IMF conditionality and the theory of special interest politics (1).
Mayer, Wolfgang ; Mourmouras, Alex
INTRODUCTION
The International Monetary Fund (IMF) was created in the aftermath
of World War II to promote stability and prosperity in the international
monetary and financial system. A key function of the IMF is to make
loans to countries facing shortages of foreign exchange. The IMF's
financial support gives countries breathing room, while they adjust
their economic policies to solve their external payment difficulties. To
ensure that borrowing governments follow policies that are consistent
with the IMF's purposes, its financial resources are disbursed
gradually and on condition that borrowers avoid measures that are
destructive to national and international prosperity. The IMF's
rules for disbursing assistance have evolved gradually and have been
continuously adapted to solve emerging problems--recycling petrodollars in the 1970s, overcoming the debt crisis in the 1980s, and integrating
the transition countries and dealing with capital-account crises in the
1990s.
While necessary, conditionality has become somewhat controversial
over the years, leading to periodic reviews--within the IMF and by the
broader academic community--of the analytical principles underlying it
and the practical ways in which it has been applied. The most recent
such internal review was conducted during 2000-2002, with extensive
external input and participation. The review highlighted the critical
importance of country ownership, defined as the ability and willingness
of country authorities and other key stakeholders to implement policy
programmes agreed with the IMF, which was underscored by the poor record
of some programmes that were not based on reasonably broad coalitions in
recipient countries. It concluded that while country ownership of
policies depends in the first place on the borrowing countries'
domestic political economy, it can be influenced by the IMF's
methods of interaction with these countries. Reforms in the IMF's
processes now under way, including the streamlining and focusing of
conditionality and greater tailoring of programmes to the circumstances
of member countries, will ensure that IMF-supported reforms will enjoy
greater domestic ownership. The importance of promoting country
ownership and of limiting conditionality to measures that are critical
to the success of programmes is reflected in the revised IMF
conditionality guidelines (IMF, 2002).
This paper presents some analytics of IMF conditionality based on
the theory of special interest politics (Grossman and Helpman, 2001).
This theory appeals to lobbying by special interest groups in order to
explain why policymakers in the real world often prefer to use
distortionary policies. The next section presents our political-economy
model of the IMF, which applies the theory of special interest politics
to understand the role of IMF conditionality in shaping economic
policies of recipient governments (Mayer and Mourmouras, 2002). The
subsequent section discusses how conditionality helps matters in the
presence of various domestic and international conflicts of interest.
The last section concludes.
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF IMF CONDITIONALITY
Overview
To be an effective incentive system (Dixit, 2000), IMF
conditionality must guide policymakers in recipient countries to improve
their policy choices. This begs the question of why these choices are
distorted and how IMF conditionality helps matters. The theory of
principals and agents, which focuses on the role of incentives and
strategic interactions, is useful in addressing both questions. The IMF
is an agent of the international community that created it, established
its mandate, and endowed it with financial resources. The conditionality
attached to IMF loans provides the international community with certain
payoffs. Principal among these are the assurances that these loans will
be repaid. Since the IMF does not impose collateral requirements,
conditionality is part of the IMF's financial due diligence. In
addition, conditionality helps steer borrowing countries toward stable
and outward-oriented economic policies and avoid measures that are
destructive of national or international prosperity (Article I (v)).
Finally, conditionality also guarantees borrowing countries certain
rights. Once an IMF loan is committed, borrowers are assured that they
will continue receiving IMF financing if they meet the conditions
specified in the loan agreement. (2) The IMF cannot arbitrarily
'move the goal-post' after an agreement is signed. The
IMF's internal rules also guarantee that borrowing countries are
not unduly discriminated against (uniformity of treatment).
