Financing balance of payments adjustment: options in the light of the elusive catalytic effect of IMF-supported programmes.
Bird, Graham ; Rowlands, Dane
INTRODUCTION
Countries are presumed to turn to the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) when they have an unsustainable current account balance of
payments deficit. The circumstances that lead to such a situation have
been studied extensively and have been found more often than not to
involve a combination of domestic macroeconomic mismanagement and
external shocks. (1) Crises during the 1990s, however, demonstrated that
referral to the Fund could have as much to do with sharp capital
reversals, implying that current account deficits could no longer be
financed by capital inflows, as with any marked deterioration in the
current account itself. The IMF responded to these events as well,
despite the presence of Article VI of the Fund's Articles of
Agreement precluding it from providing resources merely to finance
capital outflows.
When approached after the onset of unfavourable economic events,
the basic purpose of the Fund's involvement is to restore balance
of payments viability, thereby enabling the borrowing country to
eventually disengage from the Fund. The programmes supported by the Fund
combine balance of payments adjustment with external financing.
Financial assistance from the Fund comes with policy strings attached;
the so-called IMF conditionality. An IMF programme is supposed to
balance the adjustment process with external finance in an optimal way.
If financing inflows on the capital account fall short of the expected
and desired amount, the speed of adjustment on the current account will
be greater than expected. There is, of course, the opposite problem of
diluted adjustment when financing is excessive. As two IMF researchers
put it, 'the availability of external financing, the first
component of the strategy, determines the magnitude and pace of the
necessary adjustment period' (Mussa and Savastano, 1999, p. 20).
The tradeoff between external financing and the speed of adjustment is
likely to be a source of tension between the Fund and the country
concerned, and striking the right balance requires to reflect both
economic and political realities.
The Fund recognises that the resources it provides may be far from
adequate on their own to finance the adjustment programmes that it
approves, even when it has violated its original quota-based lending
limits. The difference between the resources required to finance an
adjustment programme and those which the IMF provides is supposed to
come from other public and private sources. Specifically, the Fund has
traditionally claimed that its programmes perform a catalysing role,
encouraging others to lend more than they would otherwise have done. The
view of the Fund is represented by the following quote:
In most cases, the IMF, when it lends, provides only a small
portion of a country's external financing requirements. But because
the approval of IMF lending signals that a country's economic
policies are on the right track, it reassures investors and the official
community and helps generate additional financing from these sources.
Thus, IMF financing can act as an important lever, or catalyst, for
attracting other funds. The IMF's ability to perform this catalytic
role is based on confidence that other lenders have in its operations
and especially in the credibility of the policy conditionality attached
to its lending. (IMF, 2002)
Similarly in the Prague Framework launched by the IMF's
Managing Director, Horst Kohler, in September 2000, the catalytic effect
of IMF lending was seen as an important element in enhancing crisis
resolution. The above quote from the IMF's website is useful
because not only does it say something about the assumed quantitative
significance of the catalytic effect but it also explains the mechanism
through which the effect is intended to work. (2) This paper reviews
what we know about the catalytic effect of IMF lending.
The next section briefly explores the analytical basis for
believing that there will be a catalytic effect, and reviews the
empirical evidence. The subsequent section then examines ways in which
IMF programmes might be strengthened in terms of achieving the desired
balance between financing and adjustment. A final section places the
discussion within the broader context of current trends in terms of
capital flows to emerging and developing economies.
THE CATALYTIC EFFECT OF IMF LENDING
In the above quote, the Fund argues that catalysis is based on the
'credibility of the policy conditionality attached to its
lending'. Expanding on this idea, Cottarelli and Giannini (2002)
suggest that in principle the catalytic effect works through five
channels. First, IMF programmes may improve policy design. Second, IMF
programmes may be based on transmitting information to other lenders and
investors. Third, signing an IMF agreement may indicate a
government's commitment to reform. Fourth, the process of
negotiating an IMF programme may screen out governments not committed to
reform. Finally, markets may perceive IMF programmes as a form of
insurance for their capital. (3)
The first four of these point to two primary catalytic functions
for IMF programmes. First, the programme's policy conditions must
represent a significant improvement from the lenders' or
investors' perspective relative to the policies that the government
would otherwise have adopted. Second, the signing of a programme must
imply a credible commitment to implement these improved policies.
Although clearly connected, the question of policy design and
implementation are considered in turn.
The IMF's policy conditionality has long attracted criticism.
Nowzad (1981, p. 9) suggests that '[n]o aspect of the Fund's
activities has been more controversial, more persistently criticized, or
more routinely misunderstood than ... conditionality.' The primary
irritant from the perspective of many critics has been the presumed
overemphasis on reducing aggregate demand, which can be achieved
relatively quickly, versus the expansion of aggregate supply. The need
to emphasise rapid adjustment via aggregate demand contraction is itself
seen as symptomatic of insufficient financing. Helleiner (1983, p. 1)
summarises the traditional arguments of IMF critics:
In particular, the IMF has been attacked for its overemphasis on
demand management, blunt monetary-policy instruments, and 'shock'
treatment to reduce or eliminate inflation and balance of payments
disequilibria; its relative neglect of supply-side policies, longer
term development, and income distribution; and its traditional
aversion to controls, selective policy instruments, and 'gradualist'
approaches
While these older criticisms are still repeated today, they have
been updated. The IMF has been accused of exacerbating the trauma of the
Asian crisis, with contractionary monetary policies especially singled
out as interacting adversely with weak financial sectors, a policy
dilemma highlighted in recent research on 'twin crises'
(Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1999). More recently, commentators have put more
emphasis on the IMF's apparent inability to encourage meaningful
adjustment of any kind (for example, IFIAC (2000) also referred to as
the Meltzer Commission). (4) Are the critics correct?
