From transition crises to macroeconomic stability? Lessons from a crises early warning system for Eastern European and CIS countries.
Kittelmann, Kristina ; Tirpak, Marcel ; Schweickert, Rainer 等
This paper uses a Markov regime-switching model to assess the
vulnerability of a series of Central and Eastern European countries (ie
Czech Republic, Hungary, Slovak Republic) and two CIS countries (ie,
Russia and Ukraine) during the period 1993-2004. For the new EU member
states in Central and Eastern Europe, the results of our model show that
the majority of crises in those countries can be explained by
inconsistencies in the domestic policy mix and by the deterioration of
macroeconomic fundamentals, as emphasised by first-generation crises
models, while for the CIS countries analysed, financial vulnerability
type indicators were the most relevant, that is, indicators connected
with the second- and third-generation of crisis model better explain the
vulnerability of these countries. Additionally, the set of indicators
chosen by our model is rather heterogeneous, supporting the superiority
of a country-by-country approach. Comparative Economic Studies (2006)
48, 410-434. doi:10.1057/palgrave.ces.8100162
Keywords: EU, Central and Eastern Europe, CIS, early warning
system, currency crisis, Markov switching
3EL Classifications: F47, P20, C22
INTRODUCTION
The concept of early warning systems (EWS) has been connected with
various methodologies. The pioneering paper of Kaminsky et al. (1998)
and the implementation of a EWS for currency crises by the International
Monetary Fund (1) (IMF) set the standard for the early empirical
studies. A number of empirical papers dealt with financial crises of the
Southeast Asian and Latin American countries. Central and Eastern
Europe, and especially the CIS countries, were usually not included in
those early studies.
The reasons were obvious: inconsistent and short data series,
application of different methodologies for statistical reporting and
rapid economic transition. In spite of these difficulties, the first
empirical studies dealing with so-called transition countries appeared
during the end of the nineties (see Bruggemann and Linne, 1999, 2002)
using the traditional 'signals' approach. Recently, new
methodologies have been applied to EWS construction. In this paper, we
follow the study by Abiad (2003) and estimate a Markov regime-switching
model with time-varying transition probabilities. The primary objective
of this paper is to estimate crises that occurred in a set of different
countries: Czech Republic, Hungary, Russia, Slovak Republic, and
Ukraine. (2) Our model correctly identifies most of the crisis periods.
The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 provides a
review of theoretical and empirical literature on currency crises.
Section 3 describes the applied methodology, model, and data
specification. Section 4 presents the results from the EWS based on a
Markov regime-switching model and makes an evaluation of the
capabilities of the model, based on a comparative goodness of fit assessment. Section 5 concludes the paper.
THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL BACKGROUND
To quantify the potential vulnerability of a speculative attack,
the causes of crises must be clearly understood. The following overview
of theoretical crises models represents the analytical setting for the
choice of possible leading indicators in the early warning model. (3)
According to the literature, one can distinguish between three
classes of theoretical models of currency crises. Following the model of
Salant and Henderson (1978), Krugman (1979) and Flood and Garber (1984)
developed the 'so-called' first-generation currency crises
models as response to the currency crises of Mexico and Argentina in the
1970s. In particular, the basic premise in these models is the
inconsistency of domestic policies, such as an excessive money-financed
fiscal deficit, with the commitment to a fixed exchange rate. Domestic
credit expansion in excess of money demand growth leads to a gradual
decline in international reserves. In case reserves fall to a critically
low level, which is perceived as insufficient by market agents, the
currency comes under attack: the attack depletes reserves immediately
and the fixed exchange rate regime must be abandoned. To this class
belong also models, which suggest that a real appreciation of the
currency and a deterioration of the trade or current account balance
typically precede speculative attacks. Consequently, a crisis is the
unavoidable and predictable outcome in an economy with a constant
deterioration of its 'fundamentals'.
To capture the features of the crises in the European Monetary
System (EMS) and in Mexico in the 1990s, a second-generation of currency
crises models was developed (Obstfeld, 1986, 1994). These models show
that the government faces a trade-off between alternative policies to
defend or to abandon a fixed exchange rate regime, and that the foreign
exchange market could be subject to self-fulfilling expectations if the
cost of defending the exchange rate peg rises with the expectations of
private agents towards an abandonment of it. This implies the existence
of multiple equilibria, since a change in private sector's
expectations may lead to a jump from one to another equilibrium. (4) The
exact timing of crises is, therefore, unpredictable. However, Krugman
(1996) and Obstfeld (1996) emphasise that some weakness in the
fundamentals is required before a shift in expectations can push an
economy into a crisis. Thus, it is possible to identify zones of
vulnerability for 'fundamentals' where a crisis may or may not
occur. In principle, any fundamental variable that influences the
policymakers' decision whether to defend the fixed exchange rate
can be considered in these models. The list of fundamentals originating
from first-generation models is, therefore, expanded to output,
unemployment, inflation, and domestic and foreign interest rates. An
important implication of these models is that anticipating crises may be
extremely difficult since a tight link between fundamentals and crises
does not necessarily exist.
The Asian crisis of 1997 exhibited particular characteristics that
could not be fully explained by first- and second-generation models.
This led to the development of third-generation crises models. The focus
of these models is to explain the combination of a weak financial sector
with currency crises ('twin crises'). (5) Within this new
category, two types of currency crises models may be distinguished. On
one, explicit or implicit government guarantees for private sector
foreign borrowing can create a moral hazard problem. This typically
gives rise to an asset price bubble. (6) If the asset price bubble
bursts, this causes a severe liquidity problem and a contraction of
economic activity as well as a costly fiscal bailout of bad loans.
Therefore, expectations of an ensuing excessively expansionary monetary
policy rise. Thus, like in first-generation crises models, the
speculative attack on the currency originates from inconsistent domestic
policies. On the other hand, currency crises can also originate from
banking crises if a run on the local banking system encourages
panic-stricken foreign investors to flee the country. (7) In these
models, high short-term foreign capital inflows (foreign currency loans)
lead to currency and maturity mismatches which causes banking system
fragility. The collapse of a solvent but illiquid banking system is due
to bank runs based on self-fulfilling expectations. In this setting, a
currency crisis occurs because the role of the central bank as lender of
last resort comes into conflict with the need to defend the fixed
exchange rate. In general, third-generation currency crises models
emphasise the role played by microeconomic factors implying that the
list of potential indicators can be enlarged to banking deposits,
short-term foreign debt and M2 to reserves, bank assets, lending deposit
rate ratio, portfolio flows, stock price indices, and M2 multipliers.
Summary of potential leading indicators with respect to crises symptoms
and theoretical models can be seen in Table 1.