Recent developments in the political-economy literature address why
economic policy choices are distorted and how IMF conditional loans
assist in reducing these distortions. The key innovation has been the
move away from the unitary-actor view of borrowing countries. These
multi-actor models feature domestic conflicts of interest that prevent
recipient-country governments from adopting first-best policies. The
lobbying models of the theory of special interest politics is one such
approach. Veto-player models are another. (3) In lobbying models, a
government's policy choices reflect the joint influence of
organised interest groups as well as the pursuit of public welfare. The
mathematical foundation of special interest politics is the theory of
common agency, which is concerned with strategic interactions of
multiple actors (principals) who compete in their efforts to influence a
common decision maker (agent). (4)
In this paper, we embed the IMF--modelled as an international lobby
that pursues the international public interest--in a standard lobbying
model. The combined influence of the IMF and domestic interest groups on
government policy choices is analysed using an approach that is standard
in the theory of special interest politics. Equilibrium policy choices
are the outcome of strategic interactions between the IMF, borrowing
governments and domestic lobbies in an interdependent world economy.
Conditionality furthers the IMF's broad internationalist objectives
and helps resolve conflicts of interest that surface between the IMF and
debtor governments. (5) A key feature of our model is the assumption
that policy choices have cross-border spillover effects. While national
actors--policymakers and lobbies alike--may ignore such externalities,
we assume that the IMF takes them into account in setting its
conditionality.
The impact of organised special interest groups (SIGs) on economic
policy formation has been recognised since at least the work of Olson
(1965). Interest groups that overcome the free-rider problems present in
collective action can influence policymakers to adopt policies that
favour them. In many cases, favours to SIGs come at the expense of
general welfare, yet the general public is broadly dispersed and
unorganised. The effectiveness of lobbying by vested interests increases
with the extent of the imperfection in national economic and political
systems. In countries in which the preferences of ordinary citizens are
not very well reflected in government decisions, vested interests can
assume control of the agenda and dictate policies to the detriment of
the general welfare. Imperfections in economic and political systems
reflect costly and limited information about the impacts of policy
changes and uncertainty about the identity of winners and losers, which
makes it difficult for winners to compensate losers. These difficulties
are compounded when different countries are involved and place
considerable limits on the range of feasible international economic
policy choices.
Key to the success of interest groups' efforts to influence
policies is policymakers' electoral and selfish concerns. At a
general level, all politicians weigh the political benefits and costs of
alternative policy choices and choose actions that maximise their
overall political support. Political support depends on national
well-being (economic growth, poverty reduction, etc.), as well as
backing by influential stakeholders. In practice, special interests play
a key role in constraining policy reforms in developing and transition
countries (the IMF's main borrowers). (6) Despite the spread of
democracy and pluralism in recent decades, governments in many
developing and transition economies lack sufficient transparency and
accountability. Many institutions needed for the effective exercise of
political 'voice' and the operation of checks and balances
remain weak, and ordinary citizens have limited information about their
rights or their government's responsibilities. These imperfections
make it easier for vested interests and veto players to exert large
political influence. To give but one example, banks, state enterprises
and farms in some transition and developing countries were captured by
small groups of politically connected people. Some transition-economy
enterprises became instruments of vested interests, earning rents for
politically powerful groups at the expense of producers or consumers. In
the process, growth, equity and aggregate welfare declined more than
expected, making transition a much more arduous process than originally
anticipated.
Recent applied work, including papers written for the IMF's
2000-2002 conditionality review, underscored the key role of domestic
divisions and special interests in limiting the effectiveness of
IMF-supported reforms (IMF, 2001a-c). Ivanova et al. (2003) show that
the implementation of IMF-supported programmes suffers in countries in
which an index of the strength of special interests is strong. The
quality of key institutions is important for understanding programme
implementation and macroeconomic performance in countries implementing
IMF-supported reforms (Nsouli et al., 2004). The importance of
overcoming domestic divisions and forging consensus behind reforms is
often couched in terms of the need to enhance country ownership for
sound policies. Though the evidence--from case studies and econometric work --is indirect, it does point to the key role of ownership for the
implementation of IMF-supported reforms (Bird, 2002; Boughton and
Mourmouras, 2002; Khan and Sharma, 2003; Willett, 2003). This evidence
is similar to findings about World Bank-supported programmes (Dollar and
Svensson, 2000).
The empirical studies also conclude that IMF financing and
conditionality have had inconclusive impacts on countries'
macroeconomic and structural performance. A key theme is the relatively
weak record of programme implementation. If programmes are not
consistently implemented, their desired effects will not be realised,
and the considerable resources countries invest in negotiating
programmes will not yield high returns, as Bird (2002) points out. (7)
Reconciling the theoretical case for conditionality, as it emerges from
the model of special interest politics presented in this paper, with the
nuanced empirical evidence is a key challenge in designing
conditionality.
