Adoption, implementation and impact of IMF programmes: a review of the issues and evidence (1).
Joyce, Joseph P.
INTRODUCTION
In recent years, the activities of the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) have drawn increased attention. The rise in the scrutiny of Fund
activities is due in part to the IMF's heightened profile. The IMF
played a prominent role in dealing with the Asian currency crisis of
1997, as well as the subsequent crises in Russia, Brazil and, most
recently, Turkey and Argentina. A number of studies were undertaken in
response to criticisms of the IMF's policies, which resulted in
proposals for changes in its response to crises. (2)
The increase in public notice has been accompanied by a rise in
scholarly work on the Fund. New questions about the adoption,
implementation and outcome of the IMF's lending programmes have
been raised, while the political dimensions of these arrangements have
received increased examination. Economists and political scientists have
utilised innovative tools of theoretical and empirical analysis, such as
game theory and duration models, to address these issues.
This paper reviews the recent literature on the IMF's lending
programmes, and outlines the advances that have been made and the issues
that merit future analysis. It does not address all aspects of the
Fund's activities, many of which have been examined in other
surveys, such as Krueger (1998). (3) Rather, it assesses the state of
our knowledge about IMF-sponsored programmes, and points to promising
areas of further work.
The next section reviews the research that has been undertaken on
the factors that affect the decision to initiate a program. The third
section surveys issues relating to the design and implementation of IMF
programmes, including the changing nature of conditionality and
programme completion. The fourth section reviews the literature on the
economic impact of Fund-sponsored policies. The fifth section deals with
the response of private capital markets to IMF programmes. The last
section summarises our understanding of Fund programmes and delineates
issues that need to be further explored.
EX ANTE COUNTRY CHARACTERISTICS
A member country of the IMF that faces an external sector crisis
may request financial support from the Fund. A government that is
participating in a programme signs a 'letter of intent', which
specifies the policies that it will implement to restore external sector
balance. (4) In some cases, these have been 'precautionary'
programmes, which indicates that the domestic government has stated that
it does not intend to utilise the available credit. However, this is not
a binding commitment, and the government can later reverse its decision
and borrow from the Fund.
The Fund's primary lending facilities are the stand-by
arrangement, which is designed to deal with short-term (usually 1-year)
balance-of-payments problems, and the extended fund facility, which
provides assistance for structural reforms and tares place over a longer
time horizon, typically 3 years. The IMF also administers the poverty
reduction and growth facility to provide assistance on concessional
terms to low-income countries for the purposes of fostering economic
growth and reducing poverty. The latter was known until 1999 as the
enhanced structural adjustment facility, and it had replaced the
structural adjustment facility.
A substantial portion of the research devoted to Fund programmes
has dealt with the economic characteristics of countries that adopt IMF
programmes. Among the papers that addressed this issue are those of
Joyce (1992), Edwards and Santaella (1993), Conway (1994), Santaella
(1996) and Knight and Santaella (1997). These studies often used a
binary choice model to distinguish between countries and time periods
where an IMF programme was in place and those where it was not, and
sought to determine the economic factors that influenced the initiation
of a Fund programme. Knight and Santaella (1997) pointed out that these
estimation equations can be interpreted as the reduced form derived from
the 'demand' for a Fund programme by a borrowing country and
the IMF's 'supply'.
Bird (1996) summarised this literature, and the areas of overlap
and disagreement. He noted that these studies generally showed that the
adoption of a Fund programme was linked to the occurrence of
balance-of-payments deficits, low levels of reserve holdings, increased
debt, an overvalued exchange rate and a record of past programmes. These
features are consistent with economies that have external disequilbria,
and therefore fall under the IMF's mandate in its Articles of
Agreement to address such imbalances. (5) However, the studies left
unexplained much of the variation in the occurrence of Fund programmes.
Recent work has focused on political and institutional determinants
of Fund borrowing. The relevant papers include those of Thacker (1999),
Vreeland (1999, 2003), Przeworski and Vreeland (2000), Bird and Rowlands
(2001b), Barro and Lee (2003) and Dreher and Vaubel (2004b). The
literature has progressed enough for some areas of consensus to emerge.
Thacker (1999) and Barro and Lee (2003), for example, found evidence
that access to Fund programmes is skewed towards countries that are
aligned with the US, as measured by United Nations voting patterns.
Przeworski and Vreeland (2000) and Dreher and Vaubel (2004b) report that
governments are more likely to enter into an agreement with the IMF in
the year after an election, suggesting that some form of political
business cycle may exist. Oatley and Yackee (2000) and Oatley (2002)
found that the size of a country's IMF loan is related to the size
of its commercial bank debt.
While political and institutional factors undoubtedly play a role
in the decision to initiate a Fund programme, the evidence to date does
not indicate that they have a predominating influence. Bird and Rowlands
(2001b), for example, found that while such variables are in some cases
statistically significant, they do not greatly increase the ability of
models to predict the occurrence of Fund programmes. Sturm et al. (2002)
reported a similar result in their tests of the determinants of changes
in the amount of IMF credit disbursed. While this area of research on
the IMF's programmes, therefore, may have reached the point of
diminishing returns, it does provide evidence on the economic and
political factors that make borrowing from the Fund more likely.