The IMF's own research provides mixed reviews regarding the
outcome of its programmes. Haque and Khan (1998) review most of the
relevant research and conclude that IMF programmes do, in fact,
generally succeed at reducing the current account deficit. They go on to
suggest, however, that other targets are often not met. Thus, the
effects of programmes on inflation, while generally favourable, do not
seem to be statistically significant. Further, they conclude that
economic growth tends to decline in the early period of a programme, (5)
although it picks up over the medium-to-long term. Unfortunately, it is
in the early adjustment period that positive signals are required, and
it is not clear why other lenders would be motivated to provide
financing during the initial period of contraction when it is needed the
most. (6) One IMF study goes so far as to suggest that there may be
'some inherent inconsistency in the design of IMF programmes'
(Baqir et al., 2003, p.15), though it argues that this conclusion needs
to be treated tentatively.
The evidence from research conducted outside the IMF is even less
sanguine. Several studies have concluded that IMF programmes have
adverse consequences for investment and economic growth, or are
otherwise ineffective (Conway, 1994; Killick, 1995; Hutchison, 2001;
Przeworski and Vreeland, 2000; Barro and Lee, 2001; and Evrensel, 2002).
Why should the prospect of declining growth attract external capital? In
short, the evidence on the effectiveness of IMF programmes is not
unambiguously favourable, and agreements thus appear to provide a weak
signal upon which capital markets may base their financing decisions,
especially, early on in the adjustment phase.
Of course, one of the reasons for the relatively weak results
regarding IMF programmes may not be the conditions themselves, but their
execution. Signing an agreement with the IMF does not necessarily signal
commitment to carry through the agreed policies. (7) The relationship
between implementation and catalysis may be important because of its
potential circularity. If a good record of implementation fails to
generate a positive catalytic effect, then the burden on adjustment will
be greater than originally envisaged. The increased adjustment costs may
then make further implementation less likely, having a negative effect
on capital flows and imposing a further burden on current account
adjustment. A history of past agreements may be taken as indicating
entrenched problems or little commitment to reform.
According to the IMF's own research (Mussa and Savastano,
1999) the reality is that less than a half of the programmes that are
signed appear to be successfully implemented. Although the determinants
of implementation are not fully known, they seem to include a range of
domestic political variables, (Ivanova et al., 2001; Bird, 2002a). The
credibility of Fund programmes is also eroded by apparent serial
over-ambition. The Fund is regularly too optimistic about the prospects
for economic growth, export earnings, and tax revenue (IEO, 2002).
Further reason for doubting the credibility of programmes is
recidivism in IMF lending (Bird et al., 2004). About a half of the
recent programmes have been with countries that had made prolonged use
of IMF resources (IEO, 2002). The fact that some programmes that are
cancelled due to failed implementation are immediately replaced with a
new agreement, seems inconsistent with the signalling of commitment.
Empirical studies confirm that the existence of past programmes is a
significant factor in the econometric equations explaining current
programmes (Joyce, 1992; Conway, 1994; Knight and Santaella, 1997; Bird
and Rowlands, 2001). Therefore, negotiating a programme with the IMF for
many countries will indicate a high probability that they will continue
to face severe economic difficulties in the short-to-medium term, hardly
a signal that will foster confidence in capital markets. When
interviewed, money managers claimed that they formed their own
independent views and that they relied on these even when they disagreed
with those of the IMF (Bird and Rowlands, 2000).
Finally, the ability of the Fund to create more credible signals is
confounded by the appearance of political interference in its programme
structure and allocation. Thacker (1999) and Barro and Lee (2001)
provide large sample evidence to back up the considerable anecdotal accounts of IMF activity unduly reinforcing the direct political
interests of the United States. Bird and Rowlands (2001), while failing
to find similar evidence, identify other political influences that
systematically or idiosyncratically bias the allocation of Fund
agreements. Political noise will tend to interfere with the signal that
might otherwise be transmitted by an IMF programme.
Of course, capital markets are neither uninformed nor uniform, and
their response to the different elements of IMF programmes will
undoubtedly vary. Political interference, for example, may be seen as a
positive feature by official lenders and donors seeking to increase
their leverage. Private markets may be able to sort through the mixed
signals of different IMF agreements and respond differently to their
various effects over the course of the adjustment process. These
responses may also depend on the specific characteristics of the
recipient country, such as income level, economic structure, or
governance capacity. These potentially diverse reactions of the
different types of capital flows, which are already difficult to model
and estimate, will make it impractical to generalise about any catalytic
effect for the purposes of developing adjustment programmes.
What does the empirical evidence tell us about the catalytic
effect, and is this evidence consistent with the channels of
transmission outlined by Cottarelli and Giannini (2002)? Comprehensive
surveys of the empirical research pertaining to the catalytic effect
already exist (Bird and Rowlands, 2002; Cottarelli and Giannini, 2002).