A model
The incentive effects of IMF conditionality can be analysed with
the help of a simple political-economy model (Mayer and Mourmouras,
2002). Consider a world economy consisting of two groups of countries,
those who are creditors of the IMF and those making use of IMF resources
(debtors). The IMF is a financial intermediary that represents the
interests of both groups of countries. It acquires real resources
(capital) T from creditor countries and transfers them (on loan) to the
governments of debtor countries. The IMF's objective is to help
countries address policy distortions that reduce national and
international welfare. We assume that IMF assistance is channeled in
socially beneficial ways. We also abstract from time inconsistency and
credit risk by assuming that repayment of IMF loans is guaranteed at the
contracted (but possibly subsidised) interest rate.
Let W and [W.sup.*], respectively, denote gross national welfare in
debtor and creditor countries after IMF resources have been disbursed
but before they have been repaid to the IMF and its creditors. Letting b
be the gross rate of IMF repayment (unity plus the IMF's rate of
charge), then net social welfare in a debtor country after the loan has
been disbursed and repaid is equal to gross welfare minus loan
repayments, or
(1a) Y = W - bT
Likewise, net social welfare in creditor countries, after IMF loans
have been disbursed and repaid, is
(1b) [Y.sup.*] = [W.sup.*] + bT
The IMF's objective is to maximise the weighted sum of net
world welfare, or
(2) I = [Y.sup.*] + [gamma]Y
where [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 0 is the weight which the
IMF attaches to the utility of debtor countries. This specification of
the IMF's objective function is consistent with the Articles of
Agreements, which mandate the institution to safeguard the stability and
prosperity of the international monetary and financial system. (8)
In addition to the IMF (I), the model features two other actors,
the incumbent government of the debtor country (G), and a domestic SIG
in that country. As in Grossman and Helpman, the government maximizes a
political support function which depends on the general public's
welfare and on SIG campaign contributions. We denote by [omega] [greater
than or equal to] 0 an index of policy distortions under the control of
the government. The country's social welfare would be maximised by
following first-best policies (i.e., setting the distortion index to
zero). The government's objective function is a weighted sum of SIG
contributions, C([omega]), and net social welfare:
(3) G([omega], T) = C([omega]) + aY([omega], T)
The parameter a [greater than or equal to] 0 is the
government's concern for its public's welfare relative to
interest group contributions. Maximising (3) will result in policy
choices that deviate from first-best.
The SIG benefits from distorted economic policies. Its gross
utility, U([omega]), increases at a decreasing rate with the degree of
distortions ([U.sub.[omega] > 0 and [U.sub.[omega][omega]] < 0).
The SIG's net utility is gross utility less political
contributions,
(4) V([omega]) = U([omega]) - C([omega])
The SIG designs its contribution schedule C([omega]) to maximise
its political influence. The assumption that the interest group's
welfare rises with the degree of policy distortions can be derived from
microfoundations (see next section), but it can also be justified
heuristically as follows. While there are many possible policy
distortions, some benefiting and some hurting the SIG, it will pay the
interest group to apply pressure only for the adoption of those
distortions from which it will benefit. Distortions whose net effect
hurts both the SIG and the general public are certainly possible. But
the SIG will not push for them and so we can disregard them.
Several additional assumptions are made in what follows. First, IMF
assistance is subject to diminishing returns, implying that W rises with
T but at a decreasing rate ([W.sub.T] > 0, [W.sub.TT] < 0).
