Effect of enterprise ownership and foreign competition on internet diffusion in the transition economies.
Clarke, George R.G.
INTRODUCTION
After several, decades of slow economic growth and modest
improvements in productivity, growth accelerated in the United States in
the mid- to late 1990s. Whereas output increased by only 2.8 percent per
year and output per labour hour increased by only 1.0 percent per year
between 1972 and 1995, they increased by 4.9 percent and 2.7 percent per
year respectively between 1995 and 1999 (Gordon, 2000, p. 53). Although
there is considerable uncertainty regarding the reason for the increase
in growth, many observers attributed it to growing investment in
information technology in general and to the Internet in particular. (1)
Although the benefits of information technology are still in dispute,
these changes led to considerable discussion about whether countries
that failed to make similar investments would be left behind as growth
in technologically more advanced economies accelerated. This concern was
especially marked for low- and middle-income countries, where Internet
access and the use of information technology is far less common.
The digital divide between the rich developed world and the poor
developing world is visible even when comparing the mainly middle-income
economies of Eastern Europe and Central Asia with high-income OECD countries. Over 25 percent of the inhabitants of high-income OECD
countries had Internet access in 1999, compared to about 6-7 percent of
people in Central Europe and the Baltics, and 1-2 percent of people in
South Eastern Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States.
The importance of foreign investment as a source of technological
transfers suggests that encouraging foreign investors from developed
countries to invest in developing countries might reduce the disparity between rich and poor countries. (2) In addition to increasing the use
of information technology among enterprises that directly receive
inflows of foreign investment, several mechanisms might encourage
diffusion among domestically owned enterprises in the host economy. For
example, workers and managers who leave foreign-owned enterprises to
join existing domestic firms might encourage their new employers to copy
the techniques used by foreign-owned enterprises (including more
intensive use of information technology). Alternatively, domestic
enterprises, including competitors and upstream and downstream firms,
might simply observe and copy the foreign-owned enterprises'
business techniques. Since the benefits associated with network
industries are greater when coverage is higher, enterprises that use the
Internet will generally have an incentive to encourage up- and
downstream firms to adopt it. Further, although foreign-owned
enterprises have strong incentives to prevent domestic competitors from
copying their business models, some leakage, especially of generic
knowledge such as use of information technology, seems inevitable.
Finally, foreign-owned enterprises' demand for Internet services
might encourage the formation of support companies (eg, web-hosting or
web-design companies) that can then sell their services to other
companies in the host country.
Using enterprise-level data from 21 low and middle income economies
in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, this paper looks at whether foreign
investment increases Internet access in host countries. First, it looks
at whether foreign-owned firms appear to be more likely to have Internet
access than their domestic counterparts. Second, it looks at whether
domestically owned enterprises competing either with foreign-owned
enterprises operating in the host country or with imports also appear
more likely to have access to the Internet--something that might
indicate diffusion due to foreign trade or investment. Finally, the
paper looks at whether foreign direct investment (FDI) appears to
increase Internet access for enterprises other than the foreign-owned
firms and their direct competitors in the host country. In general,
there appears to be strong evidence that foreign trade and investment
encourage higher levels of Internet access throughout the host economy.
Although the recent discussion on the 'digital divide'
between developing and developed countries makes the question of
Internet access interesting in its own right, the topic is also of
interest because of its relationship with more general questions about
international transfers of technology between developing and developed
countries. Over the past decade, a large literature has emerged looking
at how enterprises in developing countries gain access to new
technologies, often focusing on the role of foreign investment and
trade. In general, although foreign investment appears to result in
improved productivity in the enterprises that receive the investment,
there is less evidence of broad spillovers to the economy as a whole.
However, since most studies have focused on the effect of foreign
investment on productivity, it is possible that the negative results
regarding spillovers are due to the short-term pressure that foreign
entry puts on domestic enterprises through product market competition,
rather than a lack of technological transfers. (3) Since this study
looks at the adoption of a new technology directly, it is a useful
complement to the existing literature since it avoids the possibility
that pecuniary externalities will obscure technological spillovers.
EFFECT OF FOREIGN INVESTMENT ON ACCESS TO TECHNOLOGY
Although R&D expenditures are low in developing and transition
economies, enterprises in these countries might gain access to new
technologies in other ways, including foreign direct investment, joint
ventures with foreign firms, licensing, and imports of capital goods.
(4) Of these methods, foreign ownership is often seen as one of the most
effective ways for enterprises in developing and transition economies to
gain access to new technologies. In addition to giving access to hard
technological knowledge (eg, blueprints, product designs and machinery),
foreign investment might also lead to transfers of generic knowledge
(eg, improved management techniques or experience using information
technology), which might be harder to transmit through methods such as
licensing or imports of capital goods. Foreign investment might be
especially effective in Eastern Europe and Central Asia due to their
relatively large stock of skilled engineers and scientists and domestic
enterprises' relative inexperience with modern marketing and
management before the start of the transition.
Since it is hard to directly assess the effect of foreign
investment on technology transfers, most studies have focused on the
effect of foreign ownership on productivity. In general, there is strong
evidence that foreign investment improves productivity in enterprises in
developing and transition economies, with many recent studies finding
that productivity is higher and productivity growth faster in
foreign-owned enterprises in these countries. For example, in a recent
study using panel data from Venezuela, Aitken and Harrison (1999) find
that foreign ownership increases productivity in small, but not large,
manufacturing plants, even after controlling for plant-specific effects.
In contrast, Haddad and Harrison (1993) found that foreign-owned
enterprises in Morocco were more productive than wholly domestically
owned enterprises, but that their productivity grew more slowly. Since
the start of the transition, many studies have looked at the effect of
foreign ownership on productivity and productivity growth in Eastern
Europe and Central Asia, generally finding that foreign-owned
enterprises are more productive than other enterprises. (5)
Although it might not be surprising that foreign-owned enterprises
are more efficient than other enterprises in developing and transition
economies, foreign ownership might have broader benefits for the economy
as a whole. In addition to affecting the technology, and productivity,
of the recipient firm, foreign investment might have spillover benefits
for other enterprises in the host country. Saggi (2000) lists several
potential spillovers including:
1. 'Demonstration effects', where domestically owned
enterprises are able to observe the technologies that the foreign-owned
enterprise uses and the goods that it produces and can imitate the
production processes or reverse engineer products, allowing the
foreign-owned enterprises' technologies to spread throughout the
economy.
2. Labour turnover, where domestic enterprises hire former
employees of the foreign-owned enterprise gaining access to the
foreign-owned enterprise's products or processes.
3. Vertical linkages, where foreign-owned enterprises transfer
technologies or provide technical support to the enterprises that are
their suppliers or customers or to whom they sub-contract work.
Saggi (2000) distinguishes between these 'pure'
externalities and pecuniary externalities that result from the effect of
foreign investment on market structure.
Although the theoretical possibility of spillovers to other
enterprises is attractive, there is little empirical evidence to support
the assertion that there are large spillovers associated with foreign
investment. First, although some studies have round that the mechanisms
that might transmit spillovers are common, others have round little
evidence of them. (6) Second, several recent studies that have looked
for evidence of spillovers by looking at the effect of foreign entry in
a given sector on the productivity of domestically owned enterprises
have failed to find strong results.
In the 1970s and 1980s, a large number of studies looked at
industry-level data, generally finding that productivity and
productivity growth were higher in sectors with significant foreign
investment. (7) However, as pointed out in Aitken and Harrison (1999, p.