Another approach to explaining patterns of IMF lending has been
taken by Vaubel (1991, 1994, 1996), who utilised public choice theory.
He maintains that an increase in lending allows Fund officials to
maximise their power and remuneration, as manifested by their budget and
staff size, as well as operational independence. Willett (2001, 2002)
also adopts a public choice perspective, although he differs from Vaubel
in emphasising institutional autonomy and a desire to avoid failure as
determinants of the actions of Fund officials. This line of analysis
seems better suited to explain lending in the aggregate than the start
of individual programmes.
The significance of past lending in explaining the introduction of
new programmes has recently led to a new focus of research on the use of
Fund credit. A number of countries have participated in consecutive
lending programmes over time. Such continued borrowing would appear to
contradict the IMF's own Articles of Agreement, which include as a
purpose of the Fund the 'temporary' availability of its
resources to member countries.
Several studies have dealt with the characteristics of countries
that are frequent borrowers. The IMF's (2002) new Independent
Evaluation Office's first report dealt with the prolonged use of
IMF resources, and found that the programmes of frequent users exhibited
an optimistic bias in their projections of growth. Bird et al. (2004)
used models of count data to examine the characteristics of
'recidivist' borrowers, and found that the factors that
contributed to prolonged borrowing included low reserve holdings,
frequent current account deficits, large debt service ratios and low
investment rates. Conway (2000) examined how participation in IMF
programmes affects the probabilities of a country entering and exiting a
crisis. He reported that participation in Fund programmes lessens the
length of an external crisis, but that continuing reliance on Fund
programmes weakens this effect.
Duration models have been used to examine the spells of
uninterrupted programme participation. Conway (2003) reported that prior
participation in IMF programmes is negatively related to the length of a
new spell, while the length of time between spells increases with
cumulative prior participation. Joyce (2004) investigated the factors
that affect these spells, and found evidence of extended programme
duration for countries with lower per capita income, exports
concentrated in primary goods and autocratic regimes.
These studies shift the focus from the decision by a government to
adopt a programme in period t to a government's sequential
decisions regarding participation in Fund programmes over periods t,
t+1, t+2, etc. A government may use a multi-period perspective when
deciding whether to fulfil all the conditions of a particular programme,
or to let a programme lapse in the hopes of negotiating a more
favourable one in the following period (see the discussion in the next
section). This choice will be based on a government's assessment of
its bargaining ability vis-a-vis the Fund as well as its forecast of
future economic conditions. Modelling this intertemporal governmental
decision-making process could be a useful area of future research.
PROGRAMME DESIGN AND IMPLEMENTATION
The Fund disburses credit only if a government adheres to the
policies outlined in the letter of intent. The IMF periodically
evaluates a country's fulfilment of its obligations as measured by
performance criteria, structural benchmarks and overall programme
reviews, and non-compliance usually results in the suspension or
termination of a programme. (6) Several studies, including those of
Killick (1996, 1997), examine the justification for conditionality in
the context of a principal-agent relationship, where the IMF seeks to
ensure that the borrowing government implements policies consistent with
the Fund's goals, with conditionality serving as a monitoring
device.
Much recent work has dealt with the changing nature of the policy
conditions. IMF conditionality traditionally focused on measures of
demand management, such as constraints on a central bank's holdings
of domestic assets and a government's fiscal position. The
increased emphasis by the IMF on growth as an objective has resulted in
the increasing use of structural conditions. These measures are designed
to foster the use of markets in the allocation of resources, and include
domestic deregulation and the liberalisation of trade and capital flows.
The programmes initiated during the Asian crisis were criticised
for imposing an excessive number of structural conditions, particularly
in the case of Indonesia. Goldstein (2000) examined the record of
structural conditions in IMF programmes and found an increase in the
average number of these structural conditions in programmes over time.
Goldstein (2000) and Bird (2001b) suggested that this might have led to
a decline in programme compliance. Dreher and Vaubel (2004a), who use a
public choice perspective, found that the number of conditions depended
negatively on international reserves and positively on world interest
rates, domestic monetary conditions and the number of World Bank loans.
Dreher (2004b) also showed that the number of IMF conditions increased
with participation in World Bank programmes. Gould (2003) attributed the
rise in the use of structural conditions to the influence of private
creditors who supplement Fund resources.
The IMF itself (2001a-d) undertook several studies of
conditionality in the aftermath of the Asian crisis. The authors of
these reports also reported an increase in the number of structural
conditions contained in Fund programmes, but claimed that there was no
evidence that the number of criteria was linked to programme compliance.
However, they did agree that conditionality should be streamlined.