The methodologies used have included some survey work (Bird and
Rowlands, 2000), case studies (Bird et al., 2000; Ghosh et al., 2002)
and large sample econometric investigation (Rodrik, 1996, Bird and
Rowlands, 1997, 2000, 2002; Edwards, 2000; Mody and Saravia, 2002).
There are several difficulties with which this research has attempted to
come to terms. First and foremost is the sheer number of possible
dependent, independent, and antecedent variables that need to be
examined in order to reflect the potential reactions to IMF programmes.
Second, there are problems with establishing the counterfactual and
dealing with selectivity bias: what would capital flows, policy reform,
and the path of adjustment have been in the absence of a Fund programme?
Third, it is important to determine the time horizon in which the
catalytic effect should be observed, and thus the lags between programme
and response that should be reflected in the models. Finally, it is
important to acknowledge the implications of balance of payments
accounting, since an improvement in the current account of the balance
of payments will be reflected by either a change in international
reserves or a reduction in net capital inflows. An advantage of using a
range of approaches for measuring the catalytic effect is that, while
each may have its own particular methodological problems, it is
reasonable to assume that common inferences are robust.
Early anecdotal reports seemed to take the catalytic effect as a
stylised fact, though there were dissenting voices (Bird, 1978; Killick,
1995). However, subsequent case study evidence suggested that the
catalytic effect was not general, but instead limited primarily to
official bilateral flows and to cases where there was supporting and
independent evidence of the recipient government's commitment to a
sound policy agenda (Bird et al., 2000). Research from the IMF was even
more pessimistic. Ghosh et al. (2002) concluded that in all of their
eight cases, private capital inflows were lower than predicted by the
IMF. Even in the case of Argentina, where the shortfall was the
smallest, they concluded that there was no evidence of the programme
having a strong catalytic effect. As a consequence, the size of the
current account adjustment was larger than originally envisaged in all
of the countries they had studied. In the cases of Korea and Thailand,
the discrepancy amounted to 13-15 per cent of GDP.
Large sample econometric investigation of the catalytic effect has
taken on a number of forms and is still evolving and becoming
increasingly sophisticated. Recent research is helping to specify the
parameters in which catalysis may operate. The strongest catalytic
effect is generally found for official flows (Rowlands, 2001), though
this appears to be more a question of coordination than traditional
catalysis. Bird and Rowlands (2002) focus on examining the range of
possible effects by differentiating between IMF agreements, recipient
country income levels, and various types of capital flows. This study
also attempts to control for IMF programme history and degrees of
programme implementation. No general catalytic effect is observed.
Instead, some programmes have a positive effect on some flows, but only
for certain groups of countries. In other instances, the effect is
insignificant or negative. The relationship between IMF programmes and
capital flows, therefore, appears as highly idiosyncratic. These results
do not appear to be related to problems of simultaneity, the direction
of causality (which appears to run in both directions), or selection
bias.
Selection bias is treated in a more sophisticated fashion in
Edwards (2000). If countries receiving IMF programmes are significantly
worse off than non-recipients, selection bias might lead to the
estimated catalytic effect being biased downwards. But no significant
selection bias is found. Edwards also examines the extent to which
catalysis is affected by the degree of compliance with IMF
conditionality. His results are even starker than Bird and Rowlands
(2002), reporting that good implementation does not seem to lead to
increased capital inflows. Worse still, poor implementation seems to
lead to reduced inflows. Edwards thus concludes that he finds 'no
evidence that the Fund serves as a seal of approval to foreign investors
and lenders.'
Capital flows may be intrinsically unstable and a decline in net
capital inflows may reflect a reduction in the current account deficit.
An alternative approach to estimating the catalytic effect is to examine
the effect of IMF lending on the interest rate charged on a
country's external debt and current borrowing, and on gross flows.
Early research that examined programme effects on interest spreads, at
least indirectly, is reported by Ozler (1993) and Haldane (1999). In
both cases spreads were found to widen alongside IMF programmes,
suggesting that signing a programme signals, or is correlated with,
payments difficulties. A more recent study by Mody and Saravia (2002)
examines both spreads and bond issuance. Because the data can be
measured with a higher frequency, they are able to improve on past
studies in terms of handling the complex timing issues and questions of
causality in a better way. While they find little to suggest that IMF
programmes on their own transmit a significant positive signal, a
positive catalytic effect can be discerned in bond markets when they are
accompanied by credible signals of commitment to policy reform, and when
the economic circumstances of the countries have not deteriorated too
far. They also find that precautionary programmes have more powerful
positive effects, and that longer term Extended Fund Facility programmes
have stronger effects than stand-by agreements.
Therefore, the research to date appears to suggest that the
catalytic effect does not operate in its traditional, general form.
Rather the direction and magnitude of catalysis is highly sensitive to a
variety of antecedent conditions and is not consistent across programmes
or capital flow measures. It should perhaps be a relief that capital
markets do not condition their decisions on simple signals such as the
announced signing of an agreement between a government and the IMF. One
of the secondary results of the research on catalysis is the conclusion
that explaining capital flows is inherently difficult; this being the
consequence of complex interactions between 'push' and
'pull' factors (Taylor and Sarno, 2000). Indeed, no recent
study of capital flows has felt compelled to include a variable that
directly captures the role of the IMF.