611), if foreign investors are attracted to sectors that are more
productive, domestic firms in these sectors would appear more productive
than in other sectors even if spillovers were not important. To try to
control for self-selection into industries where domestic enterprises
are more efficient, several recent studies have used firm-level data,
generally finding little evidence to support the assertion that
spillovers are important. In fact, several studies have found that
foreign entry might actually harm the productivity of their domestically
owned competitors. (8) For example, using data from Morocco in the
1980s, Haddad and Harrison (1993) round that productivity growth was
slower for domestic firms in sectors with high foreign investment than
it was for firms in other sectors, although the difference was not
statistically significant. In addition, Aitken and Harrison (1999) round
that foreign investment in a sector actually reduced productivity for
domestically owned plants in Venezuela. In a similar analysis for the
Czech Republic, Djankov and Hoekman (2000) also round that foreign
investment reduced the productivity of wholly domestically owned
enterprises. One plausible explanation for the negative effect on
domestically owned enterprises might be that foreign entry affects
market structure. Aitken and Harrison (1999, p. 607) note:
If imperfectly competitive [domestic] firms face fixed costs of
production, a foreign firm with lower marginal costs will have an
incentive to increase production relative to its domestic
competitor. In this environment, entering foreign firms producing
for the local market can draw demand from domestic firms, causing
them to cut production. The productivity of domestic firms would
fall as they spread their fixed costs over a smaller market, forcing
them back up their average cost curves. If the productivity decline
from this demand effect is large enough, net domestic productivity
can decline even if the multinational transfers technology.
This study looks at whether domestically owned enterprises that
competed with foreign enterprises were more likely to adopt a new
technology (ie, access to the Internet), not at the effect of foreign
entry on domestic productivity. This allows us to identify whether
foreign investment encourages the adoption of new technologies, without
being concerned about negative effects on market structure.
When considering the results from the paper, it is important to
keep two important points in mind. A first point is that even if
enterprises competing with foreign-owned firms are more likely to adopt
the new technology (ie, access to the Internet) than enterprises
competing with domestically owned firms, this would not rule out the
possibility that foreign entry has a negative impact on the productivity
of domestic enterprises. Even if domestically owned enterprises
competing with foreign enterprises are more likely to adopt the new
technology than other domestic enterprises, this does not necessarily
imply that they are able to use if effectively to improve productivity.
(9) Consequently, it might have little impact on overall productivity.
Further, even if adoption does raise productivity, it would still be
possible that negative pecuniary externalities might outweigh any
positive spillovers from the adoption of the new technology.
A second point is that the paper looks at the adoption of a
specific technology with some characteristics that make adoption and
diffusion easier than they would be for other technologies. One
important difference between Internet access and other technologies is
that the human capital that enterprises need to gain access to the
Internet is not highly firm specific. This will make it easier for
Internet use to spread through the economy than for firm or
industry-specific technologies that require people with very specialised
skill sets and mean that it is plausible that 'demonstration
effects' might be important for the entire economy, not just for
enterprises that are direct competitors. For example, firms will often
be able to outsource their Information Technology (IT) needs, reducing
the costs associated with adoption. In practice, access to support
services for IT does not appear to be an especially severe problem in
many low and middle-income countries. For example, 82 percent of
enterprises in Peru reported that business support services were
available in the area of Information Technology. Of these, 81 percent
reported that services were affordable and, of these, 73 percent
reported that they used them. Most users (96 percent) reported that
service quality was either good or very good. (10)
One additional factor that might make diffusion of Internet use
faster and easier than the diffusion of other technologies is that some
basic, but useful, processes (eg, e-mail or web use) can be adopted
easily. This appears to be have been the case in many low and
middle-income countries at the end of the 1990s (ie, when the data used
in this paper were collected). Using data from a 1998 survey of
International Finance Corporation (IFC) client companies in 16 low- and
middle-income countries, Daly and Miller (1998) round that although many
enterprises reported using the Internet to send e-mail to other
enterprises (74 percent of industrial enterprises) and to conduct
Internet searches (60 percent of industrial enterprises), few reported
using it in more sophisticated ways. For example, only nine of 113
enterprises reported that the Internet was even slightly useful for
conducting on-line financial transactions. Further, Daly and
Miller's (1998) results probably overestimate Internet use in low-
and middle-income countries, especially for more sophisticated purposes.
They note that users were probably more likely to respond to their
survey than non-users and that IFC client companies were probably more
technologically sophisticated than non-clients. Overall, these results
suggest that initial decisions to start using Internet-related services
do not require high levels of technical or financial sophistication,
making diffusion relatively easy.
EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Data
The main source of data used in this paper is the World Business
Environment Survey (WBES), a cross-sectional survey of industrial and
service enterprises conducted in mid-1999 by the World Bank and several
other agencies. (11) The main purpose of the WBES is to identify
perceived constraints on enterprise performance and growth in developing
and transition economies. The survey, therefore, has a large number of
questions on how taxation, regulation, the performance of the financial
sector, the institutional environment and corruption affect business
operations. In contrast, the survey includes little information on
enterprise characteristics or performance; although some information on
assets, sales, broad sector of operations, ownership, employees, and
enterprise growth was collected, detailed balance sheet information and
profit and loss statements were not collected from participating
enterprises. Further, although the WBES asked similar questions in the
80 countries, there were some differences between regions. For the
purpose of this study, the most important difference was that questions
on Internet access were asked only in Eastern Europe and Central Asia.
(12)
In Eastern Europe and Central Asia, about 33 percent of enterprises
in the WBES sample reported having access to the Internet (see Table 1).
(13) However, this varied greatly between countries. Enterprises in
Slovenia were most likely to report having access to the Internet (84.8
percent), while enterprises in Azerbaijan were least likely to report
having access (7.8 percent). In general, enterprises in the CIS were
less likely to report having access to the Internet than in any other
region (see Figure 1). To control for country difference that might
affect Internet access, either a set of country dummies or a set of
country control variables are included in the analysis. The
country-level control variables include telephone lines per 100
inhabitants, to control for development of the telecommunications sector, per capita income, urban population, and size of the country
(see Table 1).
The main variables of interest are related to the enterprise's
interactions with foreign enterprises. These include whether the
enterprise has any foreign ownership (see Table 1), the overall level of
FDI and imports into the country (see Table 1), and whether its main
competitors were either foreign-owned enterprises producing in the home
market or imports (see Table 2). Since most foreign investment in these
countries is from the industrialised economies, where Internet access is
more common than in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, it seems plausible
that foreign-owned enterprises will be more likely to have access to the
Internet than domestically owned enterprises. (14)
The information on the enterprises' competitors comes from a
question that enterprises were asked about the main source of
competition they faced in domestic markets. If there were substantial
demonstration or labour turnover effects, enterprises facing competition
from foreign-owned enterprises should be more likely to adopt similar
technologies to foreign competitors than other enterprises. Further, if
demonstration effects require direct observation or only occur when
domestically owned companies hire former employees of their foreign
competitors, then the effect of competition from foreign-owned local
enterprises should be greater than the effect of competition from
imports. Finally, if spillovers from foreign ownership are large, then
foreign direct investment in other sectors of the economy might affect
enterprises that are not direct competitors. Consequently, measures of
total FDI and imports are also included in the analysis with
country-level controls. (15)
In addition to providing information on Internet access, the survey
also provided additional information on the enterprise's
performance (see Table 1), the enterprise's largest shareholder,
how many competitors the enterprise faced in domestic markets, how many
full-time employees the enterprise had and the enterprise's sector
of operations (see Table 2). (16) These are included in the analysis to
control for enterprise-specific factors that might affect whether the
company has Internet access. Since Internet access might affect
enterprise performance rather than performance affecting Internet
access, the analysis is conducted both with and without these variables.
Econometric model
The probability that enterprise i in country j has access to the
Internet is assumed to be a function of a vector of enterprise
characteristics ([X.sub.ij]) and country characteristics ([Z.sub.j]).
The enterprise characteristics include ownership, sector of operations,
size, how the enterprise was established, competition faced by the
enterprise, and, in some specifications, enterprise performance. The
country characteristics include per capita income, openness to trade and
investment, telephone coverage, population and urban population. The
probability of enterprise i having access to the Internet is
Prob(Internet [Access.sub.ij]) = [phi] ([alpha] + [beta][X.sub.ij]
+ [gamma][Z.sub.j])
where [phi](*) is the standard normal distribution and ([alpha],
[beta], [gamma]) is the vector of coefficients. The model is estimated
using standard maximum likelihood estimation. All estimated models in
Table 3 include dummies indicating sector of operations and size of the
enterprise (see Table 2 for categories). Results from the model are
shown in Table 5.