In the earlier empirical literature (8) two major approaches for
predicting currency crises can be distinguished. The first one is the
signals approach, originally presented by Kaminsky and Reinhart (1996)
and Kaminsky et al. (1998). This approach chooses thresholds for each
indicator variable in order to distinguish their movements in periods
preceding a crisis from their usual behaviour in normal, non-crisis
periods. The level of the threshold is set so that it minimises the
'noise-to-signal-ratio', that is, the risk of false signals to
the risk of missing crises. The contribution of each indicator variable
to the vulnerability of a country can then easily be determined. This
non-parametric approach is typically univariate (9) and does not allow
testing the statistical significance levels of variables. These
drawbacks can be overcome by applying multivariate logit or probit regressions. Eichengreen, Rose and Wyplosz (1995) and Frankel and Rose
(1996) were the first to apply this method to predicting currency
crises. All information about a crisis is contained in the predicted
crisis probability. By comparing signals models with probit models, Berg
and Pattillo (1999a, b) show that probit models perform slightly better
in terms of predicting crises. One explanation may be the transformation
of the indicator variables into binary variables in the signals
approach, which entails a loss of information.
Both signals and probit/logit models require a priori dating of
crises episodes before estimation. This entails many ad hoc assumptions
since different methods can be applied which result in different crises
dates being identified. A common procedure is to construct an index of
speculative pressure and set a certain threshold level such that a
crisis is being identified when this threshold is crossed.
On the other hand, applying a Markov switching model allows
simultaneously identifying crises episodes and estimating crises
forecast probabilities. Furthermore, by employing time-varying
transition probabilities, the probability of switching from a tranquil regime to a crisis regime can be modelled as a function of a
country's fundamentals. Markov switching models, therefore,
acknowledge that periods leading to crises are intrinsically different
from tranquil, non-crisis periods, and they allow determinants
triggering shifts from one regime to another. The statistical
significance of the determinants of crises can also be derived.
Markov switching models have been used in several empirical studies
to determine currency crises. (10) However, none of them examines
Central and Eastern European or CIS countries. Martinez-Peria (2002)
used a Markov switching model with time-varying transition probabilities
to model the currency crisis in the EMS in the early 1990s. Her results
indicate that the regime-switching approach identifies speculative
attacks better vis-a-vis using the common threshold crisis-dating
procedure. The study by Abiad (2003), to which this work is most closely
related, underlines the good predictive ability of the Markov switching
model. He looks at the 1997 Asian-crisis countries, but unlike
Martinez-Peria, who pooled the data across countries, estimates the
model for each country separately. This takes into account that the
economic situation in each country is different and, therefore,
different leading indicators may be significant for different countries.
By assessing the predictive ability of the model, he finds that the
model both correctly anticipates more crises periods in the sample and
sends fewer false signals than other models. (11) In a recent study,
Arias and Erlandsson (2004) also apply the Markov switching concept with
time-varying transition probabilities to the Asian-crisis countries,
where they correct for the bias of the estimation procedure, which would
result in the selection of short-term predictors of regime switches
rather than long-term ones. The predictive ability of their model is
comparable to the model of Abiad. (12)
As indicated before, only few studies have looked at transition
economies, and even fewer to CIS countries, including Russia. Among
those, Brtiggemann and Linne (2002) look at the vulnerability of 16
Central and Eastern European countries to currency crises. They find
that exports, foreign exchange reserves, and the lending deposit rate
ratio are the best performing indicators in signalling a crisis. The
real exchange rate, banking deposits, budget deficit, industrial
production, M2 multiplier, domestic credit and interest rate, M2 to
reserves, short-term foreign debt, and imports are also useful in
predicting a currency crisis.
MODEL SPECIFICATION
The endogenous variable [y.sub.t] in our model is assumed to depend
on an unobserved first-order two-state Markov chain [{[s.sub.t]}.sub.t=1.sup.T] as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (1)
where [s.sub.t] = 0 denotes a tranquil, non-crisis state and
[s.sub.t] = 1 a crisis state. The mean and variance of [y.sub.t] are
allowed to shift with the respective state [s.sub.t]. Hence, the
conditional density of [y.sub.t] for [s.sub.t] = 0, 1 is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (2)
The transition probability matrix [P.sub.t] associated with the
latent regime-switching variable [s.sub.t] is defined as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (3)
The transition probability [p.sup.t.sub.ij] gives the probability
that state i in period t-1 will be followed by state j in period t. The
two transition probabilities are time varying, evolving as the
cumulative density function of the logistic distribution F. The constant
and the early warning indicators, which affect the state transition
probabilities, are contained in vector [x.sub.t-1]. (13) To get maximum
likelihood estimates of all parameters in the regime-switching model, we
use the likelihood function using the iteration described in Hamilton
(1994: 692-93).
To be able to assess currency crises under different exchange rate
regimes, the 'crisis' variable to be used as dependent
variable [y.sub.t] is an 'Index of Speculative Pressure'
(ISP), defined as:
IS[P.sub.t] = 1/[[sigma].sub.ER] (E[R.sub.t] - E[R.sub.t -
1/E[R.sub.t-1) + 1/[[sigma].sub.IR] (I[R.sub.t] - (I[R.sub.t-1]) -
1/[[sigma].sub.R]([R.sub.t] - [R.sub.t-1]/[R.sub.t-1]). (4)
In (4) above, ER denotes the nominal exchange rate (defined as
domestic currency to Euro), IR denotes nominal interest rate, R denotes
international reserves, and a denotes the respective standard deviation.
Every variable is determined as one-month growth rate. An increase of
the ISP, therefore, originates from an increase in the nominal exchange
rate (depreciation of the domestic currency) and/or a rise in interest
rates and/or a decrease in reserves.
The model estimates 1-month ahead forecast probabilities, which are
transformed into 12-month ahead forecast probabilities. (14) This
reflects a compromise between more accurate forecasts shortly before the
crisis date and the fact that the model should signal a crisis as soon
as possible (Arias and Erlandsson, 2004). As the estimated crisis
probability cannot be compared to the actual crisis probability, it has
become standard to determine a cut-off probability so that an alarm
signal is being emitted if the forecasted probability is higher than
this threshold. We set this cut-off probability to 50%, favouring the
risk of missing crises to the risk of having more false signals at a
lower cut-off probability. In this case a good signal is defined if the
estimated crisis probability is higher than 50 % and a crisis ensued
within the next 12 month or no signal was issued and no crisis occurred.
In the same way, a signal is said to be false if the forecasted crisis
probability is higher than 50% and no crisis occurred during the next 12
month or no signal was issued and a crisis ensued.
EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The model is estimated by using monthly data series for the Czech
Republic, Hungary, Russia, the Slovak Republic, and Ukraine, taken from
IMF's International Financial Statistic (IFS). This is a very
heterogeneous set of countries: As three of these countries entered the
EU in May 2004, while two others, Russia, and Ukraine, have no such
perspective in the short run, and one, Russia, is largely a resource
dependent economy, this set enables one to assess if a credible prospect
of EU entry makes any difference in terms of both crises determinants
and crises probability.