The record of programme completion by borrowing countries has
received increasing scrutiny. Killick (1995) undertook an examination of
programmes that took place between 1979 and 1993, and used the
proportion of credit actually disbursed by the end of a programme
relative to the amount initially committed as a criterion to measure
programme completion. He selected an 80% disbursal rate as a floor to
indicate whether or not a programme was 'completed'. (7)
Killick (1995) reported that by this standard only 47% of all
programmes were successfully completed. He found empirical evidence that
the completion rate was affected by a country's external debt
position, with more frequent breakdowns in programme completion
occurring in highly indebted countries. He also found that the size of
the IMF's initial commitment of credit relative to a country's
current account deficit was higher in those countries that successfully
finished their programmes.
Mussa and Savastano (2000) provided a comprehensive review of the
IMF's lending arrangements over the period 1973 and 1997. They
point out that a country may not receive all of the originally planned
credit for a number of reasons, including external shocks. In some of
these cases, the programme is cancelled early because of an
unanticipated change in the external environment and a new arrangement
is made.
They characterised those programmes where 75% or more of the
planned credit was actually disbursed as situations where the
governments generally completed the agreed-on policies. Such programmes
represented 46% of the total, which is almost identical to
Killick's (1995) calculation of the proportion of successful
completions. The programmes where 50%-75% of the credit was disbursed
represent a range of circumstances and outcomes, including some
successful programmes, some that were rescheduled and some that were not
finished because of failure to comply with the performance criteria.
There was a serious divergence between the planned policies and those
executed in the remaining cases where less than one half of the planned
credit was disbursed.
Studies originating at the IMF of its programmes have pointed to
the importance of political factors in successful programme
implementation. Schadler et al. (1995) pointed out that there is a large
variation among countries in their commitment to carrying out reform
measures, while Mecagni (1999) attributed a major proportion of
programme breakdowns to political changes and civil instability. The
IMF's (2001b) own study of the literature on programme
implementation concluded that a national commitment to reform is
necessary to the successful completion of a program. (8)
Theoretical models based on a political economy perspective focus
on the domestic political factors that affect programme implementation.
These models stress the divergent interests of the different interest
groups within a country and the impact of an IMF programme on their
relative positions. Vreeland (1999), for example, contends that some
governments adopt Fund programmes even when economic conditions do not
warrant one in order to increase their bargaining leverage over domestic
opponents of reform policies.
Drazen (2002) and Mayer and Mourmouras (2002) presented models of
the political environment within a borrowing country, where there are
'veto players' within a government and special interest groups
outside that could block reform. Mayer and Mourmouras (2002) demonstrate
that conditional assistance can strengthen or 'tip the hand'
of the reformers. Boughton and Mourmouras (2002) reviewed this
theoretical modelling of policy reform and drew implications for
strengthening policy ownership, a subject also analysed by Khan and
Sharma (2001).
Ivanova et al. (2003) used several measurements of programme
implementation in their study of the factors that affect the outcomes of
Fund programmes. They reported that completion is linked to domestic
political conditions, including political cohesion, ethnic
fragmentation, conflict and the strength of special interests. Joyce
(2003) found that programme implementation is affected by a
country's trade openness, the ideological cohesion of the
government, the duration of the political regime and the degree of
political openness. In a related study, Dreher (2004a) showed that the
completion of an IMF programme in the year before an election increases
the probability of a government's re-election only when the growth
rate of GDP is low.
Other studies have examined the Fund's behaviour in cases of
programme suspension. Stone (2002), for example, reported evidence to
support the hypothesis that the IMF is more likely to suspend programmes
in more 'important countries', as measured by the size of
their IMF quotas, US foreign aid and aid from other OECD members, but
for shorter periods. Dreher (2003) found that non-compliance with
conditionality and programme suspension is more likely to take place
prior to elections, but this happens less frequently in democratic
countries. Edwards (2003a) showed that democracies with fractionalised
legislatures perform poorly in IMF programmes and are more likely to be
sanctioned.
In response to its critics, the IMF now emphasises the ownership of
programmes in order to achieve their successful completion. The Fund is
paying more attention to the domestic political environment when dealing
with a country. For example, the IMF and the World Bank have sought to
broaden the basis of support within a country for their programmes by
developing poverty reduction strategy papers that describe the policies
needed to promote growth in consultation with a broad range of parties.
A future focus of research will be evaluating whether this new emphasis
affects programme completion.
EX POST POLICY IMPACT
The economic policies stipulated in a Fund-sponsored programme are
designed to restore a sustainable balance-of-payments position in the
short-run while encouraging long-term output growth. An extensive amount
of research has addressed the issue of whether Fund-supported policies
actually improve economic performance, as manifested through the balance
of payments, lower inflation and higher growth. These studies seek to
determine the efficacy of the measures that the IMF recommends.
A crucial component of the empirical analysis has been the
construction of the 'counterfactual', a country's
economic performance if it had not elected to adopt a programme to serve
as a basis of comparison with the actual record. A variety of approaches
have been adopted for this purpose. The 'before-after'
approach compares a country's post-programme performance with its
performance before the programme. The 'with-without' approach
contrasts changes in target variables in programme countries with
changes in a control group of non-programme countries. Both methods,
however, ignore the systematic differences between the countries and
periods where lending occurs and those where it does not. Studies that
ignore these differences may exaggerate the impact of Fund programmes.