Second, social welfare declines at an increasing rate as distortions
rise ([W.sub.[omega]] < 0, [W.sub.[omega][omega]] < 0). This
assumption is consistent with the fact that the excess burden of
distortionary taxes or subsidies is an increasing and convex function of
the level of taxes or subsidies. Third, greater distortions reduce the
effectiveness of IMF assistance ([W.sub.T[omega]] < 0). This
assumption is consistent with the results in the aid-effectiveness
literature that foreign assistance is more valuable in good policy
environments (Burnside and Dollar, 1998, 2000). Fourth, since creditor
countries finance IMF lending, they incur financial costs by providing
assistance but reap benefits when debtor countries repay the IMF, so
that [W.sup.*.sub.T] < 0 and [W.sup.*.sub.TT] < 0. Fifth, the
world economy is interdependent in the sense that the policy distortions
of countries making use of IMF resources may affect welfare in creditor
countries ([W.sup.*.sub.[omega]] < 0 and
[W.sup.*.sub.[omega][omega]], < 0 if a debtor country is
'systemically' important). On the other hand, the IMF provides
conditional assistance to small countries (those whose policies do not
influence conditions in creditor countries, or [W.sup.*.sub.[omega]]
< 0) only to the extent that it has altruistic concerns for them.
Finally, we assume [U.sub.[omega]](0) + a-[W.sub.[omega]] (0,0) > 0.
This condition states that if the recipient country is left on its own,
then it is not in the government's interest to maintain undistorted policies (i.e., if T = 0, then the government will not adopt the
first-best policy [omega] = 0).
Micro foundations
The reduced-form model just outlined can be derived from rigorous
microfoundations. Consider an economy consisting of two sectors,
industries [X.sub.1] and [X.sub.2] with production functions [X.sub.j] =
h(T)[f.sub.j]([L.sub.j], [K.sub.j]), where [L.sub.j] and [K.sub.j] are
labour and capital employed in industry j. Private capital is
industry-specific and does not flow between sectors (specific-factor
model), while labour is perfectly mobile between sectors ([L.sub.1] +
[L.sub.2] = L). Foreign assistance T is used to build up the
infrastructure needed to underpin a market economy, broadly construed to
include physical infrastructure as well as institutions such as property
rights and law enforcement. Assistance results in an unbiased expansion
of the economy's production possibilities.
The country in question is small (price taker), markets are
perfectly competitive, and the relative world price of good X in terms
of good Y is [pi]. A SIG owns private capital specific to industry 1 and
makes contributions to the government in exchange for production
subsidies paid to industry 1. The subsidy results in misallocation of
resources, lowering national income. National income is
(5) W = [pi][X.sub.1], + [X.sub.2] = [pi]h(T)[f.sub.1]([L.sub.1],
[K.sub.1]) + h(T)[f.sub.2]([L.sub.2], [K.sub.2])
where h'(T) > 0 and h"(T) < 0. The domestic price
of [X.sub.1] in the presence of the subsidy is P = [pi] (1 + [omega]),
where [omega] is the production subsidy rate. The return paid to the
industry-specific capital employed in industry 1 is
(6) [r.sub.1] = [pi](1
+[omega])h(T)([differential][f.sub.1]/[differential][K.sub.1])
In this setting, the following propositions can he established
(proofs are available from the authors). First, a higher production
subsidy lowers the country's national income, and this decline is
more pronounced the more assistance is received. Second, if assistance
increases, then [differential][[differential]W/[differential][omega]/[differential]T < 0. Finally, the welfare of the SIG, U([omega]) =
[r.sub.1]([omega])[K.sub.1], rises with subsidies, or [differential]U/
[differential][omega] > 0. These propositions justify the assumptions
[W.sub.T[omega]] < 0 and [differential]U/[differential][omega] > 0
made in the previous section.
Political equilibrium
Following Bernheim and Winston and Grossman and Helpman, the
outcome of the strategic interaction between the borrowing-country
government, the domestic SIG, and the IMF, can be analysed as an
equilibrium of a non-cooperative, multi-stage game. The nature of the
game (timing and other aspects of the strategic interactions between the
three players) depends on the type of assistance offered by the IMF,
whether unconditional or conditional.
Unconditional assistance
The political equilibrium with unconditional assistance is
([[omega].sup.0], [C.sup.0]) the outcome of a three-stage
non-cooperative game. In the first stage, the IMF decides on the total
amount of assistance. In the second stage, the SIG tenders a
contribution schedule to the government. This schedule is designed to
maximise the SIG's net welfare. In the third stage, the government
chooses the index of policy distortions to maximise its political
support, taking as given the interest group's contribution schedule
and the IMF's assistance.