The complexity of the response to IMF agreements imposes serious
constraints on those attempting to construct a balance between external
financing and economic adjustment within the context of a Fund
programme. Evidence of a positive relationship between IMF lending and
official flows and debt rescheduling fails to provide much support for
the conventional concept of catalysis, but rather of concerted lending.
While new research may continue to discover additional nuances, it seems
unlikely that it will discover a strong and reliable catalytic effect,
as it has been traditionally portrayed. If true, this conclusion has
important and far-reaching implications for the design of policy.
Basically, it is unwise to rely on something that is unreliable.
POLICY OPTIONS FOR IMF PROGRAMMES
The policy problem faced by the IMF and its clients is how to
adjust to an unsustainable balance of payments structure. The basic
parameters of this process are defined by the level of external
financing that becomes available, which is inversely related to the
speed of adjustment that needs to take place. This inverse relationship has led some to argue for less IMF financing in order to encourage more
credible and rapid restructuring (Boockmann and Dreher, 2003; Vaubel,
1994). Others, however, including the IMF, would argue that such an
approach implies that the optimal rate of restructuring is necessarily
the fastest in all cases, and that the benefits of rapid adjustment
always outweigh any associated costs. The preference of the IMF (and
others) appears to be to assess this trade-off on a case-by-case basis
in an attempt to identify an optimal rate of restructuring that is both
politically and economically feasible. The result is supposed to be an
IMF programme that balances total external financing with adjustment.
The implication of an illusory catalytic effect is that IMF
programmes will tend to be under funded relative to their desired plan.
Consequently, more emphasis will be placed on swifter balance of
payments adjustment of the current account, as was reported across the
eight episodes examined by Ghosh et al. (2002). Consequently, countries
will have to bear higher welfare losses than initially conceived within
the agreement, especially as the shortfall will have to be made up
through a more aggressive contraction of aggregate demand. Such a
response is inconsistent with the Fund's Articles of Agreement. (8)
The political costs of adjustment will be higher, generating greater
problems for commitment and implementation and further compromising any
catalytic effect. There is little point in attempting to calculate the
required financial support for an adjustment programme if the failure to
generate it is regarded as a matter of no concern, nor does it enhance
the Fund's credibility if it claims to have a catalytic effect that
fails to materialise.
The previous analysis suggests two ways of addressing the
detrimental effects of a weak or absent catalytic effect. First, efforts
can be made to strengthen catalysis, using the information that has
emerged from the studies of both catalysis and its channels of
operation. Second, programmes may seek to limit the extent of any
necessary adjustment. These two broad approaches are examined in turn.
If catalysis is designed to work via conditionality, credibility
and time consistency, it may be strengthened by improving the
effectiveness of conditionality via programme design and implementation.
This is not an easy task. It is difficult to separate out the components
of current programmes that enhance catalysis from those that do not, or
to distinguish between programme content and implementation.
Considerable faith has been put into the notion of streamlining
conditionality and improving country ownership of programmes (Khan and
Sharma, 2001), and these may indeed be useful changes. However, the
evidence is less clear. Ivanova et al. (2001) suggest that the key
reasons for implementation failure are fundamental domestic political
economy problems, such as ethno-linguistic fractionalisation and
political disunity. These characteristics are difficult or impossible to
influence in the long term, let along in the compressed space of time
available for setting up an IMF agreement. While improved ownership
might make programmes more realistic, these implementation constraints
will impose severe limitations on the set of feasible adjustment paths.
Even if general policy initiatives fail, however, traditional
catalysis may still be useful in certain cases. Current research has
identified some circumstances in which catalysis may be present in a
sufficiently consistent and significant manner to allow the IMF to rely
on the leveraging of other finance to supplement its own resources.
Further research may allow these circumstances to be defined more
precisely and the magnitude of catalysis estimated more reliably.
Ideally, an IMF programme could even hope to bring about a more
desirable structure of external financing, using instruments that
encourage one form of capital inflow such as long-term bonds when these
are deemed to be both susceptible to catalysis and valuable for
diversifying a country's debt portfolio. We are, unfortunately, a
long way from being able to deploy IMF programmes with this degree of
precision.
A better understanding of the influence of different IMF agreements
will nonetheless help programming, as well as rationalising and
differentiating optimally the variety of facilities that the IMF
currently has on offer. Of course, caution needs to be exercised. The
Fund's experiment with its Contingent Credit Lines, which is
specifically built around the idea of precautionary programmes, has been
unsuccessful. Having already made one attempt to make the CCL more
user-friendly the Fund then embarked on a second review (November, 2002)
and eventually abandoned the facility in 2003. Yet in some ways the CCL
conformed well to the conditions that Mody and Saravia (2002) identify
as conducive to catalysis in bond markets: precautionary in nature, and
thus signed prior to the onset of serious problems or the need to draw
on it. Ultimately, countries have been reluctant to absorb the costs of
negotiating a programme if there is no guarantee of resources from the
Fund, as well as to carry the risk of spooking markets by transmitting
what might be interpreted as a negative signal. Stand-by agreements were
also initially seen as largely precautionary in nature, but have
subsequently evolved into a standard programme for financial
emergencies. The potential for programme restructuring, therefore, might
be quite limited.
If IMF programmes do not generally catalyse private lenders in the
traditional sense, modified versions of catalysis may still be relevant.
