Markets for purchased farm inputs in Russia.
Serova, Evgeniya ; Shick, Olga
INTRODUCTION
Russian policy makers usually argue that agriculture suffers from
severe decapitalisation due to financial constraints faced by producers.
This view is the basis of the national agricultural policy, which
emphasises reimbursement of input costs to producers and substitutes
government or quasi-government organisations for market institutions.
The present article evaluates the availability of purchased farm inputs,
the efficiency of their use in agriculture, and the main problems in the
development of input markets. It analyses supply and demand, the
emergence of market institutions, and the impact of government policies.
Purchased farm inputs include a wide range of goods. To keep a proper
balance between breadth and depth of analysis, we focus on five groups
of purchased inputs: farm machinery (tractors and harvesters),
fertilisers, fuel, seeds, and animal feed. Three sources of information
were used in the analysis: official national statistics, data from the
2003 BASIS survey of agricultural producers (to evaluate the demand for
farm inputs), and data from a 2001 AFE survey of farm machinery and
fertiliser manufacturers (to evaluate supply).
In the Soviet period, all sectors of the economy, including
agriculture, were served by a state supply system, which delivered
inputs in centrally planned quantities and provided financing through
state banks. The farms paid lower prices for inputs than the
manufacturers' wholesale prices, and the difference was covered
from the national budget. The relative input/output prices were kept
fixed, favouring agricultural producers at the expense of industrial
manufacturers as another way of subsidising agriculture. Price
liberalisation after 1991 aligned the terms of trade in agriculture with
the average world level.
The inevitable rise in the relative prices of farm inputs led to
shrinking machinery stocks and extensification of production,
significantly jeopardising the potential for growth. The declining
demand for inputs affected the supply of domestically manufactured farm
machinery, while fertiliser manufacturers shifted to exports, reducing
their dependence on the domestic market. It is only after the 1998
financial crisis that agricultural recovery has spurred a renewed demand
for farm inputs leading to a certain growth in domestically manufactured
machinery.
SUPPLY OF FARM INPUTS
Farm machinery and fertiliser manufacturing in Russia are highly
concentrated industries. Thus, five plants produce nearly 90% of
tractors, and just two plants produce 95% of grain harvesters. In the
fertiliser industry, 10 manufacturers produce 74% of nitrogen
fertilisers, four manufacturers produce more than 70% of phosphorus fertilisers, and just two plants produce the total output of potassium fertilisers. The concentration trend in the farm machinery industry is
continuing, as the giant machinery manufacturers have recently begun
creating vertical and horizontal holding structures, probably in
anticipation of impending competition from importers. Sales of farm
machinery are also highly concentrated: in 1999-2000, fully 75% of the
market was controlled by Rosagrosnab (a former state monopoly privatised
in the mid-1990s) that operated jointly with the regional
administrations; the remaining 25% were sales through agroholdings and
other corporate farms. Since 2000 the market share of Rosagrosnab and
regional governments has dropped to 55%, primarily due to rapid growth
of agroholdings and corporate farms as channels for machinery sales.
Independent dealer and service networks also began to develop in 2000,
after Rosagrosnab had lost its monopolistic position. These initiatives
often followed reorganisation and management shakeup in the
manufacturing plant, or takeover by a new investor (as in the Rostov and
Krasnoyarsk farm machinery plants). Up to 1999, the standard payment
mechanisms were mutual account offsets or barter deals. Since 1999,
virtually all payments have shifted to bank transfers.
Alongside the giant tractor and harvester manufacturers there is a
group of medium and small plants that manufacture a broad range of farm
equipment (mini-tractors, hitched implements, spare parts and
components) and accept repair and maintenance contracts. The sales
channels of these medium and small manufacturers are much more
diversified than those of the giant tractor and harvester plants (Table
1). They began creating own dealer and service networks earlier than the
giant manufacturers, probably because their products were never entitled to government support. The wider range and the generally lower cost of
equipment manufactured by the medium and small plants have also resulted
in a greater diversity of payment arrangements (Table 2). These
manufacturers accept cash payments and continue to rely on barter deals.