The series cover the period 1993:12 to 2004:06. The selection of
potential early warning indicators is made using as reference
theoretical models of currency crises, plus specific features of the
analysed economies (for instance, its dependency on oil exports, in the
case of Russia, and as an ersatz oil/gas exporter--due to the transit
fees on Russian oil and gas--for Ukraine), and data availability. The
tested variables are listed in Table 2 below.
We present the results for the five countries mentioned before: the
Czech Republic, Hungary, Russia, the Slovak Republic, and Ukraine. Our
country sample is restricted for two reasons. First, for most of the
remaining new EU member states the EWS was estimated, (15) but it just
does not captures any significant 'crisis event', even when
using the broad definition of an ISP. This is specially, but not only,
the case for currency board or quasi-currency board regimes (Estonia,
Latvia, and Lithuania). Of course, this non-result is in itself an
interesting one, as it may be seen as an indication of the robustness of
such an extreme type of hard currency regime. Second, for other new EU
member states, the EU accession countries Bulgaria and Romania, and
other CIS countries, either the shortness of the usable sample, the
questionable quality of the date series, or statistical problems with
the data hinders interpretation of the results and puts some doubts on
their overall robustness. For these five countries for which data is
available and which reveal crisis events daring the data availability
period our EWS show clear, robust and interpretable results, which we
will detail below.
The final selection of explanatory variables for the model is made
by using the approach of Abiad (2003). A bivariate model is estimated
with only one indicator and a constant at a time to get t-statistics for
the coefficients of the indicators and log-likelihood values for the
corresponding model. (16) The different signs and degrees of statistical
significance of various indicators confirm the country-by-country
assessment, since the chosen countries exhibit different sources of
vulnerability. (17) Only some indicators are significant per country:
for the Czech Republic, deviation of real exchange rate from trend,
current account balance as a GDP share, the growth rate of the
industrial production and the FDI-current account deficit on GDP, in
case of Hungary the lending deposit rate ratio and the gap between
foreign direct investment and current account deficit, in the case of
the Slovak Republic the gap between foreign direct investment and
current account deficit, while for Russia the deviation of real exchange
rate from trend, the LIBOR, changes in the ratio of deposits to M2 and
ratio of loans to deposits, and for Ukraine only banking deposits/M2,
M2/reserves and the real interest rate are significant.
However, considering that there is correlation among the
indicators, the t-statistics may be misleading for the significance
assessment of indicators. Therefore, the selection criterion for the
multivariate models is the log-likelihood value of each bivariate model.
Based on this final criterion, significant indicators have been chosen
for each country. Performing a likelihood-ratio test for joint
significance of indicators showed them to be significant.
The final results of the multivariate regression are shown in Table
3. As can be seen, rather traditional indicators of crises are chosen
for the Czech Republic and the Slovak Republic, mostly related to
external imbalances, and in the case of Hungary a mix of financial
sector and external imbalances indicators is relevant. For Russia and
Ukraine, the list mainly includes financial sector indicators.
Furthermore, the expected conditions [[mu].sub.o] < [[mu].sub.1] and
[[sigma].sub.o] < [[sigma].sub.1] hold, so that state 0 is identified
as low-mean, low-volatility regime, and state 1 as high-mean,
high-volatility regime.
Czech Republic
Following the results from the bivariate regression, we chose four
indicators for the Czech Republic--the deviation of the real effective
exchange rate from trend, current account balance to GDP, industrial
production, and the gap between foreign direct investment and current
account deficit to GDP. According to the selection, we conclude that
balance of payment indicators play a substantial role in explaining
speculative attacks in this case. Moreover, the deviation of the real
effective exchange rate from trend, considered as the most complex
indicator of speculative pressures, appears to be important in
evaluating incoming problems.
Three out of four chosen indicators refer to external imbalances in
the economy. The first-generation of theoretical models describes
external imbalances as symptom of crisis. The inclusion of industrial
production as an indicator shows that speculative attacks in the Czech
Republic could be predicted also by indicators described in the
second-generation theoretical models.
In Figure 1, we can observe crisis periods along with the 12-month
forecast probabilities and alarm signals based on 50% cut-off
probability. Currency speculators in the first months after the break-up
of Czechoslovakia directed their attention to the appointed monetary
authorities of the Czech Republic and the Slovak Republic. Although the
result of this speculative attack was not a currency crisis,
international reserves of both central banks decreased significantly.
The first speculative attacks in a not-fully liberalised environment, a
common feature of the experiences of the Czech and Slovak Republics,
were not analysed, due to data availability limitations.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
In the case of the Czech Republic one major currency crisis
occurred in May 1997. Our model sends alarm signals from September 1996,
8 months prior to the crisis. The principal trigger of the speculative
attack against the Czech crown was excessive external imbalance. High
real wage growth exceeding productivity growth induced a substantial
current account deficit. (18) Through rapid appreciation of the real
exchange rate, the domestic corporate sector lost competitiveness.
Consequently, increasing domestic absorption required an upswing in
imports.
During the turbulent years of the late 1990s, our model is sending
alarm signals up to the beginning of 1999. Forecast probabilities are
oscillating noticeably above the 50 % threshold. One can observe
contagion effect on the behaviour of the real exchange rate during 1998.
Excessive appreciation pressures at the beginning of the summer of 1998
were replaced by flight of short-term foreign capital right after the
Russian currency crisis erupted. Although we did not include an
indicator for measuring contagion in our model, depreciation pressures
against the Czech crown resulted in persistent signalling up to the end
of 1998. Gibson and Tsakalaatos (2004) highlight the possible effect of
the Asian crisis in 1997 and the Russian crisis in 1998 on accession
countries. They found '... the strong effect from the Russian
crisis, providing the evidence that contagion is an important factor in
determining the probability of speculative attacks'. (19)
Throughout 2002-2003, our model sends alarm signals sporadically.
Hungary
We ran the model for Hungary with four indicators--the current
account balance to GDP, real domestic credit growth, the gap between FDI and current account deficit to GDP, and the ratio of banking deposits to
M2. The results are shown in Figure 2.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The development of the Hungarian economy was disturbed by several
devaluations of forint. During the summer of 1993, the Hungarian forint experienced three minor devaluations (June, July, and September),
totalling 9.4%. The first major devaluation, by 8%, took place in August
1994 and served as a prologue to the introduction of government
stabilisation measures at the end of 1994. Stabilisation measures took
place with a supportive effect of a 9 % devaluation and a switch to more
flexible crawling band regime on March 1995.
Our estimations correctly marked all the cases of speculative
pressures in Hungary with sufficient time in advance. After the change
of exchange rate regime in March 1995 and the initial devaluation of 9%,
our model keeps sending signals of anticipated speculative pressures.