Without loss of generality, we focus on truthful equilibria.
Truthful equilibria are a refinement of Nash equilibria and are unique.
Their key property is that SIG contributions accurately reflect the
group's gains from increased policy distortions. If the equilibrium
is truthful, then in response to an increase in policy distortions the
lobby raises its contribution by an amount equal to the marginal utility it derives from the additional distortions:
[U.sub.[omega]]([[omega].sup.0]) =
[C.sup.0.sub.[omega]],([[omega].sup.0]). As Grossman and Helpman (1994)
demonstrate, focusing attention on truthful equilibria does not restrict
players" strategy spaces.
The model is solved working backwards. One first focuses on stages
two and three to determine the government's choice of [omega] in
the presence of the influence-seeking SIG, given the amount of
assistance made available by the IMF. In stage one, the IMF's
choice of assistance is determined, given the government's policy
response to alternative assistance levels. Denote by [[omega].sup.0] the
government's choice of the index of policy distortions when the
amount of IMF assistance provided is T. The condition [U.sub.[omega]](0)
+ a[W.sub.[omega]](0,0) > 0 guarantees that [[omega].sup.0] is
positive and maximises the government's political support function
(3), implying that
(7) [G.sub.[omega]] ([omega], T) = 0 [vector]
[C.sub.[omega]]([omega]) + a[Y.sub.[omega]] ([omega], T) = 0
when evaluated at [[omega].sup.0]. Substituting the truthfulness
condition [U.sub.[omega]]([[omega].sup.0]) =
[C.sup.0.sub.[omega]]([[omega].sup.0]) in (7) yields
(8) [[U.sub.[omega]([[omega].sup.0]) =
-a[W.sub.[omega]]([[omega].sup.0], T)
Condition (8) yields the government's positive equilibrium
choice of policy distortions when the IMF provides an amount T of
unconditional assistance. Even though the general public's welfare
in the borrowing country is maximised at [omega] = 0, the first-order
condition (8) states that in political equilibrium the government
chooses a positive value of [omega]. This choice balances the marginal
political benefit to the government from raising distortions (and
receiving additional contributions from the lobby) against the marginal
political damage which additional distortions impose on public welfare.
We next turn to the question of how the IMF would choose the level
of its unconditional assistance. Even if IMF loans were provided without
a quid-pro-quo, efficiency would require the IMF to be familiar with the
authorities' reaction to different levels of assistance. Varying
the level of IMF assistance alters the debtor government's
incentives because it affects the marginal damage of distortions on the
general public's welfare in that country. If, as shown, higher
assistance raises the marginal damage of distortions, the
government's reaction function will be downward-sloping. The locus
of the government's choices of [[omega].sup.0] traced by varying
the amount of IMF assistance is curve RR in Figure 1. The government
reaction function is downward-sloping. Its slope depends on the extent
of the government's concern for the general public's welfare
and on how detrimental distortions are to the effectiveness of
assistance,
(9) d[[omega].sup.0]/dT = -a[[W.sub.[omega]T([[omega].sup.0], T)
/[[U.sup.[omega] [omega]] ([[omega].sup.0] +
a[[W.sub.[omega][omega]]([[omega].sup.0)] < 0
In terms of Figure 1, if the IMF takes into account the
government's reaction function, RR, it will choose an amount of
assistance [T.sub.0] that puts it on the highest attainable welfare
contour, namely [I.sub.0] at point B.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Conditional assistance
In practice, the IMF's offers of assistance are contingent on the incumbent government's pursuit of distortion-reducing economic
policies. The conditional assistance game is a common agency game, with
the IMF and the SIG being the two principals. The government's
choice of economic policies is a subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium of the
following two-stage game. In the first stage of the game, the IMF and
the SIG simultaneously present their truthful assistance and
contribution schedule, respectively, to the government. In the second
stage, the government selects the degree of policy distortions to
maximise its political support while taking as given each
principal's contribution schedule.