During the Soviet period, Belarus and Ukraine were Russia's
main sources for farm machinery. After the dissolution of the Soviet
Union, imports from countries outside CIS have increased substantially,
and in the late 1990s the share of imported tractors was 67%. High price
is the main obstacle to wider penetration of imported machinery in
Russia. Thus, an imported tractor costs 50% more than a tractor
assembled in Russia or CIS. Imported machinery usually has a significant
quality advantage, but the cost/benefit ratio still remains better for
domestic machinery. Moreover, federal and regional subsidies are
available only for domestic machinery. Three major international
companies (John Deere, Case, and Claas) are vitally interested in
expanding their market share in Russia. So far, however, their attempts
to launch manufacturing or assembly plants have not been successful.
Russia is one of the leading fertiliser manufacturers and exporters
in the world. It ranks first, second, and fifth in world exports of N,
P, and K fertilisers, respectively. About 85% of Russia's
fertiliser output is exported and only 10% is sold domestically (the
remainder is used for further processing). Similarly to farm machinery,
the fertiliser industry has experienced a significant growth since 1998.
This growth, however, has not been in response to demand recovery: it is
attributable to advantageous world prices and the entire additional
output is exported.
All fertiliser plants have been privatised, except those in
Bashkiria and Tatarstan. The 2001 AFE survey has shown that in
state-owned enterprises the domestic sales are mainly to the regional
administration. Private fertiliser manufacturers, on the other hand,
sell very little to regional administrations and most of their domestic
sales are directly to agricultural producers, without any intermediaries
(Table 3). Export accounts are naturally settled by bank transfers
(Table 4). Domestic sales, on the other hand, are predominantly in the
form of barter transactions (eg, 'fertiliser for grain').
DOMESTIC DEMAND
With the onset of market reforms in the early 1990s, agriculture
was faced with a severe cash crunch, which bordered on a total financial
collapse. Lack of financial resources constrained the purchase of farm
inputs, and purchased inputs began to be replaced with land and labour.
Land was treated as a free input because of the prohibition of land
sales and the long-standing Marxist tradition that did not attach any
costs to the use of land; labour was relatively cheap because of the
rapid and uncontrolled slippage of agricultural wages (Bogdanovskii,
2005). Russian agriculture was thus launched on the dangerous path of
decapitalisation and extensification. The stock of tractors and combines
has decreased sharply since 1990; the consumption of fertilisers--the
main factor sustaining intensive agricultural production--dropped by a
staggering 85% between 1990 and 2002 (Figure 1).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
However, price increases have also encouraged a more efficient use
of purchased inputs. In the Soviet era, fertiliser losses on farms
reached 40% of deliveries, while farm machinery had a very short
lifetime because of low quality, careless exploitation, and poor
maintenance. Today, all the fertiliser delivered to the farm is actually
applied; farm machinery remains in use for a much longer time, and old
equipment is often cannibalised for maintenance and repairs. The
reduction of fuel and power consumption in agriculture outstripped the
decrease in production: while agricultural gross product decreased by
40% between 1991 and 2001, the use of gasoline dropped by 76%, diesel
fuel by 63%, and electric power by 51%. These numbers also point to a
more efficient use of purchased inputs in agriculture.
In the mid-1990s, growing liquidity constraints and high
indebtedness of agricultural producers led to proliferation of various
barter arrangements for provision of farm inputs. Federal and regional
programmes offer various commodity credits, while traders and processors
provide inputs to farms that supply them with produce and raw materials.
Even though the farms do not purchase these inputs directly for
themselves, the credit commodity arrangements actively influence the
market demand for inputs by channeling the actual purchases through
market intermediaries. Another active channel for the purchase of farm
machinery and other inputs began to develop in 1998 in the form of
vertically integrated agroholdings, which purchase these factors of
production for their affiliated farms.
