Overcoming the curse of hydrocarbon: goats and governance in the oil funds of Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan.
Kalyuzhnova, Yelena
INTRODUCTION
The management of oil revenues--which are volatile, unpredictable,
and ultimately exhaustible--offers important opportunities but can also
greatly complicate economic policy-making. To tackle this management
challenge, many oil-producing countries are setting up oil funds. In
light of experience, there is a need to ask a fundamental question:
under what circumstances can such funds become part of a policy
solution--rather than ending up as a part of the problem?
The literature on resource-rich economies supports the view that
oil and gas revenues can pose problems for economic management. In a
range of cases, economic performance appears to suffer rather than
benefit from the impact of natural resources endowment (Gylfason and
Zoega, 2003; Paldam, 1997). The international community, including
international financial organisations, have become growingly concerned
about the effectiveness with which natural resource revenues are used,
and notably how they can help foster long run economic and social
development. The latter fits into the wider topic of the political
economy of resource-driven growth. At the present time there is a
growing literature on the concept that natural resource endowment is an
economic curse rather than a blessing (Auty and Mikesell, 1998; Auty and
de Soysa, 2006; Gylfason, 2001; Kalyuzhnova and Kaser, 2006; Sachs and
Warner, 2001, etc). In this paper we are making an initial assumption
that for Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan their resource endowment is a
potential blessing to overcome transition disruptions. However, the
lesson of experience in other countries is that realizing this
promise--and avoiding the risk that natural resources become a
'curse'--is crucially dependent on policies, and in particular
on transparency. Oil funds, we will argue, can contribute by smoothing
some of the instability that may arise from energy price fluctuations;
and transparent rules of operation can also avoid many of the adverse
incentives that have plagued some resource-rich countries. Of course,
the optimal design and practical implementation of these instruments of
hydrocarbon revenue management in Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan remain to be
seen in the years ahead.
This paper analyses one of the possible instruments of hydrocarbon
revenue management--oil funds. Such funds have become fashionable in the
wake of recent high and volatile oil prices, and with new discoveries of
hydrocarbon deposits. In recent years, many countries either established
oil funds or are considering doing so. These funds have different
titles, goals and rules, but they share the underlying objective of
helping governments deal with the problems created by large revenues
from the energy sector. The core question to be addressed is whether oil
funds, generically, are panacea for the so called 'paradox of
plenty'--or whether they are effective only in circumstances that
are in any case particularly benign. The oil funds may serve as a form
of 'commitment mechanism', thus substituting for the IMF commitment mechanism. The paper suggests that the key requirements for
success with such funds lie in governance issues.
The paper is divided into three main sections. The first reviews
the conceptual framework relevant to natural resource funds--taking into
account the broad context of macroeconomic and energy policies, in a
setting oil price uncertainty. The second section turns to institutional
issues-including management costs and problems of organisational design.
This section highlights the critical role of governance in three
respects: defining transparently the goals of each fund; communicating
these goals to build a constituency of public support; and ensuring the
efficient and transparent management of the fund on an ongoing basis.
The third section of the paper analyses the evolution of two oil
funds, the State Oil Fund of the Azerbaijani Republic (SOFAZ) and the
National Fund for the Republic of Kazakhstan (NFRK). It highlights the
main principles that govern the operation of these funds, and reviews
managerial steps that have been taken so far as a consequence of the
policy process in these countries. It explores core governance issues,
and so doing probes the question whether, in the Azeri case, the typical
goals of an oil fund are appropriate at this stage of developments. A
final section of the paper offers brief conclusions--drawing these
threads together, and identifying future priorities for research.
A FRAMEWORK OF ANALYSIS
Statement of the problem
The governments of resource-rich countries face the challenge of
devising policies that can channel effectively 'income transfers to
governments and the inflow of foreign exchange from foreign
investments' (Kalyuzhnova, 2002, p. 79). In this context, the
literature identifies oil funds as a tool that may help in addressing
two specific problems associated with oil revenues: the unpredictability
and volatility of world market prices, and the concern to save part of
the revenues for future generations 'The Permanent Income
Hypothesis' (PIH). (ECON, 2002; Davis et al., 2001, 2003a, b;
Fasano, 2000; Gelb, 1986; Karl, 1997). A further problem could in
principle also be mitigated by oil funds: the incidence of 'Dutch
Disease.'
The volatility of the prices and the public finances
The international price of crude oil is a carefully watched
indicator and could be considered as a parameter of a stochastic
process. Although the participants of the oil market are trying to reach
an agreement, the reality demonstrates that there are too many problems
with keeping the promises and the participants could deviate from their
original strategies. That creates a volatility of oil prices and
uncertainty of the oil revenue.
In the academic literature on energy abundance, the question of
volatility and short-run policy responses is viewed as one of the most
sensitive (Auty and Mikesell, 1998; Esanov et al., 2001; Van Wijnbergen,
1984). Experience in many countries confirms the importance of achieving
some smoothing of the impact on revenues. This implies a need for
governments to find instruments and approaches--such as oil funds--that
help formulate and conduct fiscal policy in an optimal way.
The potential costs of failing to smooth revenues can be high. The
volatility and unpredictability of the world oil price is transmitted
through export earnings and taxation to government revenues--which, even
over the short run, may vary widely from the amount included in the
budget. When the authorities have overestimated the oil price in the
budget, the revenue shortfall requires a corresponding expenditure
reduction; an increase of other fiscal revenue sources; or borrowing
more than projected.
The first of these responses, expenditure reduction, may be
needed--but it can pose major challenges to efficiency, since in
practice the cuts may fall on investment and other high-priority
programs, while less productive transfers may be hard to prune back
quickly--especially in a poor economic setting. The second is also
potentially problematic, since it is difficult (though not impossible)
to swiftly broaden the tax base, and short-term expedients may also be
distortive--for example, heavier taxes on labour income. Borrowing may
be effective as a short-run expedient, but ultimately issues of debt
dynamics and stability may arise.
A key dilemma for governments, however, is that oil prices as a
time series do not have a mean-reverting quality. The literature
suggests that they perform more like a random walk, punctuated by regime
shifts. Under these circumstances, one must he thinking of a pragmatic
smoothing approach, not an optimal one.
Saving for future generations
The issue of saving for the future is even more complex, and the
policy goals of the saving funds are inherently more complicated to
determine. The financial provision of these types of funds, which are
supposed to generate income for the future generation, mainly depends on
a share of hydrocarbon revenue (which in most cases would be a fixed
one).
A first approach to devising rules envisages an optimal path for
expenditure and saving, based on assumptions about key variables such as
the future level of natural resource prices and the real interest rate.
(2) However, there are huge complexities in trying to arrive at an
optimal saving policy. With rising productivity levels, future
generations are likely to enjoy higher living standards than
today's population. Moreover, funds spent today--for example in
public investments--may also benefit future generations. The
re-distribution of the economic savings sometimes could be quite
irrational (from the economic point of view), although still politically
justifiable (see the discussion below of the Azeri fund). Indeed,
optimizing models describe an ideal world. In reality the governments of
resource-rich countries are facing a problem of dynamic inconsistency,
which reaps the gains from the optimal management strategy of the
resource wealth. (See Newbery, 1981 and Benabou and Marek, 2002.)
Hence some governments have adopted alternative approaches. The
most cautious example is the Norwegian policy of spending only the
investment income on natural resource wealth--the so-called 'bird
in the hand' approach. This, however, has little to recommend it in
a developing economy setting, where the returns to domestic
investment--for example, in areas such as education or
infrastructure--are potentially high compared with available external
investments. Moreover, such domestic investments clearly benefit future
generations directly and substantially by raising potential growth rates of the economy over the medium and long run.
Between these extremes of an optimizing model and bird-in-the-hand
caution lie more pragmatic approaches. These recognize fundamental
uncertainties about the key variables in optimizing models, and take
into account (explicitly or implicitly) the availability of high social
returns to some public expenditures. The advocates of such approaches,
however, have found themselves in search of a theoretical framework in
which to assess different policy approaches. The discussion in later
sections of this paper suggests that one natural reference point for
such a framework is to be found in the field of governance rather than
in principles of optimal resource allocation.