The persistence of signals in that case could be interpreted as the
result of the adopted crawling band exchange rate regime with its
gradual devaluations. (20)
The signals during the year 1998 can be considered the outcome of
the Russian crisis. Although there were no major movements in Hungarian
financial markets, the negative sentiment concerning emerging markets
after the Russian crisis put the Hungarian forint under temporary
pressure. Worries about fiscal stability after the general elections in
1998 strengthened this behaviour of the markets. Nevertheless, the
signals issued by the model during the end of 2000 and January 2001 are
not linked to any open crisis.
The most recent speculative attack Hungary experienced took place
during the first months of 2003, resulting in a 2.26% shift of the
forint's central parity. Our model signals the possible currency
crisis 8 months in advance of the first speculative attack against the
Hungarian forint in January 2003. A continual increase in the current
account deficit, together with low fiscal discipline, expressed in a
growing budget deficit, undermined the defence of the Hungarian forint
by the central bank.
The persistence of the twin deficits phenomenon in Hungary during
2003, amid recurrent speculative pressures on the forint, played a
dominant role in the decision process of the Hungarian central bank. In
an attempt to counteract the discrepancies produced by an inconsistent
policy mix, the central bank responded by two rapid hikes of its base
rate by 300 basis points. (21)
Slovak Republic
In our estimated model for the Slovak Republic, we chose as
indicators the current account balance to GDP, real domestic credit
growth, the gap between foreign direct investment and current account
deficit to GDP, and the import-export ratio. Figure 3 displays the
results.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The results of the bivariate regression highlight the indicators
described in the first-generation of currency crises models. In line
with results for the Czech Republic and Hungary, most of the indicators
for the Slovak Republic focus on external imbalances. The growth of
domestic credit also signals overborrowing cycles, which according to
the theoretical models can precede both currency and banking crisis. In
the late 1990s, the Slovak banking sector was near a collapse.
Nevertheless, the rapid restructuring and the gradual removal of
non-performing loans (22) to consolidation agencies averted an open
banking crisis in the Slovak Republic.
The first speculative attack in a not-fully liberalised environment
started right after the break-up of Czechoslovakia and the monetary
separation in 1993. After depletion of international reserves, the
National Bank of Slovakia came up with a 10% devaluation of the Slovak
crown against a currency basket without widening the oscillation bands.
(23) The main incentive for the devaluation was the defence of an
initially low level of international reserves. Since our model starts to
evaluate the vulnerability periods from early 1994, this speculative
attack could not be detected.
The Slovak Republic experienced several speculative attacks during
this period. Although the inconsistent policy mix and unfavourable
macroeconomic developments increased the vulnerability of the Slovakian
economy to speculative attacks, currency speculators succeeded only once
in causing an open crisis, namely in the fall 1998. The model identifies
almost persistent crisis signs, where the forecasted crisis probability
is above the 50% threshold, from 1997 up to spring of 1999.
In May 1997, a speculative attack against the Slovak crown was led
by currency speculators, a few days after they attacked the Czech crown.
Although the strength of the Slovak economy in terms of international
reserves was smaller when compared to the Czech economy, the first
speculative attack against its currency was unsuccessful. However,
devaluation pressures on the currency peg forced the central bank to
increase interest rates substantially. According to Arvai and Vincze
(2000), the main reason, why the speculative attack against the Slovak
crown was not successful is that speculative capital inflow had been
relatively low in the preceding years.
The successful speculative attack in the fall of 1998 ended with
the abandonment of the pegged exchange rate regime. Besides large
external imbalances and political uncertainty before general elections,
contagion from the Russian crisis played an important role. The
abandonment of the pegged regime was followed by a depreciation of about
20 %, after the exchange rate regime of the Slovak crown changed to a
managed float. The model estimations are in line with the observed
speculative pressures against the Slovak crown, since alarm signals are
emitted before the excessive volatility periods of May 1997 and October
1998.
During 2001 and 2002 a high current account deficit and uncertainty
about the general election in 2002 increased depreciation pressures
against the Slovak crown. Politically motivated increases in public
sector wages and pensions put pressures on the fiscal side and, through
increased domestic absorption, on the external balance. The response of
the National Bank of Slovakia was a massive intervention aiming at
halting the fall of value of the Slovak crown. (24)
Russia
For Russia the deviation of real exchange rate from trend, the
LIBOR, changes in the ratio of deposits to M2, and the ratio of loans to
deposits have been chosen as indicators for the multivariate model.
Those indicators are mostly linked to the so-called second- and
third-generation crises models, and they highlight Russia's
financial vulnerabilities.
Figure 4 shows that the issued signals are very much in line with
the stylised description of the Russian crisis during the 1990s.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The dissolution of the Soviet Union at the end of 1991 was followed
by the usual sharp GDP downturn (the so-called 'transitional
recession', see Bakanova et al., 2004). A certain macroeconomic
stabilisation around the mid 1990s was followed by the introduction of a
pegged exchange rate regime with a crawling band against the US dollar,
from July 1995 onwards, replacing the previous 'dirty float'.
However, the start of the Asian crisis in 1997 spread a negative
shock throughout emerging markets. This external shock decreased
investment confidence in Russia and caused capital outflows, forcing the
Bank of Russia to defend the band. Although during the exchange market
interventions in November 1997 the Bank of Russia lost over USD 6
billion of its liquid reserves, which was equal to two-thirds of total
reserves at that time, the exchange band was successfully defended in
that occasion.
Nevertheless, after renewed attacks in the run up to August 1998,
the government was forced to default its domestic debt obligations: this
is the onset of the famous Russian 1998 crisis, which also had
substantial regional implications, including crises in some of countries
covered by this paper.
The Russian rouble was devalued and the exchange rate band was
abandoned, leading to the adoption of a 'dirty floating'
regime (effectively, still a nominal exchange rate targeting, see Esanov
et al., 2005). One consequence of the sharp depreciation was a rapid
initial acceleration in inflation. However, the GDP fall was much less
severe and prolonged than expected, given first, the gains in
competitiveness from the devaluation in industrial sector with plenty of
excess capacity, and the still ongoing increase in energy commodities
prices (oil and gas), which represent almost 50% of Russia's
exports. Those two factors--plus the undeniably more sustainable
monetary and fiscal policy mix pursued since 1999, which is also related
to the previous factors, given the importance of the energy sector in
terms of fiscal revenues in Russia--have underpinned a GDP growth of
almost 7% per year since 1999 (see Vinhas de Souza and Havrylyshyn,
forthcoming 2006).
Particularly, one can see that the 1998 crisis is clearly
forewarned by our model.
Ukraine
For Ukraine only banking deposits/M2, M2/reserves and the real
interest rate variables were used in the final multivariate model, again
reflecting second- and third-generation type of crisis determinants,
that is, financial sector vulnerabilities.