An opposite effect on demand for farm machinery can be traced to
changing patterns of machine use in Russian agriculture. In the past, it
was taken for granted that each farm had to have a full complement of
machinery as prescribed by its technology, land endowment, and the
cropping cycle. Even machinery that was needed for a very short time
during the year had to be acquired and held by the farm. To this very
day, the Ministry of Agriculture continues to calculate sufficiency and
shortage of farm machinery based on this 'total coverage'
approach. And yet this is no longer necessary, because various
commercial entrepreneurs (both domestic and foreign) are offering
machinery rentals and custom farming services, often in return for a
share of the harvest. Waves of Turkish tractor and harvester teams move
every year from the south to the north, following the harvest frontier
with their own machinery and equipment. Corporate farms and especially
individual farmers are also willing to rent out their machinery stock
with or without an operator to any producer who happens to suffer from
some shortage. This change of machine-use practices has sharply reduced
the overall demand for new farm machinery, reinforcing the trend
triggered by the decline of agricultural production and the increasingly
parsimonious behaviour due to rising relative prices. Moreover,
machinery purchases are no longer limited to agricultural producers:
upstream and downstream businesses have also begun to enter this market.
USE OF PURCHASED INPUTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE BASIS SURVEY
The use of purchased inputs by agricultural producers is one of the
issues addressed by the 2003 BASIS surveys of corporate and individual
farms in three oblasts (the individual farms were broken down into
peasant farms and household plots). Purchases of diesel fuel and to a
lesser extent gasoline are reported with the highest frequency in the
survey. These seem to be the essential inputs, while all other inputs
are purchased much less frequently. Corporate farms generally show a
higher frequency of input purchases than individual farms (Table 5; they
also purchase larger quantities of inputs because of their larger
size).The gap between corporate farms and peasant farms is particularly
noticeable for purchases of fertilisers and machinery.
Among individual farms, there is a striking difference in the
frequency of input purchases between the larger peasant farms and the
smaller household plots. Peasant farms show a higher frequency of input
purchases for most inputs (Table 5). Two notable exceptions are animal
feed and mechanical field services. Virtually all household plots
purchase animal feed because of their high reliance on livestock
production and their small size (leading to insufficient capacity for
feed production). Very few households have farm machinery of their own,
and this in turn explains the high frequency of household plots that
purchase mechanical field services (ploughing, tilling, harvesting). The
availability of machinery is highest among the corporate farms, which
apparently continue to use the old machinery stocks accumulated during
the Soviet period, while peasant farms rely on new machinery acquired
during the last decade. Still, 85% of peasant farms have at least one
piece of motorised machinery (a tractor, a harvester, a feed combine, or
a truck). Overall, the data in Table 5 seem to suggest that the use of
purchased inputs increases with the increase of farm size from household
plots to corporate farms.
In sharp variance with the Soviet practice, the state no longer
plays a major role as a supplier of farm inputs. The share of input
purchases from regional authorities is very low (Table 6). The emphasis
has shifted to commercial trade channels. These include wholesalers,
fertiliser manufacturers, and gas stations. The reliance on commercial
suppliers is greater for individual farms (the table combines peasant
farms and household plots into one category). Corporate farms have
access to two new supply channels that appeared during the 1990s: they
receive inputs from buyers of agricultural commodities (dairy and meat
processors, vegetable marketers, grain elevators) and also from
'mother companies', that is, commercial holding companies that
acquire farms as part of their business strategy (Rylko and Jolly,
2005). The reliance on the 'mother company' is particularly
noticeable for machinery purchases, where fully 15% of the reported
transactions are organised in this novel way.
The share of inputs purchased through the mother company is
substantially higher in Rostov Oblast, which is a 'hotbed' of
agroholding activity (Rylko and Jolly, 2005). Thus, holding structures
supply 16% of gasoline, 7% of diesel fuel, and 9% of fertilisers to
corporate farms in Rostov Oblast (compared with about 2% of these inputs
in all the three oblasts surveyed). Together with inputs supplied by
buyers of agricultural commodities, the share of vertical integration
arrangements in Rostov Oblast approaches 40% of the total quantity of
purchased inputs. These new channels may be regarded as part of a trend
toward vertical integration of input supply and agricultural production,
which has become possible only with progress in market reforms.