Dutch Disease and sectoral imbalances
A further concern that supports the case for cushioning the impact
of energy prices on the economy is the issue of 'Dutch
Disease.' This is the potentially negative impact on the traded
goods sector of strong real appreciation due to buoyant export earnings
in the natural resource sector. (3)
Arguably, the damage attributed to Dutch Disease does not arise
from the longer-run balance of the economy with a large natural resource
sector: over time the level of the real exchange rate is an
equilibrating factor, not one to be fought against. However, one element
that can be problematic is short-to medium-run variability in the real
exchange rate. This--coupled with hysteretic effects and inefficiencies
in the financial sector--can damage output and employment, as resources
are not shifted swiftly between the sectors.
This suggests a two-pronged policy approach--aiming to develop the
financial sector over time, and meanwhile seeking to buffer the impact
on the economy of sharp price fluctuations. Developing the financial
sector will facilitate the switching of resources between tradeable and
non-tradeable goods, and thus mitigate risks of 'Dutch
Disease' (Hausmann and Rigobon, 2002). It should also help mobilise domestic savings for investment outside the mineral sector; and
efficient financial markets help attract external capital, which can be
invested in non-resource branches and hence support industrial
diversification. More fundamentally, of course, there is the challenge
of investing sufficiently in physical and human resources, so as to
foster rapid productivity growth and hence a viable traded goods sector
in a setting of medium- and long-run real appreciation.
The role of oil funds
These considerations point, first, to the case for some form of
stabilization of the impact of natural resource prices on the economy,
and an oil fund can be thought of as institutionalizing such a rule. It
is also, second, a natural vehicle to address the issue of saving for
future generations.
An oil fund can perform both roles if it ensures that a proportion
of revenues, over time, is invested in foreign assets, but with some
component of this varying in the short- to medium-term in order to
smooth the impact on the budget of sharp changes in oil prices. Put in
these terms, the role of an oil fund can be thought of as
formalizing--or giving institutional focus to--a set of fiscal rules.
The effectiveness of the fund can be thought of as deriving from this
role: does it reinforce good policy rules, and thus leverage market
expectations to help buffer the economy from shocks? Or are its
operations neutral--or even problematic--in this respect? (4)
To achieve these goals, institutional context matters hugely. As
Barnett and Ossowski concluded, in general, governmental fiscal policy
of the oil-producing state should take into account the relative
importance of oil to the given economy, 'the size of the oil
reserves, maturity of the oil industry, etc' (Barnett and Ossowski,
2003).
Moreover, as discussed above, with oil prices following a random
walk, one must be thinking of a pragmatic smoothing approach, not an
optimal one. The nature of the world oil market does not allow
governments to set up a confident set of rules relating to the
management of stabilisation funds. Indeed, history provides many
illustrations, where stabilisation policies relating to commodities
collapsed with the rapid exhaustion of finance.
It could be argued that the stabilization role performed by oil
funds could also be achieved by the use of oil futures markets, with the
country's future oil production, or a part of it, sold now at a
known price for up to 10 years into the future. Countries such as Chile
have experimented with the use of futures markets in this connection.
Hedging strategies, however, typically involve the costly roll-over of
relatively short-term positions.
In sum, policy-makers may need to think of the stabilization role
of oil funds as potentially valuable in reinforcing prudent fiscal
rules, but not a panacea--and not offering the prospect of some
economically optimal smoothing. If this framework of analysis is
accepted, then a core criterion against which to judge such funds is
governance: whether the way in which they operate achieves this limited
but promising task in a manner that is clear, persuasive and efficient.
INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANISATIONAL DESIGN
The considerations above bring us to focus particularly strongly
not on optimal rules but on political economy factors: institutions and
organisational design. These issues are critically important whether
funds have stabilisation or saving functions, or both. They also appear
particularly relevant in the setting of economies that are in transition
and endowed richly with natural resources: both features can be
associated with a number of institutional weaknesses.
Institutions and transparency
A first area where institutional issues are key is in the
microeconomic domain: concerns about rent-seeking and corruption. These
problems can be worsened by a lack of transparency. The principles where
clarity is most needed are the rules that ultimately govern who will
benefit from re-distribution of (all forms of) the nation's
resource wealth; and how far governmental policies act as disguised
transfers in this regard (Tullock, 1997). For resource funds, the role
of the commitment mechanisms is extremely important in order to limit
the possibility of dynamic inconsistency (Dixit, 1996).
Overcoming perverse incentives in government intervention could be
perceived as a challenge in achieving an optimal path of the public
welfare from resources. Constraints on organisational options are
defined by lack of democracy, economic instability, etc. The
implications of corrupt government lacking democratic power for
resource-rich countries are discussed in Damania and Erwin (2004). A
special place here should be given to rent-seeking behaviour of corrupt
governments, namely to the aggregate resources absorbed by rent-seeking.
In case of resource-rich countries these resources are quite large,
because as a rule they represent the main sector of the economic
activities in these countries. Therefore, the effect of rent-seeking on
the organisational design of the governmental programmes is significant
overall. Stigler (1975) and Posner (1975) demonstrated that the latter
can be particularly observed in the area of regulation.
A second area where institutional maturity and transparency are
crucial concerns macroeconomics: the design and implementation of fiscal
policy. Links to fiscal policy are particularly important in a saving
context. In successful cases these funds should ensure significant
public savings. Creation of the oil fund, and agreement on its rules,
can be seen as a commitment device. It could also help to build a public
constituency for saving part of revenues. In cases where the government
finances deficits by borrowing from saving funds, then 'saving fund
assets are merely offset by government debt' (Davis et al., 2001).
This highlights, again, the critical link between the operation of an
oil fund--here in a saving role--and the design of fiscal policy. The
key issue is the strict discipline and ability of the government to keep
a financial balance in the accumulation and spending of the saving fund
income. Of course, the large accumulation of the oil fund assets could
create political unrest (the public could ask the government to increase
public spending and decrease taxes, etc).
These considerations help answer the legitimate question whether a
sound strategy of public saving for future generations could not be
implemented without creating a formal oil fund. In financial terms, yes,
but oil funds can potentially play a key role by helping to promote
public understanding of the need to save for future generations. To
achieve this goal, however, the analysis needs to be clearly set out,
and the rules transparent: only thus will these prove persuasive to
political circles and the wider public. On this reading, governance is
the core challenge.
How should the funds be used: externally or internally? Saving
funds could look at risk-adjusted rates of return on domestic and
external assets, including externalities that result from the domestic
intervention if markets could not have supplied this. There seems little
logic, however, in having the domestic component actually identified as
part of the saving fund. It does not mitigate risks of 'Dutch
Disease,' and it could more transparently be included as public
investment in the budget.
Assessing performance of some resource funds
It may be helpful to consider, first, the two key objectives
assigned to resource funds--stabilization and saving--and ask in what
framework their effectiveness can be analysed? What are the main
criteria of success of the funds? The crucial point is clear goals of
the fund. For example Norway or Alaska's funds pursue stabilisation
and perform saving functions. Many other funds have the same functions
but have not been successful.
The second not less important set of criteria that should be put
forward are fund management rules that guarantee accountability. It is
crucial that every fund could clearly answer to the following questions:
who is managing the fund? The Norwegian fund is managed by the Norwegian
Central Bank according to the Ministry of Finance guidelines. The Alaska
Permanent Reserve Fund is managed by the Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation and external managers handle equity, fixed income and real
estate portfolios.
The last but not least set of criteria of success should be
connected with a high level of transparency of fund's operations.
Every fund requires professional management. Financial authorities of
the country should be responsible for financing non-oil deficits or
income for all kind of expenditures. If the fund has independent
spending authority, that could undermine the budgetary process. Regular
reporting and audit are quite important. In addition the management of
the fund need to maintain public awareness about the existence of the
fund. There are different steps in this respect: press releases,
advertisement, etc. For example in Alaska an annual dividend paid to
each Alaska resident (amounting to about 50% of the income, the rest is
saved).