Figure 5 reveals that this small multivariate EWS reflects the
crisis period and vulnerability of the Ukraine quite well (see Vinhas de
Souza et al., 2005). The first years of independence resulted in
substantial adjustment costs for Ukraine. This was partly due to
unfavourable initial conditions: Ukraine had one of the highest shares
of large-scale intermediate goods industrial enterprises of the former
Soviet Union, highly integrated and dependent on the rest of the USSR economy. As a result, Ukraine suffered one of the largest declines in
output among the CIS, with manufacturing output declining by over 60% in
the first 5 years of 'transition'. Monetary and fiscal
policies were clearly on an unsustainable path during this period:
budget deficits were close to 10% of GDP (a substantial part of which
was linked to para-fiscal operations to support the energy sector). As
these deficits were largely monetised, they also resulted in inflation,
which reached almost 5,000% in 1993.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
In 1994 an initial stabilisation programme was finally attempted.
Similarly to other adjustment programmes in Eastern Europe, it included
price and import/exports liberalisation, the unification of the exchange
rate, some limited fiscal consolidation and the introduction in 1996 of
a national currency, the hryvnia, which was linked to the US Dollar via
an exchange rate band of 1.7-1.9 hryvnia/USD. These measures were
successful in bringing down inflation from 400% in 1994 to 10% in 1997.
Nevertheless, the persistent fiscal deficits were incompatible with a
fixed exchange rate regime. The situation came to a head with contagion
from the Russian crisis in August 1998. Foreign reserves fell to just
over a week of imports, forcing the authorities to devalue the hryvnia
(by more than 50 %) and to introduce strict restrictions on foreign
exchange transactions. Inflation briefly increased, but returned to a
downward trend by the early 2000s.
In December 1999, Viktor Yushchenko, a former Central Bank Governor
who had built a solid reformist reputation during and after the 1998
crisis, was appointed Prime Minister. He moved fast to introduce reforms
during its brief period in power (he was voted out of office in April
2001 by a coalition of 'oligarch' and Communist parties, after
only 16 months in power). The strong growth resumption in Ukraine
(interrupted in late 2004-2005 by the policy disorganisation linked to
the change in power in the country) is considered by most analysts to be
linked to the fiscal and tax reforms initiated during this period, and
to the devaluations of hryvnia in 1998-1999 and its posterior linking to
the USD (given that most of Ukraine's external markets are in the
euro area, this implied a further depreciation of the hryvnia from 2003
onwards: a real cumulative depreciation of 40% happened since 1998) and
the resumption of growth in major CIS markets.
During subsequent years the government' continued its efforts
towards hardening budget constraints and making the tax system more
transparent. Also, in 2000 a nominally free-floating exchange rate
regime was introduced (de facto the hryvnia has been kept at almost
constant rate with respect to US dollar, by means of foreign exchange
market interventions). Since 2000 the trade and current accounts show
surpluses, which lead to an increase of the money supply, as often the
monetary authorities refrained from sterilising these inflows. The main
reason behind the lack of effective sterilisation was lack of
sterilisation instruments and ineffectiveness of NBU rates as a monetary
policy tool. Also, due to the success of the stabilisation policy, the
demand for financial assets increased, leading to high growth rates of
money supply and a credit boom.
Therefore, one might see above that there was a concentration of
crises episodes until 1996, when the Ukrainian national currency was
introduced after the first stabilisation programme. This was followed by
a tranquil period, which ended with the spillover of the Russian crisis
in 1998. It is rather surprising that this crisis period was almost
predicted by the 12-month forecast, according to which the crisis
probability increased to 38% from virtually zero in a very short period
of time. Owing to our sample, the instability associated with the
Yushchenko's 2004 election is not registered. The figure also
reveals that the introduction of a de-jure floating exchange rate regime
in 2000 was followed by warnings, which where not related to actual
crises events.
Forecast assessment
For assessing the predictive ability of our model, we constructed
several goodness-of-fit measures which have become standard for EWS.
This allows us also to compare our model to different EWS, although one
has to take into account that this comparison is a more indicative one
because of different country samples, time periods and definitions of
crises. The results are shown in Table 4.
On average, our model correctly assesses 78% of the observations.
Forecasting the pre-crisis periods is also very impressive (71% on
average), the correct assessment of tranquil periods reached 84% of
observations, and only 19% of alarms where false. (25)
Comparing our model to the similar model implemented for Asian
countries (Abiad, 2003) and a signals approach implemented for Central
and Eastern European countries (Bruggemann and Linne, 2002) highlights
the overall good performance of our model. In both cases less pre-crisis
periods could be predicted correctly but the percent of tranquil periods
predicted correctly was higher. The comparison also suggests that the
Markov switch approach is especially good in predicting crisis while the
signals approach clearly estimates a much smaller share of false alarms.
The relatively weak performance in the case of Bruggemann and Linne
(2002) may also be due to the pooling of data across countries and the
longer forecasting horizon of 24 month. This supports our assumption on
the superiority of using a country-by-country approach with a
medium-term time horizon.
The good performance of our model may be due to the fact that
crises in our country sample were mainly (but not exclusively) caused by
deteriorating fundamentals and, thus, according to first-generation of
crises models, are clearly predictable. Also, the definition of currency
crises may contribute to this result, since we set up our objective to
assess not only devaluation periods, but unsuccessful speculative
attacks as well.
One may also point out that, while roughly one-third of the periods
in our sample were estimated as having crisis warnings in the covered
new EU member states, for Russia and Ukraine almost half of all the
periods in the sample had crises warnings. Albeit some of these may be
linked to structural questions (ie, a higher dependency on more cyclical commodities in the case of Russia), this may also be seen as an
indication that the EU accession process could have decreased the
vulnerability of some of those countries to crises. The importance of
regional (and subregional, for the Czech-Slovak case) contagion should
also be stressed, given that most of the open crises periods observed in
our sample are clustered around the 1998 Russian crisis.
SUMMARY AND POLICY CONCLUSION
This paper examined vulnerability periods in a series of Central
and Eastern European countries during the period 1993-2004. For three
new EU member states (Czech Republic, Hungary, and Slovak Republic), the
results of our model have shown that the majority of currency crises in
those can be explained by inconsistencies in the domestic policy mix,
and by the deterioration of macroeconomic fundamentals with consequent
effects in terms of external imbalances, that is, mostly traditional,
first-generation type of crises, which means that crises in these
countries were clearly predictable.
Opposed to that, and beyond an apparently greater overall
vulnerability to crises than for the new EU member states (which may be
linked to the EU accession process), for the CIS countries analysed here
(Russia and Ukraine), second- and third-generation, financial
vulnerability type indicators were the most relevant ones. A corollary of this is that crises may not be as clearly predictable in these
countries, since those sorts of crises can also be subject to
self-fulfilling expectations and multiple equilibria.
This study represents, to the best of our knowledge, the first
attempt to apply a Markov regime-switching model to assess vulnerability
periods of these countries. Although it is clear that EWS are far from
perfect, and that the results do not represent a mechanical tool to
avert potential crises, the surprisingly robust performance of this
model leads one to conclude that the regime-switching approach may be
quite useful to assess vulnerability periods in the chosen countries.