Goldstein and Montiel (1986) developed a generalised evaluation
estimator (GEE) to deal with this problem. The GEE controls for the
differences between countries and takes into account the policies that
would have prevailed in the absence of a Fund programme. This approach
has been taken in many subsequent studies, such as those of Khan (1990)
and Conway (1994). Recent contributions in this area include the works
of Bagci and Perraudin (1997), Prezeworski and Vreeland (2000),
Dicks-Mireaux et al. (2000), Evrensel (2002), Barro and Lee (2003),
Hutchison (2003) and Hutchison and Noy (2003).
Haque and Khan (1998) provided a comprehensive survey of this
literature. They report that the empirical evidence generally indicates:
'... that Fund-supported programmes lead to an improvement in the
current account balance and the overall balance of payments. The
results for inflation are less clear cut ... In the case of growth,
the consensus seems to be that output will be depressed in the
short-run as the demand-reducing elements of the policy package
dominate. Over time the structural reform elements of the programme
start to take effect and growth begins to rise ...' (9)
Bird (2001a) in a later survey agrees with this assessment, except
with respect to the impact of IMF programmes on growth. He finds that
the evidence from recent studies indicates no impact or a negative one.
Other recent works have attempted to measure the impact of IMF
programmes on income distribution and poverty. Garuda (2000) found that
participation in Fund programmes has important distributional effects
that depend on a country's pre-income situation, with negative
consequences for countries in the worst circumstances. Similarly,
Vreeland (2002) reported that labour's share of income is lower in
countries with IMF programmes. Easterly (2003) investigated the impact
of structural adjustment programmes of the IMF and World Bank and
reported that such programmes lower the impact of economic fluctuations
on poverty, that is, economic expansions benefit the poor less but
contractions hurt them less.
This literature has generally not taken into account the compliance
of the countries in IMF programmes with their programmes'
conditionality. This is a surprising omission, since presumably a
country's economic performance will vary in response to its
implementation of the programme's policies. Assessing the
performance of programme countries without discriminating among them by
their degree of compliance could give a misleading view of the effects
of IMF programmes. On the other hand, if no systematic linkages exist,
then new questions arise about the effectiveness of Fund-supported
policies and the need for conditionality.
Killick et al. (1992) compared the impact on the balance of
payments of completed versus uncompleted programmes, but did not find
evidence of a significant difference in the two groups. Conway (1994)
included measurements of the time spent in programmes and the amount of
credit actually disbursed in his analysis of the economic impact of Fund
programmes. Ergin (1999) also addressed this issue, and used different
measurements of participation in Fund programmes, including a
time-weighted utilisation of IMF credit that served as a proxy for
programme compliance. He found that sustained access to Fund credit led
to improvements in the current account and real output, and a
significant decline in the inflation rate. Mercer-Blackman and
Unigovskaya (2000) used the Fund's database for monitoring fund
arrangements (MONA), and reported evidence of a link in the transition
economies between growth and compliance, as measured by MONA's
index of fund programme implementation. Boockmann and Dreher (2003)
found that neither the number of IMF programmes nor the net flow of
credit disbursed had an impact on an index of economic freedom.
The impact of Fund programmes on economic performance has
consequences for the occurrence of future programmes. Policies that are
effective reduce the need for new programmes. Unsuccessful policies
could lead to more programmes to address recurring problems, although
programmes with negative side effects may drive countries away.
Assessing the effect of IMF programmes on economic performance will
undoubtedly continue to be an important area of research.
IMF PROGRAMMES AND CAPITAL MARKETS
The research reviewed to this stage has dealt with the relationship
of the IMF and the member countries that participate in a programme.
However, Fund lending does not take place in isolation. There are other
sources of financial resources potentially available to a country, both
public and private, and these may be affected by the operations of Fund
programmes.
The IMF itself states that the existence of an agreement with a
country '... reassures investors and the official community and
helps generate additional financing from these sources. Thus, IMF
financing can act as an important lever, or catalyst, for attracting
other funds'. (10) A large number of studies have tested the
validity of this claim. (11) Rodrik (1996), Bird and Rowlands (1997,
2001a) and Ergin (1999), using different measurements of private capital
flows, found no evidence that IMF lending to a country was followed by
an increase in private credit flows. However, Ergin (1999) and Rowlands
(2001) did find evidence of an increase in lending from other public
sources, which is consistent with the Fund's lead role in
coordinating multi-lateral assistance.
These findings indicate that the existence of a Fund programme does
not serve as a sufficient condition to warrant an increase in private
capital flows. This result is not surprising in view of the record on
programme completion and impact reviewed above. It would be more
fruitful to examine whether the private markets differentiate between
successful and unsuccessful programmes.