As Table 1 illustrates resource funds come in various forms and
their nature is quite diverse: stabilisation funds (eg Kuwait, Oman,
etc); contingent funds (eg Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, etc). Some oil funds
represent separate institutions (eg Azerbaijan, Algeria, and Iran);
others just have specific accounts at a Central Bank (eg Kazakhstan and
Norway). The common characteristic of all these funds, however, is that
they represent a public institution (separated from the budget) that
accumulates income from the non-renewable sources of the country.
The data in Table 1 illustrate the relative performance of the
funds that would comply with the country-specific conditions,
institutional and organisational design. The ranking could vary between
'good', 'average' and 'poor' performance.
The qualitative aspect of this assessment is remaining an assessor
judgment and in the existing literature there are different assessments
of the performance of the same funds (eg Birdsall and Subramania (2004)
evaluated Venezuela's oil fund performance as poor, while
Zolotareva et al. (2002) classified it as successful). The active
resource funds (ie excluding those that have just been established or
that have completed the saving process) are faced with the problem of
beating the market, which is a consistently difficult task due to the
competitive pressures, the expectations of investors as well as market
factors.
The analysis of the experience of some funds presented in Table 1
produced several patterns 'for' and 'against' the
creation of such funds. The summary of the finding is presented in Table
2.
The role of the oil funds is controversial and the empirical
evidence is inconclusive. The academic literature with regard to the oil
funds remains patchy and mainly consists of the work by the IMF and
World Bank, where the role of the oil funds is also being debated. In
general, it is possible to identify two points of view. One point of
view is that the oil funds are not necessary because if the conditions
that are required for the successful functioning of these funds exist,
then the revenue windfall can be managed without them within the
budgetary process (eg Davis et al., 2001).
The other point of view is that even if it is impossible to create
'ideal' conditions, the existence of oil funds could prevent
excessive spending and help to overcome the resource curse. The
experience of the successful funds (eg Alaska, Kiribati, Norway, etc)
(Birdsall and Subramania, 2004; Fasano, 2000; etc) is usually cited in
support of this argument. To date, indeed, there are not many examples
of success. The Alaskan and Norwegian oil funds are striking exceptions
here--but did these countries need the oil funds in the first
instance--given the transparency for the national policy frameworks and
the broad support for deferring some wealth gains for future
generations? At the moment of inception of the oil funds in these
countries, capital intensity was already high, absorption problems were
small, investment risks were low, and hence there was no conflict
between domestic capital needs and macro-stabilisation. It is tempting
to think that had savings decisions been left to private actors they
would simply have saved the money abroad too, given low domestic
returns. Oil funds worked because private and public preferences were
aligned--hence the funds were also unnecessary.
History provides us with many examples of unsuccessful funds, the
number of which exceeds the successful cases (eg Nigeria, Venezuela,
etc) (Davis et al., 2003a, b; Delvin and Lewin, 2002, etc).
'Unfortunately, apart from Norway (with its strong government
institutions and healthy democracy), the experience of national oil
funds has not been encouraging' (Birdsall and Subramania, 2004, p.
85). The examples of other countries (particularly in the Middle East)
demonstrate limited success in the functioning of the oil funds. The
reason for the inefficiency of the oil funds is in its lack of clear
rules and operations, which 'should be transparent, with stringent
mechanisms to ensure accountability and prevent the misuse of
resources' (Davis et al., 2003b, p. 311). The operational side of
this management could cause further obstacles (Barnett and Ossowski,
2003).
In conclusion, the experience of different oil funds (the
Venezuelan Investment Fund, Nigerian Petroleum Trust Fund) has
highlighted an even more complicated problem: the question of
transparency, rigorous governance and accountability. A recent report by
Caspian Revenue Watch provided a public debate on these issues (Tsalik,
2003). One of their findings is that 'weak governance makes these
countries less likely to convert social expenditures into improved
income' (Tsalik, 2003, p. 11). In the political economy assuming
that funds are important in order to protect people's money, the
essential element is transparency of management. The experience of many
countries demonstrated that the combination of a non-transparent fund
and the ability to spend in an extra budgetary manner is bad and harms
the national economy.
TWO CASPIAN CASES: AZERBAIJAN AND KAZAKHSTAN
To explore more concretely the frame of reference discussed above,
it is helpful to consider experience with the oil funds of Azerbaijan
and Kazakhstan. These two economies represent examples of natural
resource dependency, which have emerged recently, and both have set up
oil funds during the past decade.
Key similarities between the two economies
A number of academic papers have analysed economic development in
the Caspian Sea Region since its independence (Pomfret, 1995; Kaser,
1997; Kalyuzhnova, 1998, 2002). All of these highlight that the last
decade has brought significant changes to the Caspian Sea Region. The
hydrocarbon sector in particular gave these economies a new shape.
Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan became strategically important to world energy
markets and thus attracted the largest share of FDI in the region
(Figure 1).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
In recent years the hydrocarbon sector in both these economies has
played a crucial role in recovery from the post-transition trough, and
attainment of a high rate of economic growth. From 2000 a steady
increase in GDP, with a rate of 9-10%, annually was recorded in the
Azerbaijani and Kazakhstani economies.
In general, both economies continue to grow strongly as a result of
rising oil exports funded by foreign direct investment. Both, indeed,
have a high export concentration in mineral resources (see Figure 2 and
Table 5). Table 5 in particular depicts the high (and somewhat
increasing) rate of dependency on oil and oil-related products in both
countries. This, however, makes their economies particularly vulnerable
to fluctuations in world commodity prices. In addition, it leads to a
concentration in specific markets which again highlights significant
dependence--the 1998 Russian financial crisis being one of the major
examples.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The task of both the Azeri and the Kazakhstani governments on the
macroeconomic and structural front is relatively similar at first
glance: strengthening domestic institutions to encourage investment,
building human and physical capital, and providing adequate and
sustainable social protection mechanisms.
Key developmental differences
There is a striking difference in income level between the two
countries. According to the World Bank classification, Kazakhstan
belongs to the Lower Middle Income country group. To a certain extent
this explains the behaviour of the decision-makers. From the
author's personal observation, during the last 2 years the
Kazakhstani government appears more willing to pass on the benefits of
the oil boom to the population than in the earlier years of transition.
This can be explained in part by a pre-emptive effort to defuse potential popular discontent. However, the gradual changes in
governmental thinking and operations, and the country's substantial
fiscal resources could also explain this change in behaviour.
By contrast in the case of Azerbaijan, classified by the World Bank
as a Low Income country, the government is faced with the problems of a
low level of GDP per capita, limited fiscal resources and administrative
capacity, a substantial informal sector and a Kazakhstani economies is
clear--to ensure the stability of current economic progress. High
incidence of poverty (Dobronogov, 2003): according to a recent survey
49% of the population is living below the absolute poverty line
(approximately USD 25.8 per capita/ month) and 17% of the population
lives in extreme poverty (approximately USD 15.5 per capita/month)
(State Statistics Committee, Household Budget Survey, 2001).
However,' as a result of rapid economic growth [due to the high oil
prices] and increased social spending, poverty declined to 40.2% in 2004
from 49% in 2001' (IMF Country Report No. 05/260, July 2005, 5).
Still, there is a long way to poverty alleviation in the country which
is reflected in the current 3-year State Programme of Poverty Reduction
and Economic Development (SPPRED).
The pattern of public expenditure in part reflects these different
levels of development. Moreover, there are significant differences in
the labour market reflecting historical circumstances. Azerbaijan has to
look after people who were displaced from their own towns within the
territory of Azerbaijan since the dispute between Azerbaijan and Armenia
in 1989--and among whom poverty is endemic. Moreover, true unemployment
is significantly higher than the officially recorded level (which puts
the unemployment rate at around 1.3%-1.5% of the labour force in 2003).
In Kazakhstan, by contrast, there is no comparable problem of displaced
persons. The unemployment rate is falling. And incomes are cushioned by
extensive under-employment in the economy, especially in industrial
enterprises, which still need to be restructured. Moreover, real wages
are rising strongly--resulting in an improvement in average living
standards.