The different sets of vulnerabilities indicate different types of
policy prescriptions. Given that the importance of external
vulnerabilities is expected to decrease substantially for the new EU
member states (especially after an eventual euro adoption), one can
expect the importance of those external sustainability indicators to be
reduce, and, therefore, the crises related to them. For Russia and
Ukraine, the (ongoing) strengthening of their financial sectors could
arguably be the priority task.
REFERENCES
Abiad, A. 2003: Early warning systems: A survey and a
regime-switching approach. IMF Working Paper 03/32.
Alvarez-Plata, P and Schrooten, M. 2003: The Argentinean currency
crisis: A Markov-switching model estimation. DIW Discussion Paper 348.
Arias, G and Erlandsson, UG. 2004: Regime switching as an
alternative early warning system of currency crises--an application to
South-East Asia. Department of Economics, Lund University, Scandinavian
Working Papers in Economics 11.
Arvai, Z and Vincze, J. 2000: Financial crises in transition
countries: Model and facts. National Bank of Hungary, Working Paper
2000/6.
Bakanova, M, Vinhas de Souza, LV, Kolesnikova, I and Abramov, I.
2004: Transition and growth in belarus. In: Ofer, G and Pomfret, R
(eds). The economic prospects of the CIS: sources of long-term growth.
Edward Elgar Publishing: UK. pp. 57-75.
Berg, A, Borensztein, E, Milesi-Ferretti, GM and Pattillo, C. 1999:
Anticipating balance of payments crises: The role of early warning
systems. IMF Occasional Paper 186.
Berg, A and Pattillo, C. 1999a: Are currency crises predictable? A
test. IMF Staff Papers 46(2): 107-138.
Berg, A and Pattillo, C. 1999b: Predicting currency crises: The
indicators approach and an alternative. Journal of International Money
and Finance 18: 561-586.
Blackburn, K and Sola, M. 1993: Speculative currency attacks and
balance of payment crises. Journal of Economic Surveys 7(2): 119-144.
Bruggemann, A and Linne, T. 1999: How good are leading indicators
for currency and banking crises in Central and Eastern Europe? An
empirical test. IWH Discussion Paper 95.
Bruggemann, A and Linne, T. 2002: Die Bestimmung des
Risikopotenzials von Finanzkrisen anhand eines
Fruhwarnindikatorensystems: Eine Untersuchung der
EU-Beitrittskandidatenlander und ausgewaihlter Staaten Mittel- und
Osteuropas Schriften des Instituts fur Wirtschaftsforschung Halle, Vol.
13, Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, Baden-Baden.
Chang, R and Velasco, A. 1998: Financial Crises in Emerging
Markets: A Canonical Model. NBER Working Paper 6606.
Corsetti, G, Pesenti, P and Roubini, N. 1998: Paper tigers? A model
of the Asian crisis. Internet Version November 2004.
Diebold, FX, Lee, J-H and Weinbach, GC. 1993: Regime switching with
time-varying transition probabilities. Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, Working Paper 93-12.
Dooley, MP. 1997: A model of crises in emerging markets. NBER
Working Paper 6300.
Eichengreen, B, Rose, AK and Wyplosz, C. 1995: Exchange market
mayhem: The antecedents and aftermath of speculative attacks. Economic
Policy 21: 249-312.
Esanov, A, Merkl, C and Vinhas de Souza, L. 2005: Monetary policy
rules for Russia. Journal of Comparative Economics 33 (3): 484-499.
Flood, R and Garber, P. 1984: Collapsing exchange rate regimes:
Some linear examples. Journal of International Economics 17: 1-13.
Flood, R and Marion, N. 1999: Perspectives on the recent currency
crisis literature. International Journal of Finance and Economics 4(1):
1-26.
Frankel, JA and Rose, AK. 1996: Currency crashes in emerging
markets: An empirical treatment. Journal of International Economics 41:
351-366.
Fratzscher, M. 1999: What causes currency crises: sunspots,
contagion or fundamentals? EIU Working Paper 99/39.
Gibson, H and Tsakalaatos, E. 2004: Capital flows and speculative
attacks in prospective EU member states. Economics of Transition 12(3):
559-586.
Goldfajn, I and Valdes, RO. 1997: Capital flows and the twin
crises: The role of liquidity. IMF Working Paper 97/87.
Hamilton, JD. 1989: A new approach to the economic analysis of
nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica 57:
357-384.
Hamilton, JD. 1994: Time series analysis. Princeton University Press: New Jersey.
Jeanne, O. 2000: Currency crises: A perspective on recent
theoretical developments. Special Papers in International Economics,
Department of Economics, Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey.
Jeanne, O and Masson, R 2000: Currency crises, sunspots and
markov-switching regimes. Journal of International Economics 50(2):
327-350.
Kaminsky, GL. 1998: Currency and banking crises: The early warnings
of distress, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
International Finance Discussion Papers 629.
Kaminsky, GL, Lizondo, S and Reinhart, CM. 1998: Leading indicators
of currency crises. IMF Staff Papers 45(1): 1-48.
Kaminsky, GL and Reinhart, CM. 1996: The twin crises: The causes of
banking and balance-of-payments problems. Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers 544.
Kaminsky, GL and Reinhart, CM. 1999: The twin crises: The causes of
banking and balance-of-payments problems. The American Economic Review
89(3): 473-500.
Krugman, P. 1979: A model of balance-of-payments crises. Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking 11(3): 311-325.
Krugman, P. 1996: Are currency crises self-fulfilling? NBER
macroeconomics annual. The MIT Press: Cambridge, pp. 345-406.
Krugman, P. 1998: What happened to Asia? November 2004.
Martinez-Peria, MS. 2002: A regime-switching approach to the study
of speculative attacks: A Focus on EMS crises. Empirical Economics
27(2): 299-334.
Masson, P. 1999: Multiple equilibria, contagion, and the emerging
market crises. IMF Working Paper 99/164.
McKinnon, RI and Pill, H. 1997: Credible economic liberalizations
and overborrowing. The American Economic Review 87(2): 189-193.
Obstfeld, M. 1986: Rational and self-fulfilling balance-of-payment
crises. The American Economic Review 76(1): 72-81.
Obstfeld, M. 1994: The logic of currency crises. NBER Working Paper
4640.
Obstfeld, M. 1996: Models of currency crises with self-fulfilling
features. European Economic Review 40: 1037-1047.
Radelet, S and Sachs, J. 1998: The onset of the east Asian
financial crisis Harvard Institute for International Development,
November 2004.
Rosenberg, MR. 1998: Currency crises in emerging markets: A guide
to speculative-attack models and early warning systems. Merrill Lynch,
International Fixed Income Research: New York.
Salant, S and Henderson, D. 1978: Market anticipation of government
policy and the price of gold. Journal of Political Economy 86: 627-648.
Vinhas de Souza, LM and Havrylyshyn, O. 2006: Return to growth in
CIS countries and the macroeconomic framework. Springer: Germany
(forthcoming).