Edwards (2003b) addresses this issue, as well as the problem of
selection bias. He also found little evidence of a catalytic effect,
although he does report a decrease in capital flows for programme
countries that had compliance problems in the past. Similarly, Mody and
Saravia (2003) demonstrated that a country's fundamentals, such as
the volatility of exports, its reserves and its debt, determine the
effect of a programme on the spreads that borrowing countries paid at
the time of bond issuance. They also showed that prolonged usage of Fund
resources raises the spreads. Benelli (2003) reported that the amount of
financial assistance provided in a programme is inversely related to
whether the projections for net private capital flows are met.
Macro-policy adjustment seemed to have a positive impact on such flows.
The initiation of a Fund programme may affect private capital
markets through an impact on existing debt. Marchesi and Thomas (1999)
presented a model in which the presence of an IMF programme serves as a
signalling device of a country's willingness and ability to
undertake substantive reform. In these circumstances, private creditors
are more willing to reschedule the country's external debt.
Marchesi (2003) empirically tested this prediction and reported evidence
in support of it. Easton and Rockerbie (1999) found that participation
in an IMF programme lowers the expected probability of a loan default
and the average spread over LIBOR.
The reaction of the private financial markets to the start of IMF
programmes could be an important factor in the eventual economic impact
of these programmes. Fund programmes are designed to encourage private
lending, but this outcome does not always take place. An increase in
capital flows may depend in part on the status of financial markets
within a country, as well as the assessment of private creditors of the
extent of reform measures. The literature on the determinants of capital
flows to emerging economies may be useful in understanding how IMF
programmes could lead to increased capital flows.
Although Fund lending does not seem to be systematically followed
by inflows of private capital, the Fund has been criticised in recent
years for indirectly encouraging risky behaviour by either borrowers or
private creditors. Moral hazard poses a problem if the potential
availability of Fund support encourages risky loans to be made that
precipitate or worsen a crisis. While the dangers of moral hazard have
been frequently raised by the critics of the IMF, there is a paucity of
evidence on its actual magnitude and relevance. (12) This is partly due
to the problem of contrasting a countervailing situation.
A number of papers have utilised the spreads on the bonds of
emerging markets to determine whether the bond markets reacted to events
such as IMF lending during a crisis. Zhang (1999) reported that he found
no evidence of moral hazard in the wake of the Mexican crisis, and Kamin
(2002) also did not find evidence of a change in the access of emerging
markets to credit after the Mexican crisis. On the other hand, Sarno and
Taylor (1999) found that moral hazard affected the flows of capital to
East Asia. Dell'Aricca et al. (2002) presented evidence in the case
of the Russian crisis consistent with the existence of moral hazard, but
cautioned that their findings could also be due to a change in the
market's perception of risk in emerging markets.
Lane and Phillips (2000) reported a mixed record of market
responses to news of Fund initiatives. Evrensel and Kutan (2003)
conducted an empirical analysis of creditor behaviour in several
countries, and found results consistent with moral hazard in the case of
the Korean asset markets. The limited evidence on moral hazard indicates
that more research is needed in this area, particularly as developing
countries move to liberalise capital flows.
SUMMARY
A balance sheet of our knowledge regarding the IMF's lending
programmes would show entries on both sides of the ledger. Areas of
consensus include:
* Countries that participate in IMF programmes usually show signs
of an external imbalance: large current account deficits, low reserve
levels, high debt burdens and an overvalued exchange rate. In addition,
they have often utilised Fund assistance before. Their governments are
supportive of the US in forums such as the United Nations. IMF lending
often occurs in the year after an election.
* Some countries have participated in a continuous series of Fund
programmes over time. Moreover, a large proportion of Fund programmes
are not successfully completed. Incomplete implementation is due in part
to adverse domestic political conditions that hinder the chances of
economic reform.
* The execution of IMF-sponsored policies improves a country's
external balance, as measured through the balance of payments. There may
also be an accompanying decline in output. There is little evidence of a
systematic effect on inflation.
* There is no evidence of a systematic increase in private capital
flows in the wake of Fund programmes. However, foreign creditors may be
more willing to reschedule debt. Credit from other official sources does
increase.
There are many aspects of IMF programmes, however, that we do not
yet fully understand. Among the unanswered questions are:
* Some countries do not enter a Fund programme despite adverse
economic circumstances. Is there a high initial political cost in
approaching the IMF, which then falls with each successive programme?
* Is recurring lending the result of unsuccessful implementation of
previous programmes, badly designed policies, systematic external shocks
or other factor(s)?
* Is the partial completion of programmes related to the design of
the programmes, as well as unfavorable domestic economic and political
conditions? How does it differ by type of programme?
* Are private capital flows a substitute or complement to IMF
credit? Do private lenders distinguish between countries with
'successful' programmes as opposed to those with uncompleted
programmes?
* Is there evidence that demonstrates that moral hazard has led to
crises because of risky behaviour by private lenders or borrowing
countries?