In sum, the economies of these two oil-rich economies differ--with
Kazakhstan being somewhat richer and more advanced in transition but
with a mixed performance in social indicators (see Table 4). Both
Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan are expected to triple their income per capita
by 2007 based on their oil and gas exports. It is important to avoid the
vulnerability to oil price declines that has caused adversity in the
past for countries such as Venezuela in the period after the oil booms
in the 1970s and early 1980s. The governments should without doubt look
at the possibilities to diversify the industrial production and to
foster competitiveness of the economies, but based on the specifics and
needs of Azeri and Kazakhstani economies (eg recently risen inflation in
Azerbaijan). Partly as a result the demand on the oil funds will differ
as well, reflecting the different priorities and initiatives by their
governments. The management of oil revenue may require pursuing reform
agendas that are markedly different. And in each case the economics of
the challenge are undeniably complex--and ultimately require finely
balanced political judgements. Nonetheless, an examination of the way
their respective oil funds operate suggests interesting parallels in
terms of the steps needed to ensure that these institutions are fully
effective in these two very different economic contexts.
The roles and objectives of the national oil funds
To facilitate the management of oil revenue, both countries have
already established national oil funds--in Azerbaijan 1999 and
Kazakhstan 2000. In each case, the fund operates as both a stabilisation
and savings funds (see Table 1).
On 29 December, 1999 Azeri President Aliyev signed the decree N240
'On setting up the State Oil Fund of the Azerbaijani Republic'
(SOFAZ) to govern the collection of oil revenue and bonuses. According
to the presidential decree, SOCAR received authorization to ensure the
transfer of funds to a special oil fund account in the National Bank of
Azerbaijan. Initially, according to SOCAR's President N. Aliyev,
USD 270,964,652 of Azeri oil revenues and bonuses provided by the
foreign companies were transferred to the oil fund account. The largest
part of this amount was made up of revenues from the sale of 967,805
tonnes of oil produced from the Chirag field. The Oil Fund is directly
accountable to the Azeri President, who appoints the executive director
and confirms members of the Supervisory Council. Mr Samir Sharifov was
appointed by the President as the first general manger of the fund.
The SOFAZ receives all revenues associated with the 'new oil
fields.' These fields are the ones included in the 1994
'Contract of the Century' (Aliyev, 1997, p. 9). It receives
and records proceeds from the state's share of oil sales,
royalties, pipeline fees, rental fees, bonus payments, and interest
income. Most of the revenues presently come from the first and only
operational consortium at the Azeri, Chiraq, and Guneshli (ACG) oil
fields, the source for the Baku-Tbilisi-Ceyhan oil pipeline. (See SOFAZ
Press release-April 16, 2003.)
The Kazakh oil fund (the National Fund for the Republic of
Kazakhstan (NFRK)) was established in August 2000 and the legal aspects
were defined by Presidential Decree N402, 23 August 2000. The NFRK is
run by a special Management Council, formed by President Nazarbayev. The
governing body includes the president of the country, the prime
minister, the heads of the two chambers of parliament, the National Bank
chairman and the finance minister. The fund is managed by the National
Bank and overseen by a governing board chaired by the President of
Kazakhstan. Information on the fund's revenues, expenditure, and
the audit results is published in the local press and the fund is
subject to an annual independent audit.
The NFRK invests in liquid foreign equities, and will be
capitalized by corporate income taxes, VAT, royalties, bonuses, and
Kazakhstan's revenues from production sharing agreements. The Fund
has a long-term investment function (75%) and a smaller stabilisation
function (25%).
The rules governing the accumulation and use of resources in the
National Funds of Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan are markedly different, and
a comparison is given in Table 5.
In Kazakhstan, the national fund is designed to save resources for
future generations, and avoid undue pressure on the domestic
economy--and layered on this is a stabilization function. President
Nazarbayev made clear at the outset that resources would not be spent on
covering current expenses, but would accumulate in the NFRK for future
generations, as well as for the contingency of economic recession.
Stabilization by the NFRK is achieved by means of 'reference
prices' for gas, oil, and four metals (chrome, zinc, lead and
copper). The nine largest oil companies and three from the metals sector
are subject to transfers based on the reference price. When the targets
are exceeded, surplus tax payments are transferred to the NFRK. On the
other hand, if market prices are below the reference prices, the Fund
provides revenue to the government. The stabilization portfolio must
constitute at least 20% of NFRK assets.
With the Kazakhstan budget in a strong position, and oil prices
rising in the recent past, this strategy has proved entirely workable.
During the first 5 years of its existence the NFRK has accumulated extra
payments made to the republic's budget from major companies
operating in the raw materials (oil and gas) sector. In 2003, the fund
began accumulating proceeds from the sale of state property. The
fund's reserves currently exceed USD 8 billion (see Figure 3).
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The underlying situation in Azerbaijan is different. At the present
time, the economy requires substantial investment for economic
development. The state budget does not have the means to meet this
demand. Therefore, the Azeri government is in the situation of borrowing
resources from the international economic organizations, sometimes with
conditions viewed as unfavourable for the country. There is a difficult
question how far it makes sense to borrow money from international
economic organizations for the country's economic needs and to pay
the debt back later with interest (which would come from the oil fund)
or, alternatively, to spend oil money now directly on the development of
the national economy? Part of the answer depends on the cost of official
borrowing--which is in part on concessional terms. However, there is
also a question whether the rate of return on the international
investments of the fund is higher than would be achieved--subject to
capacity constraints--by investing infrastructure and other reform needs
in the domestic economy.
These differing roles and objectives are reflected in the
investment strategy of the funds.
From its conception, the investment strategy of the NFRK was based
on the rules governing the foreign exchange reserves of the National
Bank of Kazakhstan: eligible assets were low-risk interest-bearing
securities (AA-grade or better). According to the FitchRatings agency
'the NFRK offers a good degree of fiscal and balance of payments
support, but as its assets are still not especially large, this support
is finite. Assets should rise more rapidly during the coming years, in
part related to the timing of additional oil production, although the
authorities might wish to revisit the question of the trigger price to
ensure regular and reliable inflows into the Fund' (FitchRatings,
2003, p. 12). Of course, a prudent strategy of investing resources in
high-quality external assets could be compatible with a more diversified
portfolio approach in the future. (5)
In Azerbaijan, by contrast, the oil fund has a strong commitment to
the financing of investment in the finance the state oil company's
(SOCAR) share of the equity investment in Baku-Ceyhan. This, clearly, is
not a liquid, market-based and diversified investment--rather the
opposite. However, in this particular situation when Azerbaijan needs an
alternative route for its oil to export and where the future economic
prosperity is highly dependent on the implementation of this project,
the investment may be strategically prudent. Moreover, this is not
consistent with the Bird-in-hand rule (BH), (6) which was adopted by
SOFAZ. In contrast, to date Kazakhstan is very cautious in this front
and has been praised by IMF (see IMF, 2004a, b, p. 73).
Examining the current operations of the funds, some pragmatic
difference in philosophy is already to be found in practice:
* In both cases (SOFAZ and NFRK) it was planned that the funds
would not be touched for the first 5 years of their existence, but an
exception has been made in the Azeri case, given the need to support
citizens forced from their historic places of settlement, to build
housing for refugees from the Fuzilin and Agdam regions and to
administer the fund.
* There are, again, marked differences between the two countries in
terms of investment targets. NFRK invests only abroad. In Azerbaijan, by
contrast, the government is using the oil fund to finance the state oil
company's (SOCAR) share of the equity investment in Baku-Ceyhan,
which amounts to approximately USD 170 million. In the Azeri case the
argument is often advanced that without BTC SOFAZ would simply not exist
(Mann, 2003).
One reaction to this would be in terms of institutions--to question
whether it was optimal to create SOFAZ. Without doubt the question of
the creation of the oil fund is quite a complex one. The answer will
require too many factors to be taken into account. The economy needs
investment in order to diversify the economy, the investments could only
come from the hydrocarbon development and therefore savings into the oil
fund could be problematic. Azeri President Ilham Aliyev has already
adopted a long-term oil revenues management strategy for 2005-2025. This
strategy focuses on hydrocarbon resource depletion and maintenance of
macroeconomic stability with the expected growth of oil revenues.