Econometric results
Foreign shareholdings and largest shareholder
The coefficient on a dummy variable indicating that the enterprise
has some foreign shareholders is positive and statistically significant
(see Table 5, column 1). This suggests that enterprises in Eastern
Europe and Central Asia that are at least partially foreign-owned are
more likely to have access to the Internet than similar enterprises
without foreign ownership. The results are similar whether country-level
control variables or country dummies are used to control for country
differences (see Table 5, columns 1 and 2). After controlling for
whether an enterprise has any foreign ownership, enterprises with
foreign companies as their largest shareholder do not appear any more
likely to have access to the Internet than enterprises where the foreign
owner is only a minority shareholder. (17) However, if the dummy
variable indicating any foreign ownership is dropped, the dummy indicating that the largest shareholder is foreign becomes statistically
significant and large (see Table 3, columns 5 and 4). (18) One concern
regarding these results is that foreign enterprises might be especially
likely to enter sectors and countries where Internet access is
particularly common. Although the other control variables (eg, sector
dummies, country controls and country dummies, and the dummies
indicating whether the enterprise is competing with foreign or domestic
enterprises) control for this to some degree, this remains a concern.
(19)
Foreign ownership has a large effect on the probability that the
enterprise has Internet access. Whereas a state-owned enterprise without
any foreign shareholders has a 24.4 percent chance of having Internet
access (see Table 4), a foreign-owned enterprise with a foreign company
as its largest shareholders is twice as likely to have access to the
Internet (48.8 percent). A state-owned company with some foreign
ownership (ie, a company where the government is the largest shareholder
but where a foreign company has a minority stake) has a 46.8 percent
chance of having access to the Internet (see Table 4).
In addition, insider-owned enterprises generally appear to be less
likely to have access to the Internet than other enterprises. The
coefficient on the dummy variable indicating employee ownership is
negative and statistically significant whether country controls or
country dummies are included in the analysis, indicating that
employee-owned enterprises are less likely to have Internet access that
state-owned enterprises. Furthermore, the coefficient on employee
ownership is smaller than the coefficient on other private ownership,
suggesting that employee-owned enterprises are also less likely to have
Internet access than outsider-owned private domestic enterprises. (20)
In contrast, the null hypothesis that the coefficients for manager and
employee-owned enterprises are equal cannot be rejected. (21)
The coefficient on the dummy variable indicating that the
enterprises' managers are the largest shareholders is also
negative, suggesting that manager-owned enterprises are less likely to
have Internet access than state-owned enterprises. However, the
coefficient is statistically insignificant when country controls are
included in the analysis. Manager-owned enterprises also appear to be
less likely to have Internet access than 'other' private
enterprises. (22) Based upon the point estimates of the coefficients in
column 1 of Table 3, manager-owned enterprises have a 17.1 percent
chance of having Internet access; employee-owned enterprises have a 17.5
percent chance; while similar state-owned enterprises have a 24.4
percent chance (see Table 4).
Competition from foreign-owned enterprises
Enterprises who saw either foreign-owned enterprises producing
domestically or imports as their main competition were more likely to
have Internet access than enterprises that saw domestically owned
enterprises as their main competition. In both cases, the effect is
quite large. A (state-owned) enterprise whose main competition is
foreign-owned enterprises producing domestically has a 34.5 percent
chance of having Internet access, an enterprise whose main competition
is imports has a 34.9 percent chance, whereas an enterprise whose main
competition is domestically owned enterprises has only a 24.4 percent
chance (see Table 4).
The result for competition with foreign-owned enterprises producing
domestically is consistent with the hypothesis that demonstration or
labour turnover effects affect enterprises' decisions to adopt new
technologies (access to the Internet in this case). However, the
coefficient on the dummy variable indicating that imports are the
enterprise's main competition is similar in size to the coefficient
indicating that foreign-owned domestic enterprises are the main
competition. (23) If demonstration effects were important either because
of direct observation of foreign-owned enterprises' operations or
because domestically owned enterprises hire workers from foreign-owned
plants, the coefficient on the dummy variable indicating competition
with foreign-owned enterprises producing in the country should be larger
than the coefficient indicating competition with imports. Taken
together, these results suggest that although openness to trade and
investment increase the likelihood that domestically owned competitors
have Internet access, foreign investment is no more effective than trade
in this respect.
One final question is whether the difference between foreign
enterprises and domestic enterprises is greater in areas where
enterprises are competing with foreign-owned enterprises than in areas
where they are competing with domestic enterprises. To test whether this
is the case, interaction terms between foreign ownership and competition
are included in the base analysis (see Table 6, columns 1 and 2). The
coefficients on the interaction terms are statistically insignificant
indicating that foreign enterprises are equally more likely to have
Internet access than similar domestic enterprises whether they are in
sectors where their main competition is other foreign enterprises or
they are in sectors where their main competition is domestic enterprises
(see Figure 2).
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Enterprise origins and competition
Enterprises that were established as either joint ventures or as
private enterprises (ie, de novo private enterprises) were more likely
to have access to the Internet than similar enterprises that either
remained state-owned or had been privatised. The difference is quite
large, with de novo enterprises having a 38.0 percent chance of having
Internet access, joint ventures having a 66.0 percent chance, while
state-owned or privatised enterprises have only 24.4 percent and 27.1
percent probabilities respectively. Finally, enterprises with no
effective competition were generally more likely to have Internet access
than enterprises with either one to three competitors or enterprises
with more than three competitors (see Table 3). However, this result is
not highly robust. When variables indicating enterprise performance are
included in the analysis (see columns 5 and 6), the coefficient drops in
both size and significance level. One plausible reason for this finding
might be that enterprises facing little effective competition perform
better, giving them the funds needed to invest in new technologies, such
as Internet access.
Country-level measures of openness
In addition to the enterprise-level variables discussed above, the
analysis also includes some country-level variables. Since these
variables become collinear with the dummies once the country dummies are
added, they are dropped when country dummies are included (see Table 3,
columns 2, 4 and 6). The coefficient on foreign direct investment is
statistically insignificant suggesting that FDI does not have a large
effect on the probability that enterprises other than the enterprise the
foreign company invests in (and the enterprise's competitors) have
Internet access.
One concern is that the result for FDI might be affected by the
inclusion of the oil-producing economies of Central Asia. FDI in two of
these economies in particular, Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan, has been far
higher than in any other country in the CIS since the start of
transition. (24) However, this investment has almost exclusively flowed
to the off sector and it is possible that spillovers to the rest of the
economy from FDI in this sector are smaller than the spillovers from
other FDI. (25) The results omitting the oil-producing economies of
Central Asia are consistent with this hypothesis. Once these economies
are omitted, the coefficient on FDI increases in magnitude and becomes
statistically significant at a 1 percent level (see Table 6, columns 3
and 4). (26) The point estimate of the elasticity on FDI increases to
0.21 when these economies are omitted.
One puzzling result is that openness to trade at the country level
appears to have a negative impact on Internet access; the coefficient on
imports as a share of GDP is statistically significant and negative (see
Table 3). The point estimate of the coefficient suggests that a 1
percent increase in imports decreases the probability that domestically
owned enterprises have access to the Internet by 0.55 percent (see Table
5). Given that enterprises competing with imports appear more likely to
have access to the Internet than enterprises competing with domestic
enterprises, it might be surprising that the broader spillover effects
from imports are negative.
To investigate this further, we divide imports into imports of raw
materials (ie, imports of fuel, minerals, ores, and food) and imports of
manufactured goods. (27) When this is done, the coefficient on imports
of raw materials is negative and statistically significant, while the
coefficient on imports of manufactured goods is positive, although
statistically insignificant (see column 5 in Table 6). This suggests
that imports of raw materials and imports of manufactured goods have
different spillover effects on Internet access. One plausible
explanation for this is whereas, on average, 72 percent of imports of
manufactured goods in the countries in this sample come from high-income
countries, only 31 percent of raw material imports come from these
countries. Given that Internet access is significantly higher in
high-income countries than in low- and middle-income countries, imports
from high-income countries might have positive spillover effects, while
imports from other low- and middle- income countries do not. Consistent
with interpretation, when imports are split into imports from
high-income countries and imports from low- and middle-income countries,
the coefficient on imports from high-income countries is statistically
significant and positive and the coefficient on imports from low-income
countries is statistically significant and negative (see column 6 in
Table 6). Unfortunately, the questions on the enterprises' main
competitors do not ask whether the competitors are from high-income or
low-income countries. Because the question on the enterprises' main
competitors pools enterprises competing with imports from both low- and
high-income countries, the impact of competition from imports from
high-income countries might be greater than the estimated coefficient
suggests. (28)
Country controls
The other country controls are also significant at, at least, a 5
percent level throughout the analysis. In general, enterprises in
countries with higher per capita income, with larger urban populations
and smaller countries appear more likely to have access to the Internet.