The payment arrangements in the survey are primarily cash and bank
transfers, with individual farms emphasising cash transactions to a
greater extent than corporate farms (Table 7). The prevalence of barter
transactions, which characterised the early 1990 s, is gone. Mutual
offsets of payables and receivables--another payment method that emerged
in the atmosphere of severe cash shortages at the beginning of the
reform--is still practiced by corporate farms for 10%-15% of their
purchases, but practically by none of the individual farms.
Despite anecdotal claims, there is no evidence of price
discrimination against individual farmers in input markets. On the
contrary, individual farms surveyed generally appear to pay lower prices
for inputs than corporate farms, but the differences in most cases are
not statistically significant. Only the prices of diesel fuel and
concentrated feed are statistically significantly lower for individual
farms (but only by about 5%-10%). This may be due to the fact that
individual farms purchase these inputs at market prices, whereas
corporate farms often receive diesel fuel and concentrated feed as part
of government commodity credit programmes, which charge a higher markup.
GOVERNMENT SUPPORT PROGRAMMES FOR PURCHASED INPUTS
Reimbursement of input purchase costs is one of the main tools of
government support to agricultural producers. One-third of the
agricultural support funds in the federal budget is earmarked for input
cost reimbursement. Oblast budgets supplement this allocation in varying
degrees depending on regional policy priorities. Cost reimbursement
programmes include subsidies for fertilisers, fuel, electric power,
elite seeds, and breeding livestock. Soil amelioration activities are
also entitled to government support. An important segment of
agricultural subsidies consists of programmes that partially reimburse the interest expense of producers on commercial loans (this is the only
form of credit subsidy in Russia today). Another category of support
programmes provide medium-term loans that allow machinery leasing. These
loans are administered by regional leasing monopolies subordinated to
the state leasing agency Rosagrolizing and do not go through the
government budget (Yastrebova, 2005).
The various support programmes--both federal and
regional--typically incorporate conditions that severely restrict the
functioning of input markets. Thus, to be entitled to federal subsidies
for fertiliser purchasing and machinery leasing, the producer must deal
with suppliers and manufacturers from a limited list approved by the
government. Most regional support programmes incorporate similar
restrictions, although some oblasts with relatively liberal policies
(most notably, Vologda and Perm) allow producers to sign contracts with
any supplier. Fuel subsidy programmes often take the form of commodity
credits, stipulating payment by delivery of farm products (eg, grain) to
federal or regional stocks.
The effectiveness of support programmes can be assessed (at least
in principle) by comparing the subsidised prices with general market
prices. An attempt has been made to conduct such a comparison for the
corporate farms in the 2003 BASIS survey. The results are summarised in
Table 8 in the form of percentage differences between the subsidised
prices and the market prices: positive differences indicate that
subsidised prices are higher than market prices (ineffective subsidies),
whereas negative differences indicate that subsidised prices are lower
than market prices (effective subsidies). We see from the table that
input subsidies have a mixed effectiveness record across inputs and
across regions. In Rostov Oblast, most subsidised prices appear to be
higher than market prices; only the price of leased tractors is less
than the market price (the price of subsidised gasoline is essentially
equal to market price). In Nizhnii Novgorod Oblast, on the other hand,
subsidised fertiliser and fuel are cheaper, while leased tractors are
more expensive. In Ivanovo Oblast, subsidised diesel fuel is cheaper,
leased harvesters are more expensive, while the price of subsidised
gasoline and leased tractors is essentially equal to the market price
(there are no general fertiliser subsidies in Ivanovo). As we have noted
previously, this price information is highly unreliable: it is based on
very small numbers of respondents and suffers from large data errors.
Yet even this crude evidence is sufficient to raise serious doubts
concerning the effectiveness of input subsidy programmes. There is
clearly a strong need for a careful analytical assessment and revision
of the existing support mechanisms.
Since detailed examination of input subsidies produces such a mixed
picture, we have combined several characteristics of regional support
programmes into a single index that can be used to rank the oblasts by
the level of administrative intervention in agriculture (Table 9).