Current efforts to diversify the Azeri economy have remained weak
and structural reforms have stalled. The privatization programme is
still procrastinated and experience resistance. The economy overall is
highly exposed to oil price fluctuations despite the fact that the
country's external balance sheet has been substantially improved as
well as public finances strengthen on the back of rising oil revenues.
An alternative approach to the issue in Azerbaijan would be to
think in terms of transparency and governance. What better example than
how best to use the Azeri fund, given domestic development needs? The
arguments may be finely balanced. The governance challenge, in assessing
the policy issues, is to set out clearly the present goals of the fund,
and a transparent critique of the rates of return on different
strategies. This would facilitate a public debate on the appropriate use
of the fund, in this situation--which differs markedly from that in many
oil-rich economies.
Again, if the conclusion in Azerbaijan were to channel more
resources to domestic development, then this needs to be done in a
transparent way. It could be by diverting more resources to the budget
for public investment. Or it might be by creating a development bank
capitalised by the Oil Fund to issue loans and credits outside the oil
sector. This might assist in stimulating development of the non-oil
sector of the Azerbaijani economy at a time when financial resources are
short, as well as securing an economic return for the fund when the
loans are repaid. However, dedicating resources to domestic investors
would not smooth the economic impact of oil revenues or mitigate the
impact of Dutch Disease.
Transparency and governance
The challenge ahead for both Azeri and Kazakhstani economies is
clear--to ensure that current economic progress is stable and sustained.
This can be achieved only by strengthening structural reforms and
enforcing transparency at every level of the economy. As Glennester and
Yongseokh (2003) showed, transparency is correlated to improvements in
investment and growth performance. Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan are already
known as countries with a low level of transparency and opportunities
for fraud and corruption (see Transparency International's
Corruption Perception Index). Without doubt both countries need to
improve their disclosure of negative practices.
What is true for the economy at large is all the more true for the
resources concentrated in the oil funds. Transparency in the management
of oil revenues is essential to present few interest groups from
appropriating oil resources by allowing a democratic debate and avoiding
corruption and waste of public resources. Part of this initiative is to
increase transparency with respect to revenues by those host country
governments. Resource revenue transparency has been advocated by
international financial institutions, including the IMF (2004a, b). The
concept of transparency is expected to focus initially on the
transparency of the general government, but because of the special needs
of transition economies it should be extended also to relevant
stakeholders (including companies investing in the sector and financial
and strategic investors supporting lending).
Four dimensions of transparency deserve particular attention in
this connection: a clear definition of goals, and rules-based
operations; the public availability of information; and the adequacy of
internal accounting and auditing of the funds; and arrangements for the
appointment of officials and managers. Experience in Azerbaijan and
Kazakhstan is considered briefly below in light of these priorities,
illustrating that transparency is a significant issue for both funds.
The main objective for the management of both NFRK and SOFAZ is
defined to be the investment of capital in such a way that the
international purchasing power of the Funds is maximised, taking into
account an acceptable level of risk. Following also IMF guidelines, the
investment portfolio of the 'oil funds' is best placed abroad.
In sum, both domestic electorate and the international community should
have confidence that the funds are well-managed, transparent, and used
for the purposes set out by law' (Kalyuzhnova and Kaser, 2006, 16).
As to whether the funds are rules-based, in a mechanical sense this
is broadly satisfied. However, in the case of Azerbaijan, the rules have
proved susceptible to an interpretation that dilutes some of the value
of the fund, through deployment of resources for priority domestic
needs. In Kazakhstan, much of the legislation and administrative
infrastructure was borrowed from Norway's oil fund. However, the
closer implementation of the Norway's model based on a non-oil
deficit target rule could be a way to enhance the transparency of the
NFRK. Broader recommendation for Kazakhstan to increase its degree of
transparency include consolidation of the treasury reports and better
integration of all fiscal costs and risks associated with extra
budgeting operations (including NFRK itself).
Recently, in order to establish a long-term strategy for the use
and accumulation of oil revenues the rules governing the NFRK have been
redesigned. Under the current system, fiscal payments from identified
companies in the natural resources sector are subject to transfer to the
NFRK. In 2004, the number of companies was reduced and the transfer of
their fiscal payments is calculated on the basis of a reference oil
price. However, the main criticism of the original reference price (19
USD billion) which was established long time before the oil boom, is
that this does not reflect the true situation. The original rules for
placing resources in the NFRK allowed the government to deplete the
balance if prices were to fall significantly below the reference price.
The practical difficulty here was that the rules were not applied
vigorously, due to the fact that the definitions of oil income and oil
enterprises could be interpreted differently and easily changed,
depending on the intention to save less or more than the rule currently
commits the government to. Overall, even if at first sight the rules
look quite straightforward, the practice demonstrated that the reality
was a complex one with all the computations, etc. The Kazakhstani
authorities intend to fully integrate the NFRK with the budget, and
devise a rule to guide the use of oil revenue, possibly by linking the
non-oil fiscal deficit to the amount of development spending. From 2007
all central government oil revenue will accrue to the NFRK and will flow
into the fund via the budget. Then, some funds will be released back
into the budget to finance development spending. There is an intention
to set up clear limits on how much can be spent in any 1 year. In
addition, for the 3-year periods the ceilings will be set up. These
changes aim to strike the balance between meeting current development
needs and providing a savings cushion for future generations.
Two more general considerations are also relevant:
* It is arguable that the principles of operation should be
formally enshrined in legislation, to guarantee reliable functioning of
the oil fund over the long term. Legitimacy and permanence would be
improved by having the formation of the oil funds come from the
parliaments of the republics, rather than presidential decrees.
* Issues of implementation matter. The relevant question in each
case is not just the principles agreed at the outset but the question
how transparent the implementation is likely to be. (7)
Public availability of information
A first important dimension is the public availability of
information, including the disclosure of payments related to resources,
according to the principles of The Extractive Industries Transparency
Initiative which was announced by UK Prime Minister Tony Blair at the
World Summit on Sustainable Development in Johannesburg, September 2002
(8) Greater transparency enhances the monitoring capacity of civil
society.
In terms of public availability of information, until now the
population of both countries is largely unaware of the existence of oil
funds. (9) However, they should have a primary voice in their
country's development since the citizens of Kazakhstan and
Azerbaijan will face the economic, environmental, human rights, and
social impacts of hydrocarbon development. By involving them in the
process, the problem of corporate and governmental accountability could
be partially solved. The Azeri and Kazakhstani citizens have to know how
much income was taken from the fund, on what grounds, and how that money
was spent. In this regards both countries have expressed their interest
in The Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI). However,
while Azerbaijan has volunteered to become a pilot case of the
Initiative, (10) Kazakhstan was initially hesitant. One of the
transparency challenges for Kazakhstan is to follow-up of this
Initiative proactively, moving towards practical implementation. The new
NFRK rules will no doubt enhance the transparency of hydrocarbon
revenues and their use. In 2005, the decision on Kazakhstan's
participation in the EITI was welcomed by international institutions,
following consultation with oil companies operating in Kazakhstan on
their willingness to participate. There is a direct benefit to
Kazakhstan from joining this initiative. First of all, there is a
unilateral commitment to disclose the oil revenues received by the
treasury from all 51 legal entities operating in the oil and gas
industry; secondly, it motivates every legal entity operating in the
sector to make available to any interested party information on the
amounts of tax they pay, as well as detailed reports on their social and
local content initiatives they pursue in the fulfillment of their PSAs
with the Kazakhstani state; and thirdly, it makes sure that the
information base is available to the general public on the National Fund
of the Republic of Kazakhstan.
Accounting and auditing
In terms of adaptation of best practice in accounting and auditing,
both funds report quarterly in the press on the total amounts of assets,
inflows received, expenditures, and interest earned by the funds. The
funds have their websites. These visible attributes of transparency in
both cases are the main arguments used by the executive directors of the
funds in the debates about transparency.