In addition, enterprises in countries with more developed
telecommunications systems appear to be more likely to have access to
the Internet. A 1 percent increase in the number of mainlines per 100
inhabitants increases the probability that an enterprise has access to
the Internet by 0.5 percent. This result is consistent with results from
a country-level analysis in Dasgupta et al. (2000), which suggest that
that cross-country differences in Internet use reflect the number of
fixed mainlines per capita in a country. Including country dummies does
not appear to either affect the enterprise-level results or to greatly
increase the explanatory power of the analysis--the pseudo-[R.sup.2] is
similar whether country dummies or country controls are included (see
Tables 3 and 6). (29)
Enterprise performance
As a final set of control variables, some additional indicators of
enterprise performance are also included in the analysis, including
employment and sales growth--in general, better performing enterprises
should contract less than worse performing enterprises--and percent of
sales to the government. Since there is a large literature showing that
foreign-owned enterprises in the transition economies generally perform
better than domestically owned enterprises along a variety of
dimensions, foreign-owned enterprises might be more likely to have
access to the Internet simply because their stronger performance gives
them better access to investment resources. (30) Similarly,
employee-owned enterprises, which appear to perform worse than other
enterprises, might have fewer resources for investment. (31)
In general, better performing enterprises appear to be more likely
to have access to the Internet than worse performing enterprises (see
Table 3), perhaps because they have more resources available for
investment in new technologies. However, this has virtually no effect on
other results. Most notably, the coefficients on foreign- and
insider-ownership are virtually unchanged and remain highly significant
even after these performance measures are added to the analysis. This
suggests that better (worse) performance is not the only reason for the
higher (lower) levels of access to the Internet for foreign- (employee-)
owned enterprises.
Although performance might affect Internet access, Internet access
might also affect enterprise performance, introducing the possibility of
reverse causation when the performance variables are included.
Therefore, the analysis is conducted both with and without these
variables (see columns 1 and 2 and columns 5 and 6 in Table 3
respectively). In practice, the main results are virtually identical
whether these performance indicators are included in the analysis or
not.
CONCLUSIONS
The results from this study support the assertion that foreign
investment increases Internet access for enterprises in low and
middle-income countries in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. The
strongest result is that Internet access is more common among
enterprises that are partly foreign-owned than it is among enterprises
that are fully domestically owned. The effect of foreign ownership
appears large--enterprises that are partly foreign-owned are almost
twice as likely to have access to the Internet as state-owned and
privately owned enterprises with no foreign ownership. Further, the
correlation between foreign ownership and Internet access does not seem
to be simply because foreign-owned enterprises tend to outperform other
enterprises in the transition economies, giving them easier access to
financing. The correlation remains statistically significant even after
including variables to control for enterprise performance and indicators
of the level of competition that the enterprise faces in domestic
markets.
The results also suggest that foreign investment has positive
spillovers for other domestically owned enterprises with respect to
Internet access. In particular, enterprises that compete with either
foreign-owned domestic enterprises or imports are more likely to have
Internet access. Since competition with imports and foreign-owned
domestic enterprises both appear to increase the likelihood, this
suggests that proximity is not very important. Although past studies
(eg, Aitken and Harrison, 1999) have found that competition from
foreign-owned firms reduces the productivity of their domestic
competitors, the negative effect of foreign entry on the productivity of
domestic competitors is thought to be due to foreign entry affecting
market structure. Since this study does not address the question of the
size, or even existence, of benefits related to Internet access, it is
unclear whether positive technological spillovers round in this study
would outweigh pecuniary externalities.
Finally, Internet access appears more common in countries that are
more open in terms of foreign investment and trade. In particular,
enterprises are more likely to have Internet access in countries that
import more from high-income countries. In contrast, imports from low-
and middle-income countries are negatively correlated with Internet
access. In addition, Internet access in more common in countries with
higher levels of FDI even after controlling for other factors (eg,
urbanisation, per capita income and telecommunications infrastructure)
that might also affect Internet access. It is important to note that the
result for FDI holds only after the oil-exporting economies of Central
Asia are excluded from the analysis. This strongly suggests that FDI
does not always increase the likelihood that a domestic enterprise will
have Internet access--investment in a single (extractive) sector might
not have the same beneficial effect as other types of investment.
Other factors also affect Internet access. Employee-owned
enterprises are less likely to have access to the Internet than
outsider-owned private enterprises or state-owned enterprises. This
holds when country dummies and performance measures are included in the
analysis, suggesting that it is not due to employee ownership being more
common in countries where Internet access is restricted or to
employee-owned enterprises finding it harder to finance new investment.
Finally, enterprises in countries with better telephone systems are more
likely to have Internet access even after controlling for income and
urbanisation. This result is consistent with results from a
country-level study by Dasgupta et al. (2000), which suggests that the
number of mainlines per capita explains most of the gap between
developed and developing countries with regards to Internet
connectivity. This stresses that steps that would improve the
performance of providers of fixed-line telephone services (eg,
privatising state-owned fixed line monopolies) would increase Internet
access.
The presence of positive spillovers from foreign investment
suggests that it might be appropriate for governments to take steps to
encourage foreign direct investment. However, although there is some
evidence that investment in information technology has improved the
productivity of enterprises in the US, there is very little evidence on
the how great the effect of Internet access or investment in information
technology is on firm performance in developing or transition economies.
(32) Although the lack of evidence regarding the effect of Internet
access on firm performance in the transition economies argues against
taking dramatic steps to encourage foreign investment, it does give
added weight to arguments for improving the business environment. For
example, there is strong evidence that corruption, which is a serious
problem in many transition economies, discourages foreign investment and
slows economic growth. (33) Since reducing corruption and taking other
steps to improve the business environment would both encourage foreign
investment and improve the functioning of the domestic economy, they
would benefit the domestic economy even if Internet access had little
short-term impact on productivity or growth.
Acknowledgements
The data used in this paper are from the World Business Environment
Survey (WBES) [c] 2000 The World Bank Group. I thank an anonymous
referee, L. Colin Xu, Ricardo Martin and participants at the 2003
Transformation, Integration and Globalization Economic Research (TIGER)
conference 'The 'New Economy' and Post-Socialist
Transition' for comments on earlier drafts. I also thank Luke Haggarty and Andrew Stone for their help with the data. Responsibility
for all errors, omissions, and opinions rests solely with the author.
All findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper
are entirely those of the author and do not necessarily represent the
views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they
represent.
Table 1: Means and standard deviations of variables
Variable Source Mean Standard
deviation
Enterprise characteristics
Does enterprise have access to WBES 0.33 0.47
the Internet? (1--yes, 0--no)
Does any foreign company have WBES 0.08 0.27
a financial stake in your
organisation? (1--yes, 0--no)
Percentage change in employment WBES 6.52 60.39
between 1996 and 1999
Percentage change in sales between WBES 13.43 67.33
1996 and 1999
Percent of sales accounted for by WBES 16.93 25.50
state sector
Country control variables
Net incoming foreign direct investment WDI 4.54 5.11
in 1998 (share of GDP)
Imports of goods and services in 1998 WDI 46.68 17.91
(share of GDP)
Main telephone lines per 100 inhabitants ITU 22.09 10.61
in 1999
Urban Population (share of total) in 1998 WDI 61.69 12.33
Per capita GDP in 1998 (PPP, international WDI 5.91 3.18
dollars, 000s)
Population in 1998 (natural log) WDI 16.41 1.38
Note: For source variables, WBES implies that data come
from the World Business Environment Survey (WBES) [c]
2000 The World Bank Group. WDI implies that data come
from World Bank, 2001. World Development Indicators.
World Bank, Washington DC. ITU implies that data come
from International Telecommunication Union, 2000.
World Telecommunication Indicators Database. International
Telecommunication Union, Geneva, Switzerland.