These questions represent a far-ranging agenda of research. In many
cases, similar questions have been raised in other contexts, including
the study of currency crises, the political economy of reform, the
effectiveness of foreign aid and the determinants of capital flows to
emerging economies. Research on IMF lending can absorb findings from
these related areas to provide new insights on these programmes, which
in turn may be incorporated into the Fund's future lending
policies.
(1) This paper has benefited from comments by two referees.
(2) See, for example, Council on Foreign Relations (1999), De
Gregorio et al. (1999) and International Financial Institution Advisory
Commission (2000).
(3) Comprehensive listings of research on the IMF and World Bank,
including those that are cited in this paper, are available at the
International Financial Institutions Research Site:
www.wellesley.edu/Economics/IFI/index.html.
(4) A country may obtain foreign exchange worth up to 25% of its
quota with minimal conditionality. See Mussa and Savastano (2000) for a
description of the process whereby a program is initiated.
(5) Article of Agreement I(vi).
(6) The Fund does grant waivers in situations where it feels they
are warranted.
(7) The disbursal rate would not be appropriate for precautionary
programmes, since the domestic government does not intend to utilise the
resources. Even if it does borrow, it may not need the entire committed
amount.
(8) See IMF (2001b, p. 52).
(9) Haque and Khan (1998, p. 19).
(10) 'What is the IMF?' on the Fund web site www.imf.org,
August 2001.
(11) See Cottarelli and Curzio (2002) for a thorough review of
these studies.
(12) Evrensel and Kutan (2003) provide a critical review of this
literature.
REFERENCES
Bagci, P and Perraudin, P. 1997: The impact of IMF programmes.
Global Economic Institutions Working paper no. 24.
Burro, RJ and Lee, J-W. 2003: IMF programs: Who is chosen and what
are the effects? Mimeo.
Benelli, R. 2003: Do IMF-supported programs boost private capital
inflows? The role of program size and policy adjustment. IMF Working
paper no. 03/231, Washington.
Bird, G. 1996: Borrowing from the IMF: The policy implications of
recent empirical research. World Development 24(11): 1753-1760.
Bird, G. 2001a: IMF programs: do they work? can they be made to
work better? World Development 29(11): 1849-1865.
Bird, G. 2001b: IMF programmes: Is there a conditionality Laffer
curve? World Economics 2(2): 29-49.
Bird, G, Hussain, M and Joyce, JP. 2004: Many happy returns?
Recidivism and the IMF. Journal of International Money and Finance
23(2): 231-251.
Bird, G and Rowlands, D. 1997: The catalytic effect of lending by
the international financial institutions. World Economy 20(7): 967-991.
Bird, G and Rowlands, D. 2001a: Catalysis or direct borrowing: The
role of the IMF in mobilising private capital. World Economy 24(1):
81-98.
Bird, G and Rowlands, D. 2001b: IMF lending: How is it affected by
economic, political, and institutional factors? Journal of Policy Reform
4(3): 243-270.
Boockmann, B and Dreher, A. 2003: The contribution of the IMF and
the World Bank to economic freedom. European Journal of Political
Economy 19(3): 633-649.
Boughton, JM and Mourmouras, A. 2002: Is policy ownership an
operational concept? IMF Working paper no. 02/72, Washington.
Conway, P. 1994: IMF lending programs: Participation and impact.
Journal of Development Economics 45(2): 365-391.
Conway, P. 2000: IMF programs and economic crisis: An empirical
study of transition. Mimeo.
Conway, P. 2003. Duration and recidivism in IMF programs: Evidence
from the period 1973-1992. Mimeo.
Cottarelli, C and Curzio, G. 2002: Bedfellows, hostages, or perfect
strangers? Global capital markets and the catalytic effect of IMF crisis
lending. IMF Working paper no. 02/193, Washington.
Council on Foreign Relations. 1999: Safeguarding prosperity in a
global financial system: The future international financial
architecture. Institute for International Economics: Washington.
De Gregorio, J, Eichengreen, B, Ito, T and Wyplosz, C. 1999: An
independent and accountable IME International Center for Monetary and
Banking Studies and Centre for Economic Policy Research: Geneva, London.
Dell'Aricca, G, Schnabel, I and Zettelmeyer, J. 2002: Moral
hazard and international crisis lending: A test. IMF Working paper no.
02/181, Washington.
Dicks-Mireaux, L, Mecagni, M and Schadler, S. 2000: Evaluating the
effect of IMF lending to low-income countries. Journal of Development
Economics 61 (2): 495-526.
Drazen, A. 2002: Conditionality and ownership in IMF lending: a
political economy approach. IMF Staff Papers 49(0): 36-67.
Dreher, A. 2003: The influence of elections on IMF programme
interruptions. Journal of Development Studies 39(6): 101-120.
Dreher, A. 2004a: The influence of IMF programs on the re-election
of debtor governments. Economics & Politics 16(1): 53-76.
Dreher, A. 2004b: A public choice perspective of IMF and World Bank
lending and conditionality. Public Choice (in press).