A key proposition in the literature on common agency games is that
truthful equilibria do not waste resources and are Pareto optimal for
the group of players who actively participate in the game (Dixit et al.,
1997, Proposition 3). Our model features three such players: the
borrowing government, the SIG, and the IME Since the IMF represents the
general public of creditor and debtor nations, it follows that the
equilibrium of the conditional assistance game is Pareto optimal for the
world as a whole. Efficiency requires maximising the joint welfare of
the government and the interest group and the government and the IMF. If
this were not true in equilibrium, the SIG (IMF) could offer the
government an alternative contribution (assistance) schedule that would
be mutually beneficial. In geometric terms, equilibrium requires
equality of marginal rates of substitution for the IMF and the
SIG-influenced government. The resulting 'international tangency
condition' between the indifference curves of the IMF and the
government is point C in Figure 1. This tangency point pins down the
government's choice of policy distortions and the IMF's
assistance level. At this tangency condition, all mutually advantageous
political trades between the IMF and the recipient government have been
exhausted, taking into account the reactions of the domestic SIG. (9)
The interior conditional assistance equilibrium choice of policy
distortions, [[omega].sup.1], can be characterised as follows.
Equilibrium requires that the joint welfare of any two active players be
maximised. Together with the truthfulness conditions, this yields the
following first-order necessary conditions, evaluated at the truthful
Nash equilibrium schedules [T.sup.1] and [C.sup.1] and [[omega].sup.1]
> 0.
(10) [C.sup.1.sub.[omega]] + a[W.sub.[omega]] + a([W.sub.T] -
b)[T.sup.1.sub.[omega]] = 0
(11) [U.sub.[omega]] - [C.sup.1.sub.[omega]] +
[C.sup.1.sub.[omega]] + a([W.sub.T] - b)[T.sup.1.sub.[omega]] = 0
(12) [gamma]([W.sub.[omega] + [W.sub.T][T.sup.1.sub.[omega]]) +
([W.sup.*.sub.[omega]] + [W.sup.*.sub.T][T.sup.1.sub.[omega]] +
[C.sup.1.sub.[omega]] + a([W.sub.[omega]] +
[W.sub.T][T.sup.1.sub.[omega]) - (1 - [gamma] - a)b[t.sup.1.sub.[omega]]
= 0
Substitution of (10) into (11) implies, just as in the absence of
IMF assistance, that [U.sub.[omega]]([[omega].sup.1]). The contribution
schedule equates the interest group's marginal benefit from
distortions to the group's marginal cost in terms of additional
contributions. Substituting (10) into (12) yields
(13) [T.sup.TE.sub.[omega]] = [gamma][W.sub.[omega]] +
[W.sup.*.sub.[omega]]/[gama][W.sub.T] + [W.sup.*.sub.T] + (1 - [gamma])b
This is a key equation that illustrates a number of properties of
truthful conditional assistance equilibria. First, as explained in
Grossman and Helpman (2001), the truthful assistance schedule, denoted
[T.sup.TE] in Equation (13), coincides with the downward-sloping part of
the government's indifference curve Go. Second, the equilibrium
depends on all the 'deep parameters' of the model, including
those describing the preferences of the borrowing government, SIG, and
IMF. Third, the conditional assistance schedule is downward-sloping--the
IMF rewards reductions in distortions with more assistance. Fourth, the
terms of the IMF's assistance reflect the impact of debtor-country
distortions on creditor-country economies, as reflected in the value of
[W.sup.*.sub.[omega]]. Fifth, the IMF's conditional assistance
schedule also takes into account the creditor countries' marginal
costs of providing assistance, as reflected in [W.sup.*.sub.T], and the
marginal benefits of assistance to recipients, or [W.sub.T]. Sixth, in
setting conditionality, the IMF also takes into account the borrowing
country's weight in its objective function. Finally, recall that
the IMF becomes an active participant--a second principal--in the
domestic political game. In other words, the efficient outcome of the
conditional assistance games is achieved at a price since the IMF is
injected more deeply in the affairs of the recipient country.
Loans versus grants
The effectiveness of IMF assistance also depends on its financial
terms, whether loans or grants, as reflected in the value of the
repayment parameter b. Raising the value of b amounts to a reduction in
the rate of subsidisation of IMF assistance. It can be shown that
conditional grants are the most effective form of assistance from the
point of view of the IMF (see Mayer and Mourmouras, 2002 for details).