Since their existence external audits of both funds have been
conducted (by Ernst & Young), the last one is underway. Although the
NFRK has a website, it only gives information on the total National Fund
assets, broken down by portfolio. Commentators have criticized this
point and claim that it demonstrates a greater lack of transparency
compared to Azerbaijan.
An annual audit of the funds is prima facie evidence of
transparency, but it is only the tip of the iceberg as regards high
standards of governance. It is encouraging that in both Kazakhstan and
Azerbaijan increasing emphasis is being laid at present on the
transparency and efficiency of investment processes in the funds. This
should pay close attention to compliance with the rules under which the
funds were set up and in the diversification of investment projects
within the areas of funds' operations.
Appointment of officials and managers
An analysis of the Azeri and Kazakhstani oil funds highlights some
structural weaknesses. In both cases, the funds have been characterised
as representative and participatory. The rule is that the President
approves all the members of the board and all of them are government
officials. This strong control by the executive branch has enabled uses
of the fund that are contrary to its purposes. The official explanation
for this is that the maturity of the society is quite rudimentary and by
allowing other people (for example, the parliament) to decide the
strategy for using oil funds, control over the oil wealth will be lost.
If transparency of the oil funds of the two countries is to be
established in a credible manner, the structure of the fund management
needs to become more representative and less dominated by government.
Only through such a structure can the high level of political influence
be overcome. In Azerbaijan, at the present time, the SOFAZ is in the
process of selecting foreign managers for the placement of its assets in
foreign banks.
By 2003, Kazakhstan saved 63% of its oil-windfall in the NFRK,
which by all standards demonstrates a remarkably prudent fiscal stance
and gives rise to hope for cautious optimism for the future.
CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The experience to date of resource-rich countries in operating oil
funds demonstrates empirically that these are no panacea for the
'paradox of plenty.' Moreover, the path of oil prices over
time does not encourage a view that funds can be designed to achieve an
optimal smoothing of income or assurance of inter-temporal equity. To
the extent that oil funds serve a useful purpose, this is at once a more
modest and more ambitious one. Modest, because a realistic goal is to
achieve some degree of pragmatically based smoothing and inter-temporal
redistribution, with no pretence of optimality. Ambitious, because their
value can lie in reinforcing the transparency, implementation, and
credibility of key fiscal rules--thus addressing at source a number of
the institutional weaknesses that may lie behind the poor performance of
many resource-rich economies.
In Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan, as Wakeman-Linn et al. (2003) stated,
the oil funds are new and therefore 'any judgments about their
success in meeting their stated objectives must, of necessity, be
preliminary'. The establishment of the oil funds is itself a major
change in fiscal practice, but as both of the funds were required to
accumulate funds for 5 years without spending from them (save for
emergency spending on refugees and financing BTC pipeline in
Azerbaijan), the degree to which the stabilization function (as distinct
from the accumulation) has yet to be demonstrated. Indeed, the present
market context of high oil prices is providing some test whether the
existence of the funds will result in greater fiscal restraint.
A long period of time is needed to determine the real impact of the
funds. But the case made in this paper, in the meantime, is the core
importance in these countries of continuing to enhance governance and
transparency of the oil funds in order to maximize the chances of
success. Inevitably this limits government discretion in disposing off
the mineral wealth of the nation. It is, however, essential to build
public support for the funds, and to leverage their economic impact
through a strong influence on market expectations.
By establishing periodic auditing and analysis of the management
performance, it is possible to ensure the sustainability and efficiency
of the management revenue. The fund's assets should be placed
abroad (to provide protection from the populist ideas to help the local
economy by investments from the fund) and greater diversification of the
assets portfolio is required (as it was demonstrated in case of the
NFRK). To date it is difficult to confirm whether SOFAZ and NFRK have
gained public support. The public is hardly aware that such funds exist.
The governments of both the states discussed above need to have a
long-term vision and determination in pursuing their policies of
management of the oil revenues, which should contribute to the
sustainable development. Among these goals, greater confidence in the
transparent management of oil funds, and greater public understanding of
their objectives and operations, are essential in order to safeguard the
sustainability and efficiency of the oil funds. In these respects, there
is a long way to go for both SOFAZ and NFRK.
REFERENCES
ADB. 2005: Key indicators of developing Asian and Pacific
countries. Available at http:// www.adb.org/Statistics/default.asp.
Aliyev, H. 1997: Azerbaijan oil in the world policy. Azerbaijan
Publishing House: Baku.
Auty, R.M. and de Soysa, I. (eds). 2006: Energy, wealth and
governance in the Caucasus and Central Asia. Routledge: London.
Auty, R.M. and Mikesell, R.F. 1998: Sustainable development in
mineral economies. Clarendon Press: Oxford.
Barnett, S. and Ossowski, R. 2003: Operational aspects of fiscal
policy in oil-producing countries, Chapter 3. In: Davis, J, Ossowski, R
and Fwedelino, A (eds). Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in
Oil-Producing Countries. IMF: Washington.
Benabou, R. and Marek, P. 2002: Dynamic inconsistency and
self-control: A planner-doer interpretation. Economics Letters 77:
419-424.
Birdsall, N. and Subramania, A. 2004: Saving Iraq from its oil.
Foreign Affairs, July/August, pp. 77-89.
Damania, R. and Erwin, B. 2004: Resources for sale: Corruption,
democracy and the natural resource curse. Draft Working Paper,
University of Adelaide: Australia.
Davis, J., Ossowski, R. and Fwedelino, A. (eds). 2003a: Fiscal
policy formulation and implementation in oil-producing countries. IMF:
Washington.
Davis, J., Ossowski, R., Daniel, J. and Barnett, S. 2003b:
Stabilisation and saving funds for nonrenewable resources: Experience
and fiscal policy implications. In: Davis, J, Ossowski, R, Daniel, J and
Barnett, S. (eds). Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in
Oil-Producing Countries. IMF: Washington.
Davis, J., Ossowski, R., Daniel, J. and Barnett, S. 2001:
Stabilisation and saving funds for nonrenewable resources. IMF
Occasional Paper 2005.
Delvin, J. and Lewin, M. 2002: Issues in oil revenue management.
Paper to the World Bank/Esmao Workshop in Petroleum Revenue Management,
Washington DC, October 23-24.
Dixit, A. 1996: The making of economic policy: A transaction--cost
politics perspective. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.
Dobronogov, A. 2003: Social protection in low income CIS countries.
The paper was prepared for the Lucerne Conference of the CIS-7
Initiative, January 20-22, 2003. Available at http://
lnweb18.worldbank.org/ECA/CIS7.nsf.
Esanov, A., Raiser, M. and Buiter, W. 2001: Nature's blessing
or nature's curse: the political economy of transition in
resource-bused economies. EBRD Working Paper 66.
EBRD. 2005: Transition Report, London.
ECON Centre for Economic Analysis. 2002: Paradox of plenty: The
management of oil wealth. Report No. 12/02, Project no. 25411,
Commissioned by Statoil.
Fasano, U. 2000: Review of the experience with oil stabilization
and savings funds in selected countries. IMF Working Paper, WP/00/112.
FitchRatings. 2003: International credit analysis: Republic of
Kazakhstan, November.
Gelb, A.H. 1986: Adjustment to windfall gains: A comparative
analysis of oil-exporting countries. In: Neary, JP and van Wijnbergen, S
(eds). Natural Resources and the Macroeconomy. Basil Blackwell and
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Glennester, R. and Yongseokh, S. 2003: Is transparency good for
you, and can the IMF help? IMF Working Paper 132, June.
Gylfason, T. and Zoega, G. 2003: Inequality and economic growth: do
natural resources matter? In: Eicher, T and Turnovsky, S (eds).
Inequality and Growth: Theory and Policy Implications. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Gylfason, T. 2001: Natural resources, education and economic
development. European Econonzic Review 45: 847-859.
Hausmann, R. and Rigobon, R. 2002: An alternative interpretation of
the 'resource curse': Theory and policy implementations, NBER Working Paper No. 9424.
IMF. 2004a: Draft Guide on resource revenue transparency,
Washington DC, December.
IMF. 2004b: Republic of Kazakhstan: Selected issues. IMF Country
Report Bo. 04/362, Washington DC, November.