Vologda, Nizhnii Novgorod, and Perm appear to be the most liberal
oblasts, characterised by the lowest government intervention level. The
agricultural policies of Chuvashia and Chelyabinsk, on the other hand,
are highly interventionist. Ivanovo and Rostov fall somewhere in the
middle on the administrative intervention scale. Table 9 also shows
that, on the whole, rich regions adopt liberal agricultural policies,
while poorer regions are more interventionist. This result is based on a
very small non-representative sample of 7 out of 77 Russian regions and
perhaps we should not be surprised that it is not entirely consistent
with other published findings, which usually indicate that
agriculturally rich regions are more conservative in their policies. As
a result of the different analytical definitions used in these studies,
the relationship between agrarian policies and regional wealth requires
further study.
CONCLUSION
In parallel with the development of markets for farm products, we
are witnessing the emergence of new market channels for farm inputs. The
state no longer has a role as a direct supplier of inputs to
agricultural producers. This function has shifted to wholesalers,
traders, and manufacturers, who sell mainly for cash and bank transfers,
not barter. The strong imperfections that still prevail in input markets
have encouraged vertical integration, with fertilisers, fuel, and
machinery delivered in substantial quantities through internal channels
of large holding structures.
Fuel is the one input that is purchased by most producers.
Fertiliser purchases are reported less frequently, whereas seeds and
animal feed are mostly used from own production (despite lower quality).
It seems that cash shortages are forcing farms to substitute land and
labour--the two cheapest factors of production--for some purchased
inputs (fertilisers, seeds, feed), a process that inevitably leads to
extensification of farm production and abandonment of productivity
improving technologies.
Although the government no longer delivers farm inputs, it has a
strong negative influence on input markets through a wide range of
federal and regional support programmes. Government-sponsored leasing
programmes with their restrictions of approved suppliers and models have
created severe obstacles to the development of dealer networks, which
will have a detrimental effect on the competitiveness of Russian
manufacturers in the long run. The cost reimbursement policy for
fertilisers only increased the demand for this input and encouraged the
export-oriented manufacturers to raise prices in the domestic market. In
regions characterised by lower levels of government intervention we are
witnessing significant growth of competitive trading in both machinery
and fertilisers.
Table 1: Sales channels of medium and small machinery manufacturers
(percent by volume)
1998 1999 2000 2001
Mini-tractors
Regional administration 6 5
Dealers 6 10
Commercial firms 5 13 23 19
Corporate farms 33 2
Peasant farms 32 31 21 17
Household plots 30 38 40 51
Hitched implements, trailers, etc
Regional administration 4 5.5
Dealers 5 9 9.5
Commercial firms 26 20 20 22
Corporate farms 2
Peasant farms 25 17 20
Household plots 74 48 50 43
Spare parts, components, assemblies
Rosagrosnab 90 95 28 40
Dealers 20 10
Commercial firms 10 5 52 50
Source: 2001 AFE survey
Table 2: Structure of payments for medium and small machinery
manufacturers
Percent of respondents Trend
Bank transfers 60 Increasing
Cash payments 17 Increasing
Barter 16 Decreasing
Other 7 Decreasing
Source: 2001 AFE survey
Table 3: Sales channels of private fertiliser manufacturers
(percent by volume)
1998 1999 2000 2001
Regional administration 0.05 0.14 0.08 0.05
Corporate farms 5.5 6.7 4 3
Peasant farms 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.04
Exports 94.4 93.2 95.8 96.9
Source: 2001 AFE survey
Table 4: Structure of payments for private fertiliser manufacturers
Prices
Percent of respondents Trend received
Bank transfers 94 Increases Lowest
Cash payments 0.1 Decreases Lowest
Barter 5.9 Decreases Highest
Source: 2001 AFE survey
Table 5: Use of purchased inputs by corporate and individual farms
(percent of farms reporting input purchases)
Corporate Peasant Household
farms farms plots (n=202)
(n=142) (n=223)
Fertiliser 74 57 5
Gasoline 96 61 32
Diesel fuel 98 98 20
Seeds 49 49 16
Animal feed 32 4 90
Farm machinery 29 7 1
Mechanical field services 18 17 40
Farms without machinery (a) 4 15 80
(a) Tractors, harvesters, feed combines, and trucks.