Table 2: Distribution of enterprises in sample
What is biggest competitive threat to enterprise?
(omitted category is domestic enterprises)
Foreign firms producing in domestic markets (not imports) 7.4%
Legal and illegal imports 11.0%
Who is the largest shareholder in enterprise?
(omitted category is government)
A foreign company 3.4%
Enterprise's managers 2.9%
Enterprise's employees 11.0%
Other private (individuals, families, domestic 65.6%
companies, banks or investment funds)
How was enterprise established? (omitted category is
state-owned, including subsidiaries and privatised
state-owned)
Private from time of start up (no state-owned predecessor) 53.3%
Joint venture with foreign and domestic partners 1.3%
How many competitors does enterprise's major product line
face in domestic markets? (omitted category is more than three)
Between one and three 9.9%
No competitors 12.6%
How many full-time employees and casual staff in total
work for this company? (omitted category is over 500)
Less than nine 26.5%
Between 10 and 49? 20.0%
Between 50 and 99? 16.0%
Between 100 and 199? 13.7%
Between 200 and 499? 15.4%
What is enterprise's main area of activity?
(omitted category is 'other')
Farming, fishing or forestry 13.5%
Mining or quarrying 0.8%
Manufacturing 29.7%
Building or construction 8.8%
Power generation 0.4%
Wholesale trade 12.5%
Retail trade 14.4%
Transportation 6.1%
Financial services 1.6%
Personal services 5.3%
Business services 4.9%
Data source: World Business Environment Survey (WBES)
[c] 2000 The World Bank Group
Table 3: Effect of ownership on probability
of enterprise having Internet access
Estimation method Probit
Dependent variable Enterprise has access to Internet
Number of observations 2999 2999
Sector dummies Yes Yes
Size of enterprise dummies Yes Yes
Country dummies No Yes
Foreign shareholding
Any foreign shareholding 0.6125 *** 0.6361 ***
(4.67) (4.69)
Ownership
Largest shareholder--foreign 0.0518 0.0404
(0.24) (0.18)
Largest shareholder--managers -0.2581 -0.3436 *
(-1.49) (-1.95)
Largest shareholder--employees -0.2398 ** -0.3049 **
(-2.04) (-2.51)
Largest shareholder--other private 0.0823 -0.0051
(0.86) (-0.05)
Competition from foreigners
Main competition--imports 0.3054 *** 0.3118 ***
(3.50) (3.47)
Main competition--foreign-owned 0.2944 *** 0.2608 **
domestic enterprises (-2.92) (-2.52)
Enterprise-level controls
Firm established as private enterprise 0.3043 *** 0.3220 ***
(3.92) (4.01)
Firm established as joint venture 0.4944 ** 0.5024 **
(2.07) (2.00)
Between one and three competitors -0.0141 -0.0554
(-0.14) (-0.53)
No competitors 0.1709 ** 0.1441 *
(2.10) (1.73)
Country-level measures of openness
Foreign direct investment (% of GDP) 0.0063
(0.85)
Imports (% of GDP) -0.0119 ***
(-4.42)
Country controls
Number of telephone lines per 100 0.0228 ***
inhabitants (4.00)
Urban population (percent of population) 0.0100 **
(2.44)
Per capita GDP (OOOs of US$) 0.0826 ***
(5.40)
Population (natural log) -0.1713 ***
(-4.33)
Enterprise-level performance
Employment growth (over last 3 years)
Sales growth (over last 3 years)
Sales to government (% of sales)
Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.25 0.28
Estimation method Probit
Dependent variable Enterprise has access to Internet
Number of observations 3006 3006
Sector dummies Yes Yes
Size of enterprise dummies Yes Yes
Country dummies No Yes
Foreign shareholding
Any foreign shareholding
Ownership
Largest shareholder--foreign 0.6497 *** 0.6496 ***
(3.66) (3.58)
Largest shareholder--managers -0.2041 -0.2853
(-1.19) (-1.63)
Largest shareholder--employees -0.2304 ** -0.2950 **
(-1.97) (-2.43)
Largest shareholder--other private 0.1174 0.0322
(1.23) (0.33)
Competition from foreigners
Main competition--imports 0.3200 *** 0.3265 ***
(3.69) (3.66)
Main competition--foreign-owned 0.3036 *** 0.2693 ***
domestic enterprises (-3.05) (-2.64)
Enterprise-level controls
Firm established as private enterprise 0.3127 *** 0.3259 ***
(4.06) (4.10)
Firm established as joint venture 0.6982 *** 0.7150 ***
(3.04) (2.97)
Between one and three competitors 0.0059 -0.0309
(0.06) (-0.30)
No competitors 0.1814 ** 0.1536 **
(2.24) (1.86)
Country-level measures of openness
Foreign direct investment (% of GDP) 0.0051
(0.69)
Imports (% of GDP) -0.0119 ***
(-4.48)
Country controls
Number of telephone lines per 100 0.0226 ***
inhabitants (3.99)
Urban population (percent of population) 0.0096 **
(2.37)
Per capita GDP (OOOs of US$) 0.0814 ***
(5.33)
Population (natural log) -0.1793 ***
(-4.59)
Enterprise-level performance
Employment growth (over last 3 years)
Sales growth (over last 3 years)
Sales to government (% of sales)
Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.25 0.27
Estimation method Probit
Dependent variable Enterprise has access to Internet
Number of observations 2798 2798
Sector dummies Yes Yes
Size of enterprise dummies Yes Yes
Country dummies No Yes
Foreign shareholding
Any foreign shareholding 0.5810 *** 0.6265 ***
(4.10) (4.28)
Ownership
Largest shareholder--foreign -0.0101 -0.0183
(-0.04) (-0.08)
Largest shareholder--managers -0.2139 -0.3097 *
(-1.17) (-1.66)
Largest shareholder--employees -0.2811 ** -0.3228 ***
(-2.31) (-2.56)
Largest shareholder--other private 0.0504 -0.0305
(0.50) (-0.29)
Competition from foreigners
Main competition--imports 0.3309 *** 0.3378 ***
(3.62) (3.59)
Main competition--foreign-owned 0.2370 ** 0.2059 *
domestic enterprises (2.28) (1.93)
Enterprise-level controls
Firm established as private enterprise 0.2156 *** 0.2445 ***
(2.62) (2.88)
Firm established as joint venture 0.4666 * 0.5184 **
(1.85) (1.97)
Between one and three competitors 0.0285 -0.0317
(0.27) (-0.29)
No competitors 0.1516 ** 0.1290
(1.77) (1.48)
Country-level measures of openness
Foreign direct investment (% of GDP) 0.0062
(0.80)
Imports (% of GDP) -0.0121 ***
(-4.33)
Country controls
Number of telephone lines per 100 0.0208 ***
inhabitants (3.46)
Urban population (percent of population) 0.0113 ***
(2.65)
Per capita GDP (000s of US$) 0.0815 ***
(5.10)
Population (natural log) -0.1900 ***
(-4.56)
Enterprise-level performance
Employment growth (over last 3 years) 0.0023 *** 0.0022 ***
(3.96) (3.78)
Sales growth (over last 3 years) 0.0017 *** 0.0017 ***
(3.61) (3.70)
Sales to government (% of sales) 0.0009 *** 0.0017
(0.71) (1.33)
Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.27 0.29
Note: t-Statistics in parentheses
*** Significant at 1 percent level.
** Significant at 5 percent level.
* Significant at 10 percent level.
Data source: The World Business Environment Survey (WBES)
[c] 2000 The World Bank Group Omitted categories are state-owned
enterprises (as largest shareholders) and enterprises established
as state-owned enterprises (origin). The pseudo [R.sup.2] is
1-([L.sub.1/[L.sub.0]), where [L.sub.0] is the log-likelihood
of a model with only a constant and [L.sub.1] is the
log-likelihood of the estimated model (Judge et al., 1988).