Vinhas de Souza, LM, Schweickert, R, Movchan, V, Bilan, O and
Burakovsky, I. 2005: Now so near, and yet still so far: Economic
relations between Ukraine and the European Union. Institute for World
Economics, Kiel Discussion Paper 419. Kiel.
The views expressed here are exclusively those of the authors and
do not necessarily reflect the official views of their institutions. All
usual disclaimers apply.
(1) The IMF's EWS is described in Berg et al. (1999).
(2) As explained later in the paper, from the group of Central and
Eastern European countries we excluded Poland, because of data
availability. Other countries from the region (ie, the Baltics, Belarus,
and Bulgaria) were excluded due to the lack of open crisis during the
period of data availability.
(3) For a comprehensive review of the theoretical literature for
the first- and second-generation crises models, see Blackburn and Sola
(1993), Flood and Marion (1999) and Jeanne (2000).
(4) What triggers the jump between multiple equilibria remains
largely unexplained. Possible explanations are contagion effects or
herding behaviour in the presence of imperfect information, see Masson
(1999).
(5) Kaminsky and Reinhart (1996, 1999) pioneered the empirical work
on twin crises. They found empirical evidence that banking crises tend
to precede currency crises, hut the causal link is not unidirectional
since the currency crisis deepens the banking crisis*
(6) See Corsetti et al. (1998), Dooley (1997), Krugman (1998) and
McKinnon and Pill (1997).
(7) See Chang and Velasco (1998), Goldfajn and Valdes (1997) and
Radelet and Sachs (1998).
(8) For an extensive survey of the empirical literature, see for
example Kaminsky et al. (1998) and Abiad (2003).
(9) Kaminsky (1998) presents a method to combine individual
indicators into a composite indicator.
(10) In addition to the studies mentioned, Alvarez-Plata and
Schrooten (2003), Jeanne and Masson (2000) and Fratzscher (1999) use
Markov-switching models with constant transition probabilities to model
the switches between multiple equilibria leading to currency crises.
(11) At a cut-off probability of 50%, the model correctly calls 65%
of pre-crisis periods, whereby 27% of total alarm signals are false.
(12) The model correctly calls approximately 70% of pre-crisis
periods at a cut-off probability of 40%.
(13) Diebold et al. (1993) extended the baseline Hamilton (1989)
regime-switching model to allow for time-varying transition
probabilities.
(14) Here, it is assumed that the indicators that influence the
crisis probability neither worsen nor improve during this period.
(15) Results not presented here, but available from the authors
upon request.
(16) Each indicator is standardised to be zero mean and unit
variance.
(17) Results not presented here, but available from the authors
upon request.
(18) At the beginning of 1997, the estimations for current account
deficit to GDP for the whole of 1997 were around 10%, far exceeding the
expected inflows of long-term non-debt capital.
(19) Gibson and Tsakalaatos (2004: 577).
(20) The rate of devaluation in the crawling band regime decreased
continuously, from 0.060 % of daily devaluation in March 1995 to
0.00654% of daily devaluation in April 2001.
(21) The first base rate increase took place in May, while the
second was at the end of November. In both cases, the increase of the
base interest rate was 300 basis points.
(22) The estimated costs of the removal of non-performing loans are
about 105 billion Slovak crowns (about 12% of the nominal GDP in 1999).
(23) After the break-up of Czechoslovakia and the following
monetary separation, both countries pegged their currencies to baskets
with relatively narrow oscillation bands ([+ or -] 0.5% from central
parity).
(24) During May 2002, the central bank decided to increase interest
rates to cool down excessive demand pressures.
(25) The goodness-of-fit values differ somewhat ranging between 88%
in Russia to 69% in Hungary for all observations. The results are most
homogeneous for calling the tranquil periods, that is, above 80% success
rate for all countries.
KRISTINA KITTELMANN (1), MARCEL TIRPAK (2), RAINER SCHWEICKERT3
& LUCIO VINHAS DE SOUZA (4)
(1) Sovereign Risk Unit, Moody's Deutschland, An der Welle 5,
D-60322 Frankfurt/Main, Germany. E-mail: kristina.kittelmann@moodys.com
(2) Faculty of National Economy, Banking and International Finance
Department, University of Economics, Bratislava, Slovakia. E-mail:
marcel.tirpak@gmail.com
(3) Kiel Institute for World Economics, Duesternbrooker Weg 120,
D-24105 Kiel, Germany. E-mail: rainer.schweickert@ifw-kiel.de
(4) Kiel Institute for World Economics and Head, Russia/Belarus
Desk, DG-ECFIN, European Commission, Avenue de Beaulieu, 1, B-1160
Brussel, Belgium. E-mail: Lucio-Mauro.Vinhas-de-Souza@cec.eu.int
Table 1: Leading indicators, in terms of crises symptoms and
theoretical models
Generation
of Crises
Symptom Indicators Model (a) Sign
Expansionary M1 1 +
Monetary policy
Foreign exchange 1 -
reserves
Domestic credit 1 +
Expansionary Budget Deficit/GDP 1 +
fiscal policy
Public debt/GDP 1 +
Bank runs Banking deposits/M2 3 -
Overborrowing Domestic credit 1 +
cycles
M2 multiplier 3 +
Current account Exports 1 -
problems
Imports 1 +
Real exchange rate 1 -
Current account 1 +
deficit/ GDP
Terms of Trade 1 -
FDI-current account 3 +
deficit
Capital account Foreign exchange 1 -
problems reserves
Interest rate 2 +/-
differential
M2/reserves 3 +
Short-term foreign 3 +
debt/reserves
Portfolio flows/ 3 +
Total capital flows
Bank assets/GDP 3 +
Growth Real interest rate 1 +
slowdown
Industrial 2 -
production
Output 2 -
Unemployment 2 +
Inflation 2 +
Lending/deposit 3 +
Rate ratio
Stock price index 3 -
Symptom Description
Expansionary Loose monetary policy can lead to currency
Monetary policy crises if the central bank cannot guarantee
the fixed peg anymore.
Expansionary Loose fiscal policy can be starting point for
fiscal policy a currency crisis if the government wants to
overcome the problem by inflation.
Bank runs Bank runs can proceed (banking and) currency
crises.
Overborrowing Currency (and banking) crises can be the
cycles consequence of rapid credit growth after
liberalization of the domestic financial
system and the elimination of capital
account controls.
Current account External imbalances and a real exchange rate
problems overvaluation are part of a currency crisis.
The loss of competitiveness can lead to
recessions, business failures and a decline in
the quality of loans. Therefore, large negative
shocks to the terms of trade, exports, the real
exchange rate and positive shocks to imports are
crises symptoms.
Capital account High foreign interest rates lead to capital
problems outflows and may therefore anticipate currency
crises. Large capital inflows usually fuel a
lending boom. If the country's foreign debt is
large and capital flight increases capital
account problems become more severe since this
raises issues of debt sustainability. High
short-term foreign debt increases the
vulnerability of a country to external shocks.