In principle, an alternative to catalysis is coercion, or to use a more
attractive term 'concerted lending'. The IMF adopted this
policy in the aftermath of the debt crisis over the period 1982-86. The
advantage of this approach is that the IMF will be in a relatively
stronger bargaining position vis a vis private lenders in the immediate
aftermath of a crisis, when the need to supplement their own resources
is the strongest. This bargaining power does erode, however, as
illustrated in the mid-1980s by the eventual abandonment of the Baker
Plan and its focus on setting unenforceable lending targets. In its
place, the international community adopted the Brady Plan, emphasising
debt relief and seeking to shift the bargaining power in favour of
debtors by having the IMF agree to lend to countries in payments
arrears. Today, private lenders and investors are more diverse, and the
legal framework and institutional imperatives faced by foreign investors
may make it difficult for them to be concerted. Despite these
difficulties, however, concerted lending was reactivated in Korea in
1998, suggesting that it might still be relevant under certain
conditions.
The ultimate form of concerted lending is the explicit coordination
of financing among official lenders and donors. Fewer players make
coordination easier. Moreover, aid donors may possess greater freedom of
manoeuvre, being subjected as they are to political constraints rather
than commercial imperatives. Although aid donors will be looking for
assurances about the conduct of economic policy in the same way as
private investors will be, they will have different objective functions.
They may indeed be attracted to lend to countries where the economic
fundamentals are weak. They may view IMF resources and their own as
largely substitutable, and thus potentially be willing to reduce the
resource burden on the Fund while still ensuring adequate programme
financing. While many forms of official development assistance (ODA) are
limited to poorer countries, the coordination of official creditors may
be relevant for a larger group of countries through the terms of Paris
Club rescheduling. These reschedulings, which effectively require an IMF
agreement to be negotiated, offer an opportunity to alter the debt
payments of a country in a manner that can mimic catalysis, even though
it is not really catalysis in the conventional sense. Not surprisingly,
it is in the context of debt rescheduling that evidence supporting a
positive association with IMF programmes has been discovered (Marchesi,
2001).
The final method of dealing with shortfalls in finance is to have
the Fund provide the money directly. Of course, this approach would
presumably impose a significant resource cost on the IMF. There are at
least two potential drawbacks. The most obvious problem is that such a
policy may require member countries to increase the resources of the
IMF. The reluctance of some of the Fund's major shareholders to
endorse the increase in quotas associated with the Eleventh General
Review may be indicative of a general reluctance to do so. Indeed, it
could be surmised that the attention paid to catalysis in the Prague
Framework in part resulted from dissatisfaction among some powerful
shareholders of the Fund with enhancing the Fund's own lending
capacity. Second, there may be some understandable hesitation if members
anticipate that a larger resource base might also encourage the Fund to
assert greater independence. Others may view a downgrading of catalysis
as the elimination of private oversight considering the efficacy of the
IMF. In short, more resources might be seen as permitting the IMF to
ignore the views of other key players in the international financial
system. (9)
Therefore, a range of catalytic or catalytic-type effects might be
marshalled in specific circumstances to enhance financing, and hence the
viability of IMF programmes. If these are unavailable, what alternative
does the IMF have? One approach would be to alter the degree of
adjustment needed by a country through other means. These have already
been alluded to in the context of improving catalysis, and involve the
timing of IMF programmes and situations of crisis.
The stated preference of the Fund is to become involved with
countries prior to the emergence of severe economic difficulties. This
'lender of first resort' function also seems consistent with
the evidence on catalysis provided by Mody and Saravia (2002). By
heading off difficulties, however, the Fund's conditions would be
less onerous and the Fund's resource commitments could also be
smaller. The long-stated desire by the Fund, however, has not yet
translated into early intervention. Encouraging countries to turn to the
IMF earlier in the evolution of their balance of payments problems will
remain a challenge for as long as conditionality is seen by countries to
impose significant costs. Moreover, if at this stage countries continue
to have access to private capital markets, some of the Fund's
shareholding countries may argue that they should not be seeking to use
IMF resources. After all, governments have to have a balance of payments
need before they are eligible to draw resources from the Fund.
Ultimately, and in extremis, strong fundamentals might power up the
catalytic effect but they would also eliminate the need for Fund
involvement and perhaps also for its catalytic effect. The empirical
evidence on catalysis suggests that private markets will be more
prepared to lend to countries that have less need to borrow.
While some programme structure might yet be discovered that will
encourage voluntary early resort to the IMF, the more likely route is
the more aggressive use of Article IV consultations and a re-emphasis of
its traditional surveillance functions (Pauly, 1997). Reliance on this
mechanism might be more credible if it were applied more evenly across
the Fund's membership as well, particularly to its wealthier
members. Aside from moral suasion, however, there are no obvious
enforcement mechanisms the IMF could rely on to compel countries to seek
early intervention. In addition, it is hard to imagine nations providing
the IMF with a means of enforcement that would jeopardise members'
sovereignty.
If the scope of adjustment cannot be modified before economic
crisis sets in, it may be possible to do so immediately afterwards. As
noted in the discussion of coerced lending, crises may provide the IMF
and its key members with considerable leverage over private lenders.