Table 4: Effect of dummy variables on probability of having access
to the internet
Probability of
having Internet
access (%)
Base enterprise 24.4
Foreign shareholding
Any foreign shareholding 46.8
Ownership
Largest shareholder--foreign (a) 48.8
Largest shareholder--managers 17.1
Largest shareholder--employees 17.5
Largest shareholder--other private 27.1
Competition from foreigners
Main competition--imports 34.9
Main competition--foreign-owned domestic
enterprises 34.5
Enterprise-level controls
Firm established as private enterprise (b) 38.0
Firm established as joint venture between foreign
and domestic enterprises (c) 66.0
Between one and three competitors 24.0
No competitors 30.1
Note: Probabilities are calculated setting all continuous variables to
their respective means and using coefficients from Table 3, column (1).
The base enterprise is a state-owned enterprise, whose main competition
comes from other domestically owned enterprises, with more than three
competitors for its main product line, with between 50 and 100 workers
(median size), in the manufacturing sector (most common sector). All
other enterprises are the same as the base type with changes as noted
in the title column.
(a) If the largest shareholder is foreign, the dummy indicating any
foreign shareholder is also set to '1'.
(b) If the firm is established as private, the dummy indicating that
the largest shareholder is (other) private (i.e., not state-owned)
is also set to '1'.
(c) If the firm is a joint venture between foreign and domestic, the
dummy indicating some foreign shareholding is set to '1'.
Table 5: Elasticities of the probability of having Internet access
with respect to continuous variables
Variable Elasticity
Country-level measures of openness
Net incoming foreign direct investment in 1998
(share of GDP) 0.03
Imports of goods and services in 1998 (share of GDP) -0.55 ***
Country control variables
Main telephone Lines per 100 inhabitants in 1999 0.50 ***
Urban Population (share of total) in 1998 0.62 **
Per capita GDP in 1998 (PPP, international dollars,
000s). 0.49 ***
Population in 1998 (natural log) -0.17 ***
Enterprise-level performance
Percentage change in employment between 1996 and 1999. 0.04 ***
Percentage change in sales between 1996 and 1999. 0.03 ***
Percent of sates accounted for by state sector. 0.03 ***
*** Significant at 1 percent level. ** Significant at 5 percent level.
* Significant at 10 percent level. Note: Probabilities are calculated
setting all continuous variables to their respective means and using
coefficients from Table 3, column (1). The base enterprise is a
state-owned enterprise, whose main competition comes from other
domestically owned enterprises, with more than three competitors
for its main product line, with between 50 and 100 workers
(median size), in the manufacturing sector (most common sector).
Table 6: Effect of ownership on probability of enterprise having
Internet access
Estimation method
Dependent variable
Sample All All
Number of observations 2999 2999
Sector dummies Yes Yes
Size of enterprise dummies Yes Yes
Country dummies No Yes
Foreign shareholding
Any foreign shareholding 0.6280 *** 0.6579 ***
(4.26) (4.31)
Interaction term
Foreign companies facing competition 0.0937 0.0932
from foreign-owned companies (0.32) (0.31)
Foreign companies facing competition -0.1543 -0.1799
from imports (-0.56) (-0.64)
Ownership
Largest shareholder--foreign 0.0416 0.0268
(0.19) (0.12)
Largest shareholder--managers -0.2620 -0.3487**
(-1.51) (-1.98)
Largest shareholder--employees -0.2407 ** -0.3061 **
(-2.05) (-2.52)
Largest shareholder--other private 0.0811 -0.0065
(0.84) (-0.07)
Competition from foreigners
Main competition--imports 0.3220 *** 0.3312 ***
(3.52) (3.52)
Main competition--foreign-owned 0.2785 *** 0.2441 **
domestic enterprises (2.57) (2.20)
Enterprise-level controls
Firm established as private 0.3036 *** 0.3211 ***
enterprise (3.90) (4.00)
Firm established as joint venture 0.4961 ** 0.5035 **
(2.06) (1.99)
Between one and three competitors -0.0150 -0.0565
(-0.15) (-0.54)
No competitors 0.1715 ** 0.1447 *
(2.10) (1.73)
Country-level measures of openness
Foreign direct investment (% of GDP) 0.0061
(0.83)
Imports (% of GDP) -0.0118 ***
(-4.39)
Manufacturing imports (% of GDP)
Raw material imports (% of GDP)
Imports from low- and middle-income
countries (% of GDP)
Imports from high-income countries
(% of GDP)
Country controls
Number of telephone Lines per 100 0.0227 ***
inhabitants (3.97)
Urban population 0.0099 ***
(percent of population) (2.42)
Per capita GDP (OOOs of US$) 0.0830 ***
(5.41)
Population (natural Log) -0.1705 ***
(-4.30)
Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.25 0.28
Probit
Enterprise has access
to Internet
Estimation method Oil Oil
Dependent variable Exporters Exporters
Sample Omitted Omitted
Number of observations 2638 2638
Sector dummies Yes Yes
Size of enterprise dummies Yes Yes
Country dummies No Yes
Foreign shareholding
Any foreign shareholding 0.7015 *** 0.7256 ***
(4.95) (4.95)
Interaction term
Foreign companies facing competition
from foreign-owned companies
Foreign companies facing competition
from imports
Ownership
Largest shareholder--foreign -0.1514 -0.1592
(-0.65) (-0.66)
Largest shareholder--managers -0.2946 * -0.3684 **
(-1.67) (-2.04)
Largest shareholder--employees -0.2571 ** -0.3304 **
(-2.06) (-2.55)
Largest shareholder--other private 0.0644 -0.0252
(0.62) (-0.23)
Competition from foreigners
Main competition--imports 0.3200 *** 0.2952 ***
(3.42) (3.09)
Main competition--foreign-owned 0.2426 ** 0.2193 **
domestic enterprises (2.32) (2.04)
Enterprise-level controls
Firm established as private 0.3030 *** 0.3230 ***
enterprise (3.72) (3.83)
Firm established as joint venture 0.4593 * 0.5013 *
(1.72) (1.78)
Between one and three competitors 0.0442 -0.0156
(0.41) (-0.14)
No competitors 0.1184 0.0937
(1.38) (1.06)
Country-level measures of openness
Foreign direct investment (% of GDP) 0.0463 ***
(3.54)
Imports (% of GDP) -0.0125 ***
(-4.57)
Manufacturing imports (% of GDP)
Raw material imports (% of GDP)
Imports from low- and middle-income
countries (% of GDP)
Imports from high-income countries
(% of GDP)
Country controls
Number of telephone Lines per 100 0.0193 ***
inhabitants (3.20)
Urban population 0.0063
(percent of population) (1.38)
Per capita GDP (OOOs of US$) 0.0990 ***
(6.11)
Population (natural Log) -0.1189 ***
(-2.76)
Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.25 0.27
Estimation method
Dependent variable
Sample All All
Number of observations 2636 6636
Sector dummies Yes Yes
Size of enterprise dummies Yes Yes
Country dummies No No
Foreign shareholding
Any foreign shareholding 0.6019 *** 0.5546 ***
(4.24) (3.87)
Interaction term
Foreign companies facing competition
from foreign-owned companies
Foreign companies facing competition
from imports
Ownership
Largest shareholder--foreign 0.0259 0.0334
(0.11) (0.14)
Largest shareholder--managers -0.2248 -0.2415
(-1.25) (-1.34)
Largest shareholder--employees -0.1828 -0.2107 *
(-1.47) (-1.68)
Largest shareholder--other private 0.1350 0.0895
(1.32) (0.87)
Competition from foreigners
Main competition--imports 0.2743 *** 0.2415 **
(2.94) (2.57)
Main competition--foreign-owned 0.3004 *** 0.2775 ***
domestic enterprises (2.84) (2.61)
Enterprise-level controls
Firm established as private 0.2585 *** 0.2578 ***
enterprise (3.11) (3.08)
Firm established as joint venture 0.4246 0.4469
(1.54) (1.59)
Between one and three competitors -0.1085 -0.0965
(-0.96) (-0.85)
No competitors 0.1825 ** 0.1688 *
(2.06) (1.89)
Country-level measures of openness
Foreign direct investment (% of GDP) -0.0057 -0.0052
(-0.57) (-0.63)
Imports (% of GDP)
Manufacturing imports (% of GDP) 0.0042
(0.66)
Raw material imports (% of GDP) -0.0191 *
(-1.85)
Imports from low- and middle-income -0.0164 ***
countries (% of GDP) (-4.51)
Imports from high-income countries 0.0133 ***
(% of GDP) (3.07)
Country controls
Number of telephone Lines per 100 0.0269 *** 0.0227 ***
inhabitants (3.88) (3.30)
Urban population 0.0039 0.0026
(percent of population) (0.64) (0.43)
Per capita GDP (OOOs of US$) 0.0475 * 0.0341 *
(1.75) (-1.92)
Population (natural Log) -0.0607 -0.0189
(-0.99) (-0.31)
Pseudo-[R.sup.2] 0.25 0.26
Data source: The World Business Environment Survey (WBES)
(c) 2000 The World Bank Group
See Table 3 for notes to this table.