Formally,
(14) dI/db = T([W.sub.T] + [W.sup.*.sub.T])/([W.sub.T] - b) < 0
if [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 1
This condition states that if the IMF cares about recipient
countries at least as much as it does about its creditors, then reducing
the rate of subsidisation raises policy distortions in the assisted
countries. In a world economy in which decisions are made only once, the
IMF's assistance is most effective if it is provided in the most
direct way possible (i.e., through conditional grants). Conditional
grants enable the IMF to exercise the most leverage on the policy
choices of borrowing governments. Note, however, that while these grants
do not have to be repaid, they are not 'free' Grants are
disbursed only if borrowing governments reduce their policy distortions,
which is costly for them in terms of lost political support.
In practice, the repeated nature of the interactions between the
IMF and debtor countries vastly complicates the answer to the loans
versus grants question. While more subsidised assistance purchases
greater reductions in policy distortions, improvements in policies may
not be durable if the underlying source of the distortions--the
influence-seeking activity of SIGs--is not addressed. In a multi-period
version of the model in which the IMF provides assistance for only a
limited time, conditionality will help for only as long as the IMF stays
financially engaged. To the extent that the interest group remains
active, policy distortions will increase following the withdrawal of IMF
assistance. Mayer and Mourmouras (2004) analyse policies to avoid
recidivism in such an environment.
IMPLICATIONS OF SPECIAL INTEREST POLITICS FOR THE IMF
The analysis of IMF conditionality presented in this paper is based
on a stylised political-economy model, suitably modified to incorporate
the IMF's role in the world economy. Based on this general
approach, this section draws some additional implications of the theory
of special interest politics for the design and application of IMF
conditionality.
At a general level, the theory points to the critical need to
consider the political feasibility of reforms when designing
IMF-supported programmes. While IMF conditionality counteracts
government incentives to pursue distortionary policies, the
recipients' domestic political economy places clear limits on the
IMF's leverage. The imperfections in economic and political systems
of countries making use of IMF resources impose clear limits on the
ability and willingness of governments to pursue first-best economic
policies. Such policies are preferred by IMF staff both on technical
grounds and because the IMF is a public-interest institution. However,
as illustrated by the model, insisting on first-best programmes in the
presence of organised vested interests could lead to problems in
implementation and be counterproductive. Taking into account the limits
on feasible reforms at the programme-design stage could result in more
realistic, better-designed, and better-implemented adjustment
programmes.
The theory makes a strong welfare case for using IMF conditionality
to counter policy distortions. We have portrayed a
'representative' IMF that uses conditionality to push for the
reduction of policy distortions and achieves a Pareto optimal allocation
for the world economy. The results of conditional lending are superior
relative to either the case of no IMF assistance or to the case where
assistance is unconditional. This basic efficiency result will survive
so long as the IMF's objective function includes all the citizens
of the world and the strategic interactions between the IMF, the
authorities and their domestic constituents do not waste resources.
On the other hand, the distribution of the gains from the financial
relationship between the IMF and borrowing governments depends on the
nature of the strategic game being played. In general, the outcome of
the conditional assistance game depends on the number and nature of
interest groups, who has the ability to make offers, and the bargaining
process. In the model of this paper, conditional assistance raises world
economic welfare, including of the general public in the recipient
country which benefits both from improved policies and from access to
IMF funds. On the other hand, the government's political support in
the conditional assistance equilibrium is unchanged relative to the no
assistance case. This is a special result, reflecting the
perfect-information nature of the model and the convention--that is
standard in the common agency literature--that principals have the power
to make take-it-or-leave it offers. Even though the IMF engages in
extensive information gathering and in frequent negotiations with
officials during the programme design and implementation stages, in
reality its information does not match that of country authorities. The
authorities' informational advantage presumably leads to a more
equitable distribution of the gains from the conditional assistance game
than portrayed in the formal model.
International conflicts of interest
IMF conditionality is most commonly justified by appealing to
international conflicts of interest. Such conflicts arise naturally when
sovereign governments' policy objectives clash. Beggar-thy-neighbor
policies, such as competitive exchange rate devaluations and resort to
tariffs and other trade protection in the 1930s, were key factors behind
the decision to create the IMF in 1944. International policy spillovers
continue to be an important justification for the IMF's existence.