Source: 2003 BASIS survey
Table 6: Supply channels for corporate and individual farms (percent of
inputs purchased from each channel)
Gasoline
Corporate Individual
Regional government 1 4
Gas station 35 85
Trade 28 8
Buyer 20 2
Mother company 2 --
Other 14 1
Total quantity 100 100
Diesel fuel
Corporate Individual
Regional government 2 3
Gas station 23 55
Trade 30 24
Buyer 28 4
Mother company 2 --
Other 15 14
Total quantity 100 100
Fertiliser
Corporate Individual
Regional government 4 1
Gas station 16 17
Trade 68 76
Buyer 6 2
Mother company 2 --
Other 4 3
Total quantity 100 100
Machinery (a)
Corporate Individual
Leasing 28 21
Manufacturer 14 0
Trade, dealers 24 35
Buyer 0 3
Mother company 15 --
Other farms (used) 19 41
Total 100 100
(a) Percentage of all reported machinery purchase transactions in the
sample (104 transactions for corporate farms, 34 transactions for
individual farms).
Source: 2003 BASIS survey
Table 7: Forms of payment for fertilisers and machinery in corporate
and individual farms
Fertiliser (a) Machinery (b)
Corporate Individual Corporate Individual
Commodity credit 9 7 8 5
Barter 6 2 4 5
Cash 25 54 22 66
Bank transfers 51 34 51 24
Mutual offsets 9 3 16 0
Total quantity 100 100 100 100
(a) Percent of quantity purchased, as reported by 98 corporate farms
and 138 individual farms.
(b) Percentage of all reported machinery purchase transactions in the
sample (104 transactions for corporate farms, 34 transactions for
individual farms).
Source: 2003 BASIS survey
Table 8: Subsidised input prices compared with market prices for
corporate farms in three oblasts (a)
Rostov Ivanovo Nizhnii Novgorod
Fertiliser +5.9 NA -9.8
Gasoline -0.3 +0.1 -4.3
Diesel fuel +5.5 -3.1 -4.1
Tractors -5.1 +0.0 +46.4
Grain harvesters +47.8 +91.0 NA
(a) Price differences in percent: [+ or -] according as subsidised
price higher/lower than market price.
NA: not applicabLe.
Source: 2003 BASIS survey
Table 9: Scores for level of administrative interventions in
agriculture and regional wealth in selected regions 2002 (0 - lowest,
3 - highest) (a)
Vologda Nizhnii Novgorod Perm Ivanovo
Intervention level 0.39 1.01 1.02 1.59
Regional wealth 2.75 2.26 3.00 0.00
Rostov Chivashia Chelyabinsk
Intervention level 1.67 2.20 2.78
Regional wealth 1.55 0.81 2.05
(a) Intervention level score based on number of support programmes for
general services; share of agricultural budget expenditure on food
funds; number of restrictive government decisions affecting
agriculture. Regional wealth score based on share of transfers from
federal budget in regional budget revenues; gross regional product per
capita; ratio of average per capita income to minimum standard of
living.
Source: Calculated by the authors from data provided by regional and
federal statistical organs and by the Russian Ministry of Finance
REFERENCES
Bogdanovskii, V. 2005: Agricultural employment in Russia 1990-2003.
Comparative, Economic Studies 47(1): 141-153.
Goskomstat, various years: Statisticheskii ezhegodnik RF.
Goskomstat, Moscow.
Rylko, D and Jolly, R. 2005: Russia's new agricultural
operation: their emergence, growth and impact. Comparative Economic
StLldies 47(1): 115-126.
Yastrebova, O. 2005: Nonpayments, bankruptcy and government support
in Russian agriculture. Comparative Economic Stzzdies 47(1): 167-180.
EVGENIA SEROVA (1) & OLGA SHICK (2)
(1) AFE--Analytical Centre for Agri-Food Economics and Higher
School of Economics, Moscow, Russia. E-mail: serova@iet.ru;
(2) AFE--Analytical Centre for Agri-Food Economics, Moscow, Russia.
E-mail: shick@iet.ru