(1) Although some formal analyses have supported the assertion that
investment in information technology increased labour productivity in
the 1990s, others have found only modest effects. For example, Oliner
and Sichel (2000) find that 0.45 percentage points of a roughly 1
percentage point increase in labour productivity in the non farm
business sector could be attributed to investment in information
technology. In contrast to results in Oliner and Sichel (2000), which
suggested widespread benefits from investment in information technology,
Gordon (2000) round that the gains were concentrated in computer
hardware manufacturing and that there was no increase in productivity
outside of durable manufacturing. Oliner and Sichel (2000, p. 19)
attribute the difference in results to Gordon's (2000) treatment of
cyclical effects. In a survey of firm-level evidence, Brynjolfsson and
Hitt (2000) argue that the firm-level evidence suggests that information
technology started affecting productivity in the early 1990s. Although
several studies have round that investment in IT has improved
procductivity in the US, the direct impact of e-commerce is thought to
be small even in the United States. For example, Oliner and Sichel
(2000) estimate that e-commerce has increased multifactor productivity
growth in the US by considerably less than 0.1 percent per year. Since
e-commerce has almost certainly had a greater impact in the US than it
has had in middle and low-income eeonomies, the impact in the developing
and transition economies is likely to be very small.
(2) For example, Sachs (2000) proposes FDI as a way of increasing
access to technology (although not just information technology) in
developing countries. Blomstrom and Kokko (1996), Barba Navaretti and
Tarr (2000), and Saggi (2000) provide recent reviews of the literature
on the effect of foreign investment and trade on the diffusion of
technology in developing countries.
(3) Aitken and Harrison (1999, p. 607) suggest that entry by
foreign-owned enterprises that are more efficient than domestic
enterprises might cause a short-term drop in the efficiency of domestic
enterprises if it reduces demand for their products, stopping them from
achieving economies of scale.
(4) Research and development (R&D) expenditures are far lower
in developing and transition economies than in developed countries, both
in absolute per capita terms and as a share of GDP. For example, R&D
expenditures accounted for about 2.4 percent of GNP in high-income OECD
countries in 1996, but only 0.8 percent of GNP in the transition
economies of Europe and Central Asia, similar to the level for other
low- and middle-income economies. Data are from World Bank (2001), World
Development Indicators. In 1994, the last year for which data were
available, R&D expenditures accounted for about 0.84 percent of GNP
in low- and middle-income countries.
(5) Djankov and Murrell (2002) presents a meta-analysis synthesising results from 23 studies that look at the effect of
ownership on various measures of performance (ie, not just productivity)
in the transition economies. They find that, overall, foreign-owned
enterprises appear to perform better than, or as well as, all other
ownership types in the transition economies.
(6) For example, although Pack (1997) finds a large amount of
labour turnover between foreign multinationals and domestic enterprises
in Taiwan, Gershenberg (1987) finds only limited turnover in Kenya.
(7) Saggi (2000), Haddad and Harrison (1993), and Barba Navaretti
and Tarr (2000) provide brief surveys of this literature. Studies
include Caves (1974), Globerman (1979), Blomstrom and Persson (1983),
Blomstrom (1986), and Blomstrom and Wolff (1994).
(8) Other enterprise-level studies have found evidence of positive
productivity spillovers. For example, Blomstrom and Sjoholm (1999) find
positive spillovers on labour productivity of domestic firms from both
majority and minority foreign investment in Indonesia in 1991.
(9) For example, domestic enterprises might be able to use new
technologies productively only if they have sufficient levels of human
capital. Consistent with this, Borensztein et al. (1998) find that FDI
is more productive than domestic investment only when countries have a
minimum threshold of human capital.
(10) Data come from the 2002 Investment Climate Survey for Peru,
which was conducted by the World Bank in collaboration with Andean Development Corporation. The survey is described in World Bank (2003).
(11) The survey of the transition economies was conducted in
collaboration with the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development.
Hellman et al. (2000) and European Bank for Reconstruction and
Development (1999) provide more complete descriptions of the survey.
(12) The countries in the sample were: (Commonwealth of Independent
States) Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, Russia, Ukraine and Uzbekistan; (Early Applicants to
the EU) Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Poland and Slovenia; (Other
Central Europe and the Baltics) Lithuania and the Slovak Republic;
(Southeastern Europe) Albania, Bulgaria, Croatia, and Romania. Questions
on Internet access were also asked in Cambodia, Thailand, Turkey, and
the West Bank. However, since these additional countries are less
comparable with the economies of Eastern Europe and Central Asia than
these economies are with each other, and because other control variables
were not available for the additional countries, they are omitted from
the analysis.
(13) The survey question reads '[d]oes your company have
Internet access?' Although it seems that most managers answering
the survey would interpret this to mean 'does the company have
Internet access on the premises', it seems plausible that the
manager might interpret it to include other methods of access (eg,
whether he or she has access to the Internet at home).
(14) The most important countries were Germany, the United States,
the United Kingdom, France and Austria. Only nine of the 268 foreign
enterprises were from Russia.
(15) These measures are omitted when country dummies are included
since they are collinear with them.
(16) The WBES provided categorical information on number of
employees, not the actual number.
(17) The null hypotheses that majority foreign-owned enterprises
are only as likely to have Internet access as employee-owned,
manager-owned, state-owned and 'other' privately owned
enterprises with some foreign ownership can be tested by comparing the
coefficient on majority foreign-owned enterprises with the coefficients
on the dummies for the other classes of largest shareholder. The null
hypotheses cannot be rejected at conventional significance levels for
any of the ownership categories. In the regressions with country
controls, the [chi square][1] statistics are 1.53 (P-value=0.21), 1.68
(P-value =.19), 0.02 (P-value = 0.88) and 0.06 (P-value = 0.81) for
manager-owned, employee-owned, other private domestic, and state-owned
enterprises respectively. Results are similar for the regressions with
country dummies.
(18) Tests of the null hypothesis that the coefficient on majority
foreign-owned enterprises is different from the other coefficients
reject the null hypothesis at conventional significance levels once the
dummy variable indicating any foreign ownership is dropped. In the
regressions with country controls, the [chi square][1] statistics are
14.94 (P-value=0.00), 22.35 (P-value=0.00), 10.32 (P-value=0.00) and
13.41 (P-value=0.00) for manager-owned, employee-owned, other private
domestic, and state-owned enterprises respectively. Results are similar
for the regressions with country dummies.
(19) Although it would be possible to control for endogeneity using
a two stage estimation method, it is difficult to find instruments that
are likely to be correlated with foreign ownership but uncorrelated with
Internet access.
(20) When country controls are included, a hypothesis test rejects
the null hypothesis that the coefficients on employee-owned and
'other' private enterprises are equal at conventional
significance levels ([chi square][1] = 11.53, P-value = 0.00), Results
are similar when country dummies are included.
(21) When country controls are included, the null hypothesis that
the coefficients on manager owned enterprises and employee-owned
enterprises are equal cannot be rejected at conventional significance
levels ([chi square][1] = 0.02. P-value = 0.88). Results are similar
when country dummies are included.
(22) When country controls are included, a hypothesis test of
whether the coefficients are equal for manager owned enterprises and
other private domestic enterprises rejects the null hypothesis that the
coefficients are equal ([chi square][1]=4.19, P-value = 0.04). Results
are similar when country dummies are included.
(23) We are unable to reject the null hypothesis that the
coefficients are equal at conventional significance levels when either
country controls or country dummies are included in the analysis.