Growth Currency (and banking) crises are preceded by
slowdown recessions and the burst of asset price bubbles.
High real interest rates could signal a
liquidity crunch, which leads to a slowdown
and banking fragility. A decline in loan quality
can be shown by an increase in the lending deposit
rate ratio.
Source: See Kaminsky (1998) and Rosenberg (1998).
(a) This column is meant to indicate from which generation of currency
crises the indicator originates. Therefore, indicators originating from
first- and/or second-generation crisis models are also important in
explaining third-generation currency crises.
Table 2: Tested variables
1 Deviation of real exchange rate
from trend
2 Current account balance/GDP
3 Real domestic credit, growth rate
4 Portfolio flows
5 Lending deposit rate ratio
6 FDI-current account deficit/GDP
7 Import-export ratio
8 M2 multiplier
9 M2 as share of reserves
10 Changes of M2 as share of reserves
11 GDP growth
12 Exports growth
13 Changes in reserves
14 Stock prices lagged growth
15 Lagged current account balance
16 Real interest rate
17 IPI growth
18 Growth of ratio of loans on deposits
19 LIBOR
20 Growth in bank assets
21 Lagged reserve ratio
22 Monetary authority credit
23 The ratio of non-FDI inflows
24 Ratio of deposits to M2
25 Changes in the ratio of deposits to M2
26 Ratio of Loans to deposits
27 Brent oil price
28 Changes in Brent oil price
29 Budgetary position of the central government
in GDP %
30 Changes of the budgetary position of
the central government in GDP%
Table 3: The multivariate EWS models
Czech Republic
Early Warning Indicators Coeff. T-stat.
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 0 -0.19 -2.19
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 1 2.07 1.30
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 0 0.80 12.60
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 1 2.79 3.30
Deviation of real exchange rate from trend -1.65 -1.03
Current account balance/GDP -1.96 -0.70
Real domestic credit, growth rate
Industrial product-ion, growth rate -0.70 -0.52
FDI-current account deficit/GDP -0.32 -0.28
Import export ratio
Banking deposits/M2
M2/reserves
Real interest rate
LIBOR
Changes in the ratio of deposits to M2
Ratio of loans to deposits
Constant ([[beta].sub.0]) 2.91 1.17
Constant ([[beta].sub.1]) -0.38 -0.48
Number of observations 121
Likelihood ratio test 9.26
P-value 0.05
Hungary
Early Warning Indicators Coeff. T-stat.
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 0 -0.09 -1.06
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 1 2.43 2.71
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 0 0.81 10.80
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 1 1.63 3.15
Deviation of real exchange rate from trend
Current account balance/GDP -0.27 -0.50
Real domestic credit, growth rate -0.84 -1.40
Industrial product-ion, growth rate
FDI-current account deficit/GDP -0.24 -0.21
Import export ratio
Banking deposits/M2 -1.16 -0.87
M2/reserves
Real interest rate
LIBOR
Changes in the ratio of deposits to M2
Ratio of loans to deposits
Constant ([[beta].sub.0]) 1.82 2.53
Constant ([[beta].sub.1]) 0.41 0.49
Number of observations 133
Likelihood ratio test 15.61
P-value 0.00
Slovak Republic
Early Warning Indicators Coeff. T-stat.
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 0 -0.21 -2.49
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 1 2.77 1.32
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 0 0.84 13.31
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 1 2.42 2.79
Deviation of real exchange rate from trend
Current account balance/GDP -0.45 -0.56
Real domestic credit, growth rate -0.60 -1.01
Industrial product-ion, growth rate
FDI-current account deficit/GDP -0.48 -0.59
Import export ratio -0.41 -0.44
Banking deposits/M2
M2/reserves
Real interest rate
LIBOR
Changes in the ratio of deposits to M2
Ratio of loans to deposits
Constant ([[beta].sub.0]) 1.80 2.35
Constant ([[beta].sub.1]) -0.88 -1.28
Number of observations 124
Likelihood ratio test 11.68
P-value 0.02
Russia
Early Warning Indicators Coeff. T-stat.
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 0 -0.28 0.07
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 1 0.25 0.48
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 0 0.45 0.05
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 1 2.92 0.25
Deviation of real exchange rate from trend 0.32 1.08
Current account balance/GDP
Real domestic credit, growth rate
Industrial product-ion, growth rate
FDI-current account deficit/GDP
Import export ratio
Banking deposits/M2
M2/reserves
Real interest rate
LIBOR -1.90 1.24
Changes in the ratio of deposits to M2 -0.45 0.56
Ratio of loans to deposits -0.51 0.50
Constant ([[beta].sub.0]) 1.74 0.64
Constant ([[beta].sub.1]) 1.08 0.38
Number of observations 122
Likelihood ratio test 11.73
P-value 0.02
Ukraine
Early Warning Indicators Coeff. T-stat.
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 0 0.00 0.01
Mean, [s.sub.t] = 1 -0.11 -0.13
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 0 0.22 14.05
Sigma, [s.sub.t] = 1 3.75 11.74
Deviation of real exchange rate from trend
Current account balance/GDP
Real domestic credit, growth rate
Industrial product-ion, growth rate
FDI-current account deficit/GDP
Import export ratio
Banking deposits/M2 -0.35 -0.13
M2/reserves -1.94 -1.35
Real interest rate 6.27 0.54
LIBOR
Changes in the ratio of deposits to M2
Ratio of loans to deposits
Constant ([[beta].sub.0]) -20.63 -1.28
Constant ([[beta].sub.1]) 0.76 2.15
Number of observations 125
Likelihood ratio test 7.98
P-value 0.05
Table 4: In-sample forecast assessment: Measures of predictive power
Goodness-of-fit (cut-off probability of 50%) Our Abiad
model (2003)
(a) Per cent of observation correctly called 78 81
(b) Per cent of pre-crisis periods correctly called 71 65
(c) Per cent of tranquil periods correctly called 84 89
(d) False alarms as per cent of total alarms 19 27
Goodness-of-fit (cut-off probability of 50%) Bruggemann/
Linne (2002)
(a) Per cent of observation correctly called 74
(b) Per cent of pre-crisis periods correctly called 16
(c) Per cent of tranquil periods correctly called 96
(d) False alarms as per cent of total alarms 5
(a) This is equal to the sum of pre-crisis month correctly called
and tranquil periods correctly called divided by the number of
observations.
(b) This is the number of pre-crisis periods correctly called
(observations for which the estimated probability of crisis is above
the cut-off probability and a crisis ensues within 12 month) as share
of total pre-crisis periods.
(c) This is the number of tranquil periods correctly called
(observations for which the estimated probability of crisis is below
the cut-off probability and no crisis ensues within 12 month) as share
of total tranquil periods.
(d) A false alarm is an observation with an estimated probability of
crisis above the cut-off probability not followed by a crisis within
12 month.