Dreher, A and Vaubel, R. 2004a. The causes and consequences of IMF
conditionality. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade (in press).
Dreher, A and Vaubel, R. 2004b: Do the IMF and IBRD cause moral
hazard and political business cycles? Evidence from panel data. Open
Economies Review 15(1): 5-22.
Easterly, W. 2003: IMF and World Bank structural adjustment
programs and poverty. In: Dooley, M and Frankel, JA (eds). Managing
Currency Crises in Emerging Markets. University of Chicago: Chicago, IL.
pp. 361-382.
Easton, ST and Rockerbie, DW. 1999: Does IMF conditionality benefit
lenders? Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 155(2): 347-357.
Edwards, M. 2003a: Domestic institutions and economic performance
under IMF programs, 1979-1995. Mimeo.
Edwards, M. 2003b: Signaling credibility? The IMF and catalytic
finance. Mimeo.
Edwards, S and Santaella, JA. 1993: Devaluation controversies in
the developing countries: Lessons from the Bretton Woods era. In: Bordo,
MD and Eichengreen, B (eds). A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods
System: Lessons for International Monetary Reform. University of Chicago
Press: Chicago. pp. 405-455.
Ergin, E. 1999: Determinants and consequences of International
Monetary Fund programs. PhD dissertation, Stanford University.
Evrensel, AY. 2002: Effectiveness of IMF-supported stabilization
programs in developing countries. Journal of International Money and
Finance 21(5): 565-587.
Evrensel, AY and Kutan, AK. 2003: The IMF and creditor moral hazard
and new evidence. Mimeo.
Garuda, G. 2000: The distributional effects of IMF programs: A
cross-country analysis. World Development 28(6): 1031-1051.
Goldstein, M. 2003: IMF structural programs. In: Feldstein, M (ed).
Economic and Financial Crises in Emerging Market Economies. University
of Chicago: Chicago, IL, pp. 363-437.
Goldstein, M and Montiel, PJ. 1986: Evaluating fund stabilization
programs with multicountry data: Some methodological pitfalls. IMF Staff
Papers 33 (2): 304-544.
Gould, E. 2005: Money talks: supplementary financiers and
International Monetary Fund conditionality, International Organization
57(3): 551-586.
Haque, NU and Khan, MS. 1998: Do IMF-supported programs work? A
survey of the cross-country empirical evidence. IMF working paper no.
98/169, Washington.
Hutchison, MM. 2003: A cure worse than the disease? Currency crises
and the output costs of IMF-supported stabilization programs. In:
Dooley, M and Frankel, JA (eds). Managing Currency Crises in Emerging
Markets. University of Chicago: Chicago. pp. 321-354.
Hutchison, MM and Noy, I. 2003: Macroeconomic effects of
IMF-sponsored programs in Latin America: Output costs, program
recidivism and the vicious cycle of failed stabilization. Journal of
International Money and Finance 22(7): 91-1014.
International Financial Institution Advisory Commission. 2000:
Report of the International Financial Institution Advisory Commission.
US Government Printing Office: Washington.
International Monetary Fund. 2001a: Conditionality in
fund-supported programs: overview. IMF: Washington.
International Monetary Fund. 2001b: Conditionality in
fund-supported programs: Policy issues. IMF: Washington.
International Monetary Fund. 2001c: Conditionality in
fund-supported programs. IMF: Washington.
International Monetary Fund. 2001d: Trade policy conditionality in
fund-supported programs. IMF: Washington.
International Monetary Fund. 2002: Evaluation of prolonged use of
IMF resources. Independent Evaluation Office: Washington.
Ivanova, A, Mayer, W, Mourmouras, A and Anayiotas, G. 2003: What
determines the success or failure of fund-supported programs? IMF
Working paper no. 03/8, Washington.
Joyce, JP. 1992: The economic characteristics of IMF program
countries. Economics Letters 38(2): 237-242.
Joyce, JP. 2003: Promises made, promises broken: A Model of IMF
program implementation. Wellesley College Economics Department Working
paper no. 2003-03.
Joyce, JP. 2004: Time Present and time past: a duration analysis of
IMF program spells. Review of International Economics (in press).
Kamin, SB. 2002: Identifying the role of moral hazard in
international financial markets, international Finance Discussion paper
no. 736, Federal Reserve Board of Governors: Washington.
Khan, MS. 1990: The macroeconomic effects of fund-supported
adjustment programs. IMF Staff Papers 37(2): 195-231.
Khan, MS and Sharma, S. 200l: IMF conditionality and country
ownership of programs. IMF working paper no. 01/142, Washington.
Killick, T. 1995: IMF Programmes in developing countries.
Routledge: London.
Killick, T. 1996: Principals, agents and the limitations of BWI conditionality. World Economy 19(2): 211-229.
Killick, T. 1997: Principals, agents and the failings of
conditionality. Journal of International Development 9(4): 483-495.