Thus, for example, proposals for a Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism (SDRM) may be viewed as an alternative to catalysis. (10)
There are also more general forms of intervention such as IMF-endorsed
standstills on debt repayments and capital controls. In the longer run,
and if such mechanisms were to enable countries to move towards debt
sustainability, they could even themselves exert a positive catalytic
effect on future capital flows. The most reliable effect would be in the
short run, however, where such policies may be useful in moderating
capital flight. Consequently, the need for adjustment would be reduced.
In principle, what might be achieved by an SDRM for middle-income
countries could be achieved by the Heavily Indebted Poor Country (HIPC)
initiative for low-income countries. Of course, HIPC-related
negotiations need not take place in the same environment of financial
crisis as might be relevant for the other forms of intervention, and
might thus be more generally applicable. There are current doubts,
however, about whether HIPC will be successful in allowing eligible
countries to exit from their debt problems. Since debt problems appear
to impede catalysis, it may be unwise to regard these initiatives as
substitutes for the catalytic effect. Resolving them may contribute
towards stronger catalysis in the future, and may even be close to a
pre-condition for effective catalysis.
The outline of an adjustment policy for the IMF may be traced from
the discussion in this section. There appear to be some instances where
the traditional catalysis of private capital markets might work.
Although considerably more research is needed to specify these instances
with reasonable certainty, it may be possible eventually to build some
agreements around catalysis in its traditional sense. In situations
where such catalysis is unreliable, the IMF may wish to make
arrangements to make up any apparent shortfalls from its own resources
or those of other official lenders. These agreements may also be made
more effective if the IMF were to push for earlier adoption. Continuing
to experiment with innovations, such as streamlining conditionality and
improving country ownership, may also help to identify programmes that
have more desirable effects and better chances of implementation. This
approach seems most relevant to middle-income countries with access to
capital markets that are not in the midst of crisis.
When crisis does hit emerging market countries, the best
alternative to catalysis is likely to be coerced lending to maximise new
inflows in conjunction with some form of controls or standstills to
limit outflows. Laying out the guidelines for crisis management of this
sort will allow the market to work with clearer information, and will
hopefully have the salutary effect of reducing political interference by
wealthier nations. Of course, it may be the case that wealthier nations
will also need to provide additional finance either directly on a
bilateral basis, or indirectly via lending to and through the IMF.
Official financing will also play the most significant role in
poorer countries, for which traditional catalysis is probably
irrelevant. For these countries the emphasis needs to be on increasing
programme performance and implementation, more generous debt forgiveness
to restore debt sustainability, and improved official financing in the
context of adjustment. Official financing needs to be coordinated and
made explicit for agreements while at the same time minimising its
impact on future debt sustainability. In the end it needs to be
recognised that many of the poorest countries do not use the IMF in the
manner in which it was originally meant to be used. Rather than facing
temporary balance of payments problems, these countries face longer term
structural problems associated with low levels of economic development.
Programmes need to reflect this, and they should be distinguished from
those deployed in emerging market middle-income countries in an effort
to preserve some signalling capacity for the latter.
Thus by differentiating member characteristics, adjustment
circumstances, and programmes, the IMF might be able to achieve the
balance between financing and adjustment that catalysis is not currently
providing on a consistent basis. By formalising these distinctions, the
Fund may be able to reduce the noise-to-signal component of its
agreements, and thus permit catalysis to function properly.
CONCLUDING REMARKS
Capital flows to developing and emerging economies have been
falling since the East Asian financial crisis in 1997/98. Combined with
the desire to replenish international reserves, this has implied that
countries have had to substantially strengthen their current account
balance of payments. Such adjustment carries a cost. In a period of
declining capital inflows it has become important to consider
alternative ways in which foreign capital can be mobilised. This issue
is likely to become increasingly important as tighter regulation and
prudential control in capital markets and an increased use of risk
management techniques tend to reduce international capital flows still
further.
This paper has examined the role of the IMF in mobilising capital
flows to emerging and developing economies. The nature of the
relationship between the IMF and private capital markets and official
finance is complex. There are aspects of both complementarity and
substitutability in it. The topic has received high-profile attention,
and the associated discussion has raised very fundamental questions
about the role of the IMF. Some observers argue that IMF lending creates
severe moral hazard problems and delays necessary adjustment. Others,
however, suggest that adjustment has taken place without concern for its
adverse consequences, political feasibility, or sustainability, and
without sufficient adjustment-related financing. In trying to strike the
right balance between adjustment and external finance, the Fund has
placed much emphasis on the catalytic effect of its lending.
The review and analysis in this paper casts doubt on the
traditional notion of catalysis as a passive but reliable mechanism for
increasing a wide range of external capital inflows for countries with
an IMF agreement. Consequently, it is crucial to consider alternative
policy approaches by which the Fund may attempt to mobilise capital and
strengthen the financial position of emerging market and developing
economies. By differentiating between low- and middle-income countries,
between private and public capital flows, between crisis and non-crisis
lending contexts, and between different IMF facilities, it might be
possible to restore the balance between financing and adjustment in a
more optimal manner. Some of the proposed policies are likely to prove
controversial, while others might be technically impractical. However,
the failure to compensate for an elusive catalytic effect in a more
meaningful way will relegate many IMF recipients to a cycle of programme
failure and continued economic unsustainability.