IMF Country Report. 2005a: Republic of Azerbaijan: Fifth review
under the poverty reduction and growth facility and request for waiver
of performance criteria--Staff Report; Press release on the executive
board discussion; and Statement by the Executive Director for the
Republic of Azerbaijan, No. 05/260, Washington DC, July.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. 1998: The Kazakstani Economy: Indepedence and
Transition. Macmillan Publishing: London, 168pp.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. 2002: Economies and energy, Chapter 3. In:
Kalyuzhnova, Y, Jaffe, AM, Lynch, D and Sickles, R (eds). Energy in the
Caspian Region: Present and Future. Palgrave: Basingstoke.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. and Kaser, M. 2006: Prudential management of
hydrocarbon revenues in resource rich transition economies.
Post-Communist Economies 18(2) (forthcoming).
Karl, T.L. 1997: The paradox of plenty: Oil booms and petro-states.
University of California Press: Berkeley, California.
Kaser, M. 1997: The economies of Kazakhstan and Uzbekistan. The
Royal Institute of International Affairs: London.
Mann, S. 2003: The coming phases of Caspian energy. Presentation at
the International Conference on Sustainable Development and Social
Issues. The Centre for Euro-Asian Studies, The University of Reading,
March 14.
Newbery, D.M. 1981: Oil prices, cartels and the problem of dynamic
inconsistency. Economic Journal 91: 617-646.
Paldam, M. 1997: Dutch disease and rent seeking: The Greenland
model. European Journal of Political Economy 13: 591-614.
Pomfret, R. 1995: The economies of Central Asia. Princeton
University Press: Princeton, New Jersey.
Posner, R. 1975: The social costs of monopoly and regulation.
Journal of Political Economy 83: 807-827.
Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M. 2001: The curse of natural resources.
European Economic Review 45: 827-838.
SOFAZ. 2003: Press release April 16, Baku, Azerbaijan.
State Statistics Committee of Azerbaijan. 2001: Household Budget
Survey, 2001.
Stigler, G. 1975: The citizen and the state: Essays on regulation.
University of Chicago Press: Chicago. pp. 61-77, 78-100.
Tsalik, S. (ed). 2003: Caspasin oil windfall: Who will benefit?.
Open Society Institute. Central Eurasia Project: New York.
Tullock, G. 1997: The economics of income redistribution, 2nd Edn.
Wheatsheaf Press: London.
Van Wijnbergen, S. 1984: Inflation, employment, and the Dutch
disease in oil-exporting countries: A short-run disequilibrium analysis.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 99(2): 233-250.
Wakeman-Linn, J., Mathieu, P. and Van Selm, B. 2003: Oil funds in
transition economies: Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan. In: Davis, J, Ossowski,
R and Fwedelino, A (eds). Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation
in Oil-Producing Countries. IMF: Washington.
Zolotareva, A., Drobyshevskii, Sinel'nikov, S. and
Kadochnikov, P. 2002: The prospects for creating a stabilization fund in
the Russian Federation. Problems of Economic Transition 45(2): 5-85.
(1) My sincere appreciation goes to Mark Casson, Jeff Miller and
Maria Vagliasindi who made valuable criticism and ideas for improvement.
I am grateful for the comments of the anonymous referees. Max
Watson's creative suggestions fundamentally improved the quality of
the paper.
(2) The problem of optimal resource allocation was discussed by,
among others, Barnett et al. (2002) who considered government spending over time, denoted by t. The key assumption is that oil revenue
[Z.sub.t] is certain, constant, and lasts for exactly N periods. The
social planner (government) must choose the optimal path of government
expenditures [G.sub.t] that maximise the social welfare function
discounted over time, subject to a budget constraint and a balance
budget condition for government debt.
(3) For the definition and discussion of Dutch Disease see Davis et
al. (2001), Hausmann and Rigobon (2002), Kalyuzhnova (2002).
(4) Barnett and Ossowski (2003) suggest that the existence of an
oil fund does not alter the relationship between oil export earnings and
government expenditure. They analysed 10 countries with oil funds and 16
without, using the latest oil price upswing 1999-2001. Real expenditure
(deflated by CPI) rose on average by 20%-21% in both groups. They did
not find a difference between the two groups within these countries. To
date the empirical results cannot provide a certain answer to the
question.
(5) It is important to note that already at the present stage the
management of the fund could envisage a longer-term investment horizon
and a broader diversification. Although investments in equity
instruments involve a higher risk of exposure to short-term fluctuations
in market value compared to bonds, historically it has been shown that
they have provided a better average return. The idea that returns on
equities are higher has taken quite a knock with the experience of the
last few years but it still seems to have been true over long enough
(20+ years) periods. Whether risk-adjusted returns are higher depends on
how big an adjustment you make for risk and that depends on the
investor's risk-aversion. Generally only the richest countries (eg
Kuwait) invest any more than a very small proportion of their assets in
equities.
(6) For the definition of BH see IMF, 2004a, b, pp. 50-51.
(7) In April 2003, Kazakh National Bank Chairman Marchenko endorsed
President Nazarbaev's decision to divert over USD 1 billion from a
secret account into the NFRK, telling journalists that 'this was
the right decision from the economic point of view,' although it
may have been flawed from a political or legal perspective (Reuters and
Interfax-Kazakhstan, 2003). The Kazakhstani officials claim that almost
USD 880 million of the USD 1 billion deposited 5 years ago in Swiss bank
accounts was used to pay off pension arrears and support the national
budget. Mr Marchenko refused to reveal how much money the government
still has in foreign bank accounts on the grounds that it is a state
secret.
(8) See http://www.dfid.gov.uk.
(9) Author's interviews with a number of citizen of Kazakhstan
and Azerbaijan in 2002-2003.
(10) In January 2006, the third EITI report has been released in
Azerbaijan.
YELENA KALYUZHNOVA (1)
The Centre for Euro-Asian Studies, The University of Reading,
Whiteknights, PO Box 218, Reading, RG6 6AA, UK. E-mail:
y.katuyzhnova@reading.ac.uk
Table 1: Overview of some resource funds
Country Fund
Algeria Algeria State Fund
Azerbaijan State Oil Fund
Canada Alberta Heritage Saving Fund
Government of Nunavut Trust
Nunavut (Canada)
Chad Revenue Management Plan
Chile Copper Stabilisation Fund
Colombia Oil Stabilization Fund
Iran Foreign Exchange Reserve Account
Kazakhstan National Fund
Kiribati Revenue Equalization Reserve Fund
Kuwait General Reserve Fund
Nigeria Petroleum Trust Fund
Norway Government Petroleum Fund
Oman State General Reserve Fund
Papua New Guinea Mineral Resources Stabilisation Fund
USA Alaska Permanent Reserve Fund
Venezuela Investment Fund for Macroeconomic
Stabilisation
Commencement
Country date Type
Algeria 2000 Stabilisation
Azerbaijan 1999 Stabilisation and saving
Canada 1976 Stabilisation and saving
Government of 1990 Saving
Nunavut (Canada)
Chad 1999 Saving and stabilisation
Chile 1985 Stabilisation
Colombia 1993 Stabilisation
Iran 1999 Stabilisation
Kazakhstan 2000 Stabilisation and saving
Kiribati 1956 Stabilisation
Kuwait 1960 Stabilisation and saving
Nigeria 1995 Stabilisation and saving
Norway 1990 Stabilisation and saving
Oman 1980 Stabilisation
Papua New Guinea 1974 Stabilisation
USA 1976 Stabilisation and saving
Venezuela 1998 Stabilisation
Country Size Performance
Algeria N/A
Azerbaijan USD 1.4 billion N/A
Canada Canadian dollar 12 billion Average
Government of Canadian dollar 475 million Average
Nunavut (Canada)
Chad Not yet funded N/A
Chile USD 2 billion Average
Colombia Average
Iran USD 1.2 billion Average
Kazakhstan USD 8.1 billion N/A
Kiribati $A 677 million at end-2000 Good
Kuwait Provision of public Average
information on the
fund's assets is
prohibited by Law
Nigeria Poor
Norway USD 82 billion Good
Oman USD 2 billion Good
Papua New Guinea Government recently closed Average
the fund
USA USD 22.7 billion Good
Venezuela USD 3.7 billion Poor
We based our assessment only on the funds that already existed by 1998.