(24) Between 1993 and 1998, there was $509 of FDI per capita in
Azerbaijan and $431 per capita in Kazakhstan. In comparison, there was
less than $130 per capita over the same period in the CIS and less than
$100 per capita in most of the other economies. The other oil exporting
countries in Central Asia have received far less FDI, $179 per capita in
Turkmenistan and $31 per capita in Uzbekistan. Russia has also received
far less FDI--$84 per capita over the same period. Data are from
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (2000).
(25) For example, in 1998, there was $129 of FDI per capita in
Azerbaijan. However, there was only $24 per capita outside of the oil
sector. Excluding investment in the oil sector, FDI in Azerbaijan was
similar to the level in other CIS economies for that year. Data are from
International Monetary Fund (2000).
(26) Most of the other results of interest do not appear to be
affected by this change. The only changes are that the coefficient on
the dummy indicating that the enterprise has no competitors in its main
market becomes statistically insignificant and the coefficient on urban
population becomes insignificant when the country controls (rather than
country dummies) are included in the analysis,
(27) Data come from the United Nations Statistical Division
Commodity Trade Database. Data were not available for Armenia, Georgia,
and Uzbekistan.
(28) One related point is that few of the enterprises in the sample
produce food or raw materials (ie, most might be expected to be
competing with imports from developed countries); only 0.8 percent of
enterprises are in mining or quarrying and only 13.5 percent of
enterprises are in farming, fishing or forestry (see Table 2). Excluding
these enterprises from the sample does not affect the main results. That
is, the coefficient on foreign ownership and the coefficients on
competition from foreign-owned enterprises and imports remain positive
and statistically significant at a 5 percent level or lower. Results are
available from author upon request.
(29) The pseudo-[R.sup.2] is 1-([L.sub.1]/[L.sub.o]), where
[L.sub.o] is the log likelihood of a model with only a constant and
[L.sub.1] is the log-likelihood of the estimated model (Judge et al.,
1988).
(30) See footnote 5. Better performing enterprises might both have
better access to capital markets and have higher retained earnings.
Given the underdeveloped nature of the banking systems and capital
markets in these countries, retained earnings are a vital source of
resources for investment in the transition economies.
(31) The meta-analysis in Djankov and Murrell (2002) indicates that
ownership by foreign enterprises and individuals, ownership by
investment funds, ownership by managers, and concentrated individual
ownership was more effective than employee-ownership at improving
enterprise performance.
(32) One study that looks at the effect of the Internet on firm
performance in transition economies, Clarke (2001), finds that export
growth is faster for industrial enterprises in transition economies with
Internet access than for non-connected firms even after controlling for
self-selection bias.
(33) Mauro (1995) shows that corruption has a large and
statistically significant effect on economic growth. In addition,
several recent papers have round that corruption is negatively
correlated with foreign direct investment. Wei (1999), who uses FDI data
from 45 developing and developed countries from 12 OECD countries, finds
that corruption in the host country has a statistically significant
effect on foreign direct investment. The effect is quite large--a
one-point increase in corruption (on a five-point scale) would decrease
foreign direct investment by about 16 percent. Similarly, Gastanga et
al. (1998) also rind that corruption reduces foreign direct investment
in a sample of 45 less-developed countries.
REFERENCES
Aitken, B and Harrison, AE. 1999: Do domestic firms benefit from
direct foreign investment? Evidence from Venezuela. American Economic
Review 89(3): 605-618.
Barba Navaretti, G and Tarr, DG. 2000: International knowledge
flows and economic performance: A review of the evidence. World Bank
Economic Review 13(1): 1-15.
Blomstrom, M. 1986: Foreign investment and productive efficiency:
The case of Mexico. Journal of Industrial Economics 35(1): 97-110.
Blomstrom, M. and Persson, H. 1983: Foreign investment and
spillover efficiency in an underdeveloped economy: evidence from the
Mexican manufacturing industry. World Development 11(6): 493-510.
Blomstrom, M and Kokko, A. (1996). The impact of foreign investment
on host countries: A review of the empirical evidence. Policy Research
Working Paper 1745, World Bank: Washington DC.
Blomstrom, M and Sjoholm, F. 1999: Technology transfer and
spillovers: does local participation with multinationals matter?
European Economic Review 43(4-6): 915-923.
Blomstrom, M and Wolff, EN. 1994: Multinational corporations and
productivity convergence in Mexico. In: Baumol, W, Nelson, R and Wolff,
E (eds). Convergence of Productivity: Cross-National Studies and
Historical Evidence. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK.
Borensztein, E, De Gregorio, J and Lee, JW (1998). How does foreign
direct investment affect economic growth? Journal of International
Economics 45(1): 115-135.
Brynjolfsson, E and Hitt, LM. 2000: Beyond computation: information
technology, organizational transformation and business performance.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(4): 23-48.
Caves, RE. 1974: Multinational firms, competition and productivity
in host-country markets. Economica 38(149): 1-27.
Clarke, GRG. 2001: Does internet connectivity affect export
performance? Evidence from the transition economies. Mimeo, World Bank:
Washington, DC.
Daly, J and Miller, RR. 1998. Corporations' use of the
internet in developing countries. IFC Discussion paper #35,
International Finance Corporation, World Bank: Washington, DC.
Dasgupta, S, Lall, S and Wheeler, D. 2000: Policy reform, economic
growth and the digital divide: An econometric analysis. Policy Research
Working Paper #2567, World Bank: Washington, DC.
Djankov, S and Hoekman, B. 2000: Foreign investment and
productivity growth in Czech enterprises. World Bank Economic Review
14(1): 49-64.
Djankov, S and Murrell, P. 2002: Enterprise restructuring in
transition: a quantitative survey. Journal of Economic Literature 40(3):
739-792.
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. 1999: Transition
Report 1999: Ten Years of Transition. European Bank for Reconstruction
and Development, London, UK.
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. 2000: Transition
Report 2000: Employment, Skills, and Transition. European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development, London, UK.
Gastanga, VM, Nugent, JB and Pashamova, B. 1998: Host country
reforms and FDI inflows: How much difference do they make? World
Development 26(7): 1299-1314.
Gershenberg, I. 1987: The training and spread of managerial
know-how, a comparative analysis of multinational and other firms in
Kenya. World Development 15(7): 931-939.
Globerman, S. 1979: Foreign direct investment and
'spillover' efficiency benefits in Canadian manufacturing
industries. Canadian Journal of Economics 12(1): 42-56.
Gordon, RJ. 2000: Does the 'new economy' measure up to
the great inventions of the past. Journal of Economic Perspectives
14(4): 49-74.
Haddad, M and Harrison, A. 1993: Are there positive spillovers from
direct foreign investment? Journal of Development Economics 42(1):
51-74.
Hellman, J, Jones, G, Kaufmann, D and Schankerman, M. 2000:
Measuring governance and state capture: The role of bureaucrats and
firms in shaping the business environment. European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development Working Paper #51, European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development: London, UK.
International Monetary Fund. 2000. Azerbaijan Republic: Recent
economic developments and selected issues. International Monetary Fund:
Washington, DC.
Judge, GG, Griffiths, WE, Hill, C, Lutkepohl, H and Lee, T-C. 1988:
The Theory and Practice of Econometrics, 2nd Edition. John Wiley and
Sons: New York, NY.
Mauro, P. 1995: Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 110(3): 681-712.
Oliner, SD and Sichel, DE. 2000: The resurgence of growth in the
late 1990s: is information technology the story? Journal of Economic
Perspectives 14(4): 3-22.
Pack, H. 1997: The role of exports in Asian development In:
Birdsall, N and Jaspersen, F (eds). Pathways to Growth: Comparing East
Asia and Latin America. Johns Hopkins University Press: Baltimore, MD.
pp. 227-251.
Sachs, J. 2000: A new map of the world. The Economist, June 22,
2000.
Saggi, K. 2000: Trade, foreign direct investment and international
technology transfer: A survey. Policy Research Working Paper #2349,
World Bank: Washington, DC.
Wei, S-J. 1999: How taxing is corruption on international
investors? Review of Economics and Statistics 81(4): 1-12.
World Bank. 2003: Peru: Microeconomic constraints to growth study.
The World Bank: Washington, DC.
GEORGE R.G. CLARKE
Development Research Group, MSN MC3-307, The World Bank, 1818 H
Street, NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA. E-mail,: gclarke@worldbank.org