The next few years may be dominated by the problem of helping
emerging and developing countries to gain the access to the foreign
capital they need in order to complement their own developmental
efforts. In this regard, the problem has changed markedly from that of
the early 1990s when there were excessive capital inflows and the focus
of the Fund was on stabilising them. Capital markets tend to exhibit
patterns of feast and famine. In the middle of the famine years reliance
on the largely illusory catalytic effect is unlikely to be sufficient.
More radical action will be required. Without it global welfare could be
significantly and adversely affected.
Acknowledgements
While the views expressed in the paper should be attributed only to
us, we gratefully acknowledge the financial support of the British
Academy.
(1) There are various studies that examine the economic
circumstances in which countries turn to the 1MF for financial
assistance (Bird, 1997; Conway, 1994; Killick, 1995; Knight and
Santaella, 1997).
(2) There are various other statements by politicians in both the
US and UK and by academics which suggest that the catalytic effect has
been widely believed to exist (Bird and Rowlands, 1997: Cottarelli and
Giannini, 2002).
(3) In this paper, we ignore the insurance role because it is
directly related to the problem of moral hazard, a topic that has
received considerable recent attention in this own right and is best
dealt with separately. Moral hazard is generally discussed in terms of
the potential for lenders to provide excessive credit in anticipation of
being bailed out by a subsequent IMF programme. An alternative version
of moral hazard is that the promise of subsequent IMF assistance causes
governments to delay needed adjustment and engage in inefficient
policy-making. For recent discussion and evidence, see Dreher (2004);
Dreher and Vaubel (2004); Rogoff (2002); Evrensel (2002);
Dell'Ariccia et al. (2002); Lane and Phillips (2000); and
Nunnenkamp (1999).
(4) Mussa and Savastano (1999) provide an interesting review of,
and response to, the main criticisms.
(5) This initial negative effect is hardly surprising and may
indeed be a necessary element of adjustment. The debate is over the
extent to which it is relied on in order to restore external
equilibrium.
(6) Khan and Sharma (2001, p. 12) suggest that recent evidence is
more favourable, but provide no information.
(7) Bird (2002b) concludes that programmes are unlikely to have
strong credibility and that the signalling effect is as likely to be
negative as positive, and generally quite weak.
(8) Article 1, sub section v, states that the purposes of the IMF
include giving 'confidence to members by making the general
resources of the Fund temporarily available to them under adequate
safeguards, thus providing them with the opportunity to correct
maladjustments in their balance of payments without resorting to
measures destructive of national or international prosperity.'
(9) Although, as noted earlier, diminishing the extent to which
political interference affects Fund behaviour might allow it to send
clearer signals to financial markets.
(10) A useful summary of the evolution of the SDRM may be found in
Rogoff and Zettelmeyer (2002). For a critical assessment, see
Eichengreen (2002) who basically claims that such a mechanism would tip
the balance too much in favour of debtors vis a vis creditors. For a
long time, Eichengreen has argued that modifying bond contracts to
include collective action clauses would be a superior way of organising
orderly debt workouts. This view seems to reflect the current views of
the US Treasury as well.
REFERENCES
Baqir, R, Ramcharan, R and Sahay, R. 2003: The consistency of IMF
programs. IMF Research Workshop 'Macroeconomic Challenges in Low
Income Countries'.
Barro, RJ and Lee, J-W. 2001: IMF Programs: Who is chosen and what
are the effects? Paper presented at 2nd IMF Research Conference.
Bird, G. 1978: The International Monetary System and the less
developed countries. Macmillan: London.
Bird, G. 1997: External financing and balance of payments
adjustment in developing countries: Getting a better policy mix. World
Development 25(9): 1409-1420.
Bird, G. 2002a: The completion rate of IMF programs: What we know,
don't know and need to know. The World Economy 25(6): 833-847.
Bird, G. 2002b: The credibility and signalling effect of IMF
programs. Journal of Policy Modeling 24(9): 799-811.
Bird, G, Mori, A and Rowlands, D. 2000: Do the multilaterals
catalyse other capital flows? A case study analysis. Third World
Quarterly 21(3): 483-503.
Bird, G, Hussain, M and Joyce, JP. 2004: Many happy returns?
Recidivism and the IMF. Journal of International Money and Finance
23(2): 231-251.
Bird, G and Rowlands, D. 1997: The catalytic effect of lending by
the international financial institutions. The World Economy 20(7):
967-991.
Bird, G and Rowlands, D. 2000: The catalyzing role of policy-based
lending by the IMF and the World Bank: Fact or fiction? Journal of
International Development 12: 951-973.
Bird, G and Rowlands, D. 2001: IMF lending: How is it affected by
economic, political, and institutional factors? Journal of Policy Reform
4(3): 243-270.
Bird, G and Rowlands, D. 2002: Do IMF programs have a catalytic
effect on other international capital flows? Oxford Development Studies
30(3): 229-249.
Boockmann, B and Dreher, A. 2003: The contribution of the IMF and
the World Bank to economic freedom. European Journal of Political
Economy 19(3): 633-649.
Conway, P. 1994: IMF lending programs: Participation and impact.
Journal of Development Economics 45(2): 365-391.
Cottarelli, C and Giannini, C. 2002: Bedfellows, hostages, or
perfect strangers? Global capital markets and the catalytic effect of
IMF crisis lending. IMF Working paper no. 02/193.
Dell'Ariccia, G, Schnabel, I and Zettelmeyer, J. 2002: Moral
hazard and international crisis lending: A test. IMF Working paper WP
02/181.