Table 2: Pros and cons of the resource funds
For Examples of funds Against
The funds can help Alberta Heritage Funds are no
avoid rent-seeking Saving Fund Alaska guarantee of an
and corruption Permanent Reserve appropriate fiscal
creating the Fund stance and indeed
conditions for are no substitute
proper management for sound fiscal
of the resource and macro-economic
revenue management
Funds could improve Copper Stabilization The rules of the
fiscal policy impact Fund (Chile) management of the
during the time when funds are constantly
prices are high changing under
political pressures
If the funds are Government Petroleum The existence of
sufficiently Fund (Norway) fund could create an
protected from the Revenue Equalization artificial sense of
external influence Reserve Fund security causing the
(including the (Kiribati) need for real fiscal
political discipline to be
pressures), they are abandoned
able to ensure that
resource revenues of
the country are
saved for future
generations
Investing the fund's General Reserve The existence of
assets abroad could Fund (Kuwait) funds encouraged
prevent exchange corruption and fraud
rate appreciation
For Examples of funds
The funds can help Mineral Resources Stabilization
avoid rent-seeking Fund (Papua New Guinea)
and corruption
creating the
conditions for
proper management
of the resource
revenue
Funds could improve Investment Fund for
fiscal policy impact Macroeconomic Stabilization
during the time when (Venezuela)
prices are high
If the funds are Foreign Exchange Reserve
sufficiently Account (Iran)
protected from the
external influence
(including the
political
pressures), they are
able to ensure that
resource revenues of
the country are
saved for future
generations
Investing the fund's Petroleum Trust Fund (Nigeria)
assets abroad could
prevent exchange
rate appreciation
Table 3: Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan: Oil and Oil
Products in Total Export, in percentage, 2002-2005
Country 2002 2003 2004 2005 (a)
Azerbaijan 89 86 83 90
Kazakhstan 50 53 55 61
Source: IMF Country Report No. 05/260
and IMF Country Report No. 05/244.
(a) IMF staff projections.
Table 4: Key socio-economic indicators
for Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan, 2005 *
Indicator Azerbaijan Kazakhstan
1. Minerals as % of exports 90.0 (87.9) 85
2. Human Development Index Rank (2002) 91 78
3. Gini Index, % 36.5 31.3
4. GNI per capita (dollar PPP), 2003 3,380 6,170
5. EBRD Transition indicator, 2005 3- 3
6. GDP index (1989=100) 76.3 101.4
7. Government consumption as % of GDP 6.0 11.4
8. Private sector as % of GDP 60 65
Source: Author's estimations for 2005, figures in brackets for full
year 2004 Rows 1, 5 and 7 Asian Development Bank, Key Indicators of
Developing Asian and Pacific Countries (2005); rows 2, 3 Human
Development Report (2004); rows 5 and 8 EBRD (2004a) Transition
Report 2005 (London, EBRD), arithmetical average of nine indicators
graded 1 to 4+); row 6 UNECE, Economic Survey of Europe 2005, No. 1
(Geneva, United Nations, 2005).
Table 5: Comparison of rules for accumulation and use
of the National Funds of Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan
Azerbaijan
Use of the Fund Profit gained from the Fund's deposits placed in
credit organizations with a high rating is mainly
used for investment purposes.
The Fund's resources are used according to
directions (programmes) confirmed each year by
decrees of the President of the Azerbaijani
Republic.
For the country's socio-economic progress, the
Fund's resources can be used for solving national
problems, and constructing and reconstructing
infrastructure facilities of strategic importance.
Management of The executive director carries out operational
the Fund management of the Fund's activities. He/she is
appointed by the President of the Azerbaijani
Republic.
The executive director of the Fund:
* organizes the current work of the Fund
and manages it;
* prepares proposals on the main directions
(programme) of spending the Fund's resources
and submits them for approval to the President
of the Azerbaijani Republic, along with the
opinion of the Supervisory Council;
* prepares an annual report about the Fund's
activities and submits it to the president
of the Azerbaijani Republic, along with the
opinion of the Supervisory Council;
* prepares a draft estimate of expenses on the
management of the Fund (including expenses on
personnel) and submits it for approval to the
president of the Azerbaijani Republic;
* ensures the preparation of materials on the
basis of instructions from the president of
the Azerbaijani Republic,
* appoints employees of the Fund's administration
to positions established by the law and
dismisses them, and applies measures of
encouragement and reprimand with regard to them;
* ensures the necessary conditions for the auditor
appointed by the president of the Azerbaijani
Republic to conduct audits; publishes in the
press the auditor's opinion reflecting the
Fund's annual activities;
* prepares analytical certificates on the Fund's
activities and submits them to the President of
the Azerbaijani Republic and the Supervisory
Council; implements other authorities in
accordance with the legislation of the
Azerbaijani Republic and this statute.
With the aim of ensuring general supervision over
the Fund's activities, the Supervisory Council is
formed from representatives of relevant state bodies
and public organizations, as well as other people.
The President of the Azerbaijani Republic confirms
members of the Supervisory Council.
The Supervisory Council examines and expresses its
opinion regarding the main directions (programme)
of using the Fund's resources, its annual report
(together with the auditor's opinion attached to
it) and balance, as well as the draft estimate of
the Fund's annual expenses on the basis of the
executive directors representation.
The Supervisory Council holds its sessions when
necessary, but no less than once a quarter. The
Supervisory Council can hold extraordinary sessions
at the initiative of the executive director or half
the members of the Supervisory Council.
The members of the Supervisory Council carry out
their activities on a public basis (without
payment).
Report and The Oil Fund is subordinated directly to the
Accountability President and is accountable to him.
Azerbaijan
The Fund carries out accounting procedures and
statistic reports as established by the law. The
annual financial activities of the Fund have to be
inspected and confirmed by an independent auditor
appointed by the President of the Azerbaijani
Republic.
Kazakhstan
Use of the Fund The Fund could be used:
* for the purpose of execution of its
stabilisation function--in the form of receipts
from the Fund to the republican and local
budgets to compensate for losses to be
determined as the difference between approved
and actual amounts of tax and other mandatory
payments receipts;
* in the form of targeted transfers of the Fund
to the republican and local budgets for the
purposes defined by the Kazakhstani President;
* to cover expenses connected with management of
the Fund and annual external audit conducted.
Management of The President of the Republic of Kazakhstan is:
the Fund
(1) Establishing a Management Council of the
National Fund;
(2) Issuing directives that are binding on the
Council, the Government and the National Bank
with regard to issues relating to the Fund;
(3) Exercising other authorities stipulated in
the rules of the Fund.
With regards to management of the Fund, the
Kazakhstani Government exercises the following
powers:
(1) develop and approve rules for the compilation
of reporting documents and the order for
accumulation and use of the Fund;
(2) develop together with the National Bank and
approve a schedule for the submission of
informational materials and financial
reporting on activities associated with
the management of the Fund;
(3) provide for the submission of a report on
the accumulation and use of the Fund to the
President and information on activities
related to the formulation and use of the
Fund for the Parliament;
(4) ensure that an annual audit of the Fund
is carried out;
(5) ensure that accounting is carried out for
formulating and use of the Fund; and
(6) exercise other powers stipulated by the Rules.
The National Bank is exercising fiduciary management
of the Fund on the basis of a fiduciary management
agreement concluded between the National Bank and
the government.
A consultative and deliberative body (the Council)
is created under the Kazakhstani President for the
purpose of implementing the powers of the President
with regard to the management of the Fund. The main
task of the Council is to provide assistance and
develop recommendations for the President with
regard to issues of the use of the Fund.
Report and Each year by February 1 of the year following the
Accountability reporting year the Government together with the
National Bank has to compile an annual report on
accumulation and use of the fund.
By April 1 of the year following the reporting year
the Government should submit for the approval of the
President, the annual report on accumulation and use
of the Fund together with the results from external
audit.