Killick, T, Malik, M and Manuel, M. 1992: What can we know about
the effects of IMF programmes? World Economy 15(5): 575-597.
Knight, M and Santaella, JA. 1997: Economic determinants of IMF
financial arrangements. Journal of Development Economics 54(2): 405-436.
Krueger, AO. 1998: Whither the World Bank and the IMF? Journal of
Economic Literature 36(4): 1983-2020.
Lane, T and Phillips, S. 2000: Does IMF financing result in moral
hazard? IMF Working paper no. 00/168, Washington.
Marchesi, S. 2003: Adoption of an IMF programme and debt
rescheduling: an empirical analysis. Journal of Development Economics 70
(2): 403-423.
Marchesi, S and Thomas, JP. 1999: IMF conditionality as a screening
device. Economic Journal 109(454): C111-C125.
Mayer, W and Mourmouras, A. 2002: Vested interests in a positive
theory of IFI conditionality. IMF Working paper no. 02/73, Washington.
Mecagni, M. 1999: The causes of program interruptions. In:
Bredenkamp, H and Schadler, S (eds). Economic Adjustment and Reform in
Low-Income Countries. IMF: Washington. pp. 215-276.
Mercer-Blackman, V and Unigovskaya, A. 2000: Compliance with IMF
program indicators and growth in transition economies. IMF Working paper
no. 00/47, Washington.
Mody, A and Saravia, D. 2003: Catalyzing capital flows: Do
IMF-supported programs work as commitment devices? IMF Working paper no.
03/100, Washington.
Mussa, M and Savastano, MA. 2000: The IMF approach to economic
stabilization. In: Bernanke, BS and Rotemberg, JJ (eds). NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1999. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA. pp. 79-122.
Oatley, T. 2002: Commercial banks and the International Monetary
Fund: An empirical analysis. Mineo.
Oatley, T. and Yackee, J. 2000: Political determinants of IMF
balance of payments lending: The curse of carabosse? Mimeo.
Przeworski, A and Vreeland, JR. 2000: The effect of IMF programs on
economic growth. Journal of Development Economics 62(2): 385-421.
Rodrik, D. 1996: Why is there multilateral lending? In Bruno, M and
Pleskovic, B (eds). Annual World Bank Conference on Development
Economics 1995. World Bank: Washington. pp. 167-193.
Rowlands, D. 2001: The response of other lenders to the IME Review
of International Economics 9 (3): 531-546.
Santaella, JA. 1996: Stylized facts before IMF-supported
macroeconomic adjustment. IMF Staff Papers 43(3): 502-544.
Sarno, L and Taylor, ME 1999: Moral hazard, asset price bubbles,
capital flows, and the East Asian crisis: The first tests. Journal of
International Money and Finance 18(4): 637-657.
Schadler, S, Bennett, A, Carkovic, M, Dicks-Mireaux, L, Mecagni, M,
Morsink, JHJ and Savastano, MA. 1995: IMF conditionality: Experience
under stand-by and extended arrangements. Part I: Key issues and
findings. Part II: Background papers. IMF Occasional papers no. 128 and
no. 129, Washington.
Stone, RW. 2002: Lending credibility: The International Monetary
Fund and the post-communist transition. Princeton University Press:
Princeton, NJ.
Sturm, JE, Berger, H and de Haan, J. 2002: IMF credit: How
important are political factors? A robustness analysis. Center for
Economic Studies & Ifo Institute for Economic Research Working paper
no. 642 (6). Munich.
Thacker, SC. 1999: The high politics of IMF lending. World Politics
52(1): 38-75.
Vaubel, R. 1991: The political economy of the International
Monetary Fund: A public choice analysis. In: Vaubel, R and Willett, T
(eds). The Political Economy of International Organizations. Westview
Press: Boulder, CO. pp. 204-244.
Vaubel, R. 1994: The political economy of the IMF: A public choice
analysis. In: Bandow, D and Vasquez, I (eds). Perpetuating Poverty: The
World Bank, the IMF and the Developing World. Cato Institute:
Washington, DC. pp. 37-55.
Vaubel, R. 1996: Bureaucracy at the IMF and World Bank: A
comparison of the Evidence. World Economy 19(2): 195-210.
Vreeland, JR. 1999: The IMF: Lender of last resort or scapegoat?
Mimeo.
Vreeland, JR. 2002: The effect of IMF programs on labor. World
Development 30(1): 121-39.
Vreeland, JR. 2003. The IMF and economic development. Cambridge
University Press: Cambridge, UK.
Willett, TD. 2001: Upping the ante for political economy analysis
of the international financial institutions. World Economy 24(3):
317-332.
Willett, TD. 2002: Towards a broader public choice analysis of the
International Monetary Fund. Mimeo.
Zhang, XA. 1999: Testing for 'moral hazard' in emerging
markets lending. Institute of International Finance Research paper no.
99-1.
JOSEPH P JOYCE
Department of Economics, Wellesley College, Wellesley, MA 02482,
USA. E-mail: jjoyce@wellesley.edu