Dreher, A and Vaubel, R. 2004: Do IMF and IBRD cause moral hazard
and political business cycles? Evidence from panel data. Open Economies
Review 15(1): 5-22.
Edwards, MS. 2000: Re-evaluating the catalytic effect of IMF
programs. Paper presentation at the Annual Meetings of the American
Political Science Association. Washington, DC (September).
Eichengreen, B. 2002: Financial crises and what to do about them.
Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Evrensel, A. 2002: Effectiveness of IMF-supported stabilization
programs in developing countries. Journal of International Money and
Finance 21(5): 565-587.
Ghosh, A, Lane, T, Schultze-Gattas, M, Bulir, A, Hamann, J and
Mourmouras, A. 2002: IMF supported programs in capital account crisis.
IMF Occasional paper no. 210. International Monetary Fund: Washington.
Haldane, A. 1999: Private sector involvement in financial crises:
Analytics and public policy approaches. Financial Stability Review,
November.
Haque, NUI and Khan, MS. 1998: Do IMF-supported programs work? A
survey of the cross-country empirical evidence. IMF Working paper no.
98/169.
Helleiner, G. 1983: The IMF and Africa in the 1980s. Princeton
Essays in International Finance No. 146. Princeton University:
Princeton.
Hutchison, MM. 2001: A cure worse than the disease? Currency crises
and the output costs of IMF-supported stabilization programs. In:
Dooley, M and Frankel JA (eds). Managing Currency Crises in Emerging
Markets. University of Chicago: Chicago.
Independent Evaluation Office. 2002: Evaluation of the prolonged
use of IMF resources. IMF: Washington, DC.
International Financial Institutions Advisory Committee. 2000:
Report of the International Financial Institutions Advisory Committee.
Washington, DC.
International Monetary Finance. 2002: What is the International
Monetary Fund? www.imf.org Updated August 2002.
Ivanova, A, Mayer, W, Mourmouras, A and Anayiotas, G. 2001: What
determines the success or failure of fund-supported programs? Paper
presented at 2nd IMF Research Conference.
Joyce, JP. 1992: The economic characteristics of IMF program
countries. Economics Letters 38: 237-242.
Kaminsky, G and Reinhart, C. 1999: The twin crises: The causes of
banking and balance-of-payments problems. American Economic Review
89(3): 473-500.
Khan, M and Sharma, S. 2001: IMF conditionality and country
ownership of programs. IMF Working paper no. 01/142.
Killick, T. 1995: IMF programs in developing countries--design and
impact. Routledge: London.
Knight, M and Santaella, JA. 1997: Economic determinants of IMF
financial arrangements. Journal of Development Economics 54(2): 405-426.
Lane, T and Phillips, S. 2000: Does IMF financing result in moral
hazard? IMF Working paper no. 00/168.
Marchesi, S. 2001: Adoption of an IMF program and Debt
rescheduling. An empirical analysis. Development Studies Working papers no. 152. University of Oxford/Queen Elizabeth House: Oxford.
Mody, A and Saravia, D. 2002: Catalyzing private capital flows: Do
IMF programmes work us commitment devices. IMF Working paper.
Mussa, M and Savastano, M. 1999: The IMF approach to economic
stabilization. IMF Working paper no. 99/104.
Nowzad, B. 1981: The IMF and its critics. Princeton Essays in
International Finance No. 146. Princeton University: Princeton.
Nunnenkamp, P. 1999: The moral hazard of IMF lending: Making a fuss
about a minor problem? Kiel Institute of World Economics Discussion
paper no. 332.
Ozler, S. 1993: Have commercial banks ignored history? American
Economic Review 83(3): 608-620.
Pauly, L. 1997: Who elected the bankers? Surveillance and control
in the world economy. Cornell University Press: Ithaca and London.
Przeworski, A and Vreeland, JR. 2000: The effect of IMF programs on
economic growth. Journal of Development Economics 62(2): 385-421.
Rodrik, D. 1996: Why is there multilateral lending? In: Bruno, M
and Pleskovic, B (eds). Annual World Bank Conference on Development
Economics. World Bank: Washington, DC.
Rogoff, K. 2002: Moral hazard in IMF loans: How big a concern?
Finance and Development 39(3).
Rogoff, K and Zettelmeyer, J. 2002: Bankruptcy procedures for
sovereigns: A history of ideas, 1976-2001. IMF Working paper no. 02/133.
IMF: Washington, DC.
Rowlands, D. 2001: The response of other lenders to the IMF. Review
of International Economics 9(3): 531-546.
Taylor, M and Sarno, L. 2000: Capital flows to developing
countries: Long term and short term determinants. World Bank Economic
Review 14.
Thacker, SC. 1999: The high politics of IMF lending, World Politics
52(1): 38-75.
Vaubel, R. 1994: The political economy of the IMF: A public choice
analysis. In: Bandow D and Vasquez I (eds). Perpetuating Poverty: The
World Bank, the IMF, and the Developing World. The Cato Institute:
Washington, DC.
Graham Bird (1) & Dane Rowlands (2)
(1) Surrey Centre for International Economic Studies, University of
Surrey, Guildford, Surrey GU2 7XH, UK E-mail: g.bird@surrey.ac.uk;
(2) The Norman Paterson School of International Affairs, Carleton
University, Ottawa, Canada