaucracies' (p. 213). Their take
on the constitutional process at the time of writing was quite cautious.
Indeed, anyone agreeing with their analysis had to expect that EU
Constitution project to founder--as it has in mid-2005.
Rather less convincing is the big sweep of history chapters, of
which there are several. Here the focus is on Chapter 11, 'The Size
of Nations: A Historical Overview.' The big picture is (small
numerous states, small open economies, somewhat democratic) before 1500.
This is followed by nation-building by autocrats leading to (less
numerous states, large closed economies, fairly autocratic) up to 1945.
Finally, we have the post-War, and recently, the post-Cold War world,
rather like that prior to 1500, only with a lot more democracy. Whether
this level of temporal aggregation is useful, is really beyond
economics: historians are better able to judge. But even to this reader
some things are odd. First, there is no mention of the City State
Leagues--the Hanseatic League of Northern Europe, the Rhine League
inside the Holy Roman Empire, the Northern League in Italy. Surely these
leagues are a part of the story pre-1500. The one-sentence verdict on
the fall of the Ottoman Empire ('diversity') seems somewhat
simplistic. The reference to 'astrological measurements' as
driving the colonial borders of Africa (p. 197) seems far-fetched. The
reference to the partition of Germany in 1945 as 'artificial'
(p. 200) flies in the face of the vast amount of evidence from the
Potsdam Conference in July of that year. Although I could go on, the
space for a review is limited. Suffice to say, the reader may come away
from the big sweep of history less than convinced.
Still, this book is a fine read. Even if you have read the two big
mainstream articles already, you will get a lot out of the extended
versions. If you haven't read those two articles already, read the
book. I guarantee plenty of food for thought. Why are there almost 200
states in the world today? Alesina and Spaolare have the answer.
Roy Gardner
Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana, USA