This role for the IMF is reflected in our modeling approach, in which it
takes the international externalities of recipient countries'
policies into account when setting the terms of its conditionality. In
the model, international externalities are captured in a stylised
fashion, by inserting the debtor countries' aggregate distortion
index into the creditors' social welfare function. This may be
justified by appealing to the deadweight losses that countries suffer
when their trading partners adopt inefficient trade policies, such as
tariffs, quotas, or undervalued exchange rates. (10) The political
trades that creditor countries are willing to engage in (through the
IMF) reflect the extent to which debtor countries' policies affect
their welfare: an increase in the absolute value of
[W.sub.[omega].sup.*] makes the IMF's truthful assistance schedule
steeper. In other words, the IMF will willingly provide more assistance
for a given reduction in distortions to those debtor countries whose
policies have greater impact on creditor-country welfare (are
systemically more important). This finding is also consistent with
Stone's (2002) conclusion that the length of punishment for
non-compliance with conditionality is shorter in systemically important
countries.
While conditional assistance is effective in addressing policy
distortions originating in debtor countries, it is not clear how much
leverage the IMF has in addressing policy failures in creditor
countries. To address the international externalities caused by
industrial country policies, including agricultural subsidies, trade
barriers, or inappropriate exchange rate policies, requires endowing
international institutions such as the IMF with instruments that go
beyond that of conditional lending. Thinking about these issues is
clearly very important but is beyond the scope of the present paper.
Domestic conflicts of interest
Conditionality will not be implemented unless key groups and
stakeholders in recipient countries support or acquiesce to the policy
programmes being supported by the IMF. In an ideal setting in which
losers could be identified and compensated by those gaining from the
enactment of welfare-enhancing reforms, all such reforms would be
unanimously approved. However, as already discussed, domestic political
and economic systems are imperfect and elected governments have
considerable latitude to pursue personal and electoral objectives. These
imperfections also give organised interest groups the opportunity to
exert disproportionate influence on government decision-making. Interest
groups are able to gain access to decision-makers and provide them with
specialised information about the impact of different policy choices and
the strength of support for a particular policy. As illustrated by the
model, political contributions may also buy interest groups more
favourable policies, such as trade protection, subsidies, or tax
advantages.
The presence of domestic groups opposing reforms provides a
rationale for IMF conditionality even in countries that are so small
that their choices result in negligible cross-border externalities. Yet,
because the IMF's mission is commonly defined as the amelioration of the international spillovers discussed in the previous section, the
insertion of IMF conditionality in domestic conflicts of interest is
controversial. Many observers would like to return to the simpler world
in which the IMF only lends to countries whose policies pose a threat to
the regional or global economy. But, as stated in Article I of its
charter, the IMF's purpose is to give members the 'opportunity
to correct maladjustments in their balance of payments without resorting
to measures destructive of national or international prosperity.'
Countries can use IMF assistance to achieve a more orderly adjustment of
internal disequilibria, and reduce structural rigidities and ineffective
institutions--such as those associated with central planning for
example.
The IMF can assist countries in overcoming the pernicious influence
of domestic vested interests by helping them to amplify the voice of
governmental or non-governmental civil society organisations. As more
interest groups organise in borrowing countries, including those
representing the broad public interest, the proportion of the population
represented in the political trades rises. In the limit, if all the
citizens are represented in some domestic interest group, the political
equilibrium is Pareto optimal for the country. Since the identity of the
under-represented--including the poor, disenfranchised, or marginalised
groups--is likely to vary from country to country, and within a given
country at different times, considerable field work may be required to
ensure that IMF processes help give such groups voice, including in
poverty and social impact analysis. The participatory features of the
Poverty Reduction Strategy Process are a step in the direction of giving
groups voice and could be emulated in other IMF-supported programmes.
Inefficient policy instruments
The tension between the IMF and member governments extends to the
choice of policy instruments. As the special interest politics approach
shows, governments operating under the influence of interest groups
prefer to use tariffs, export taxes, subsidies and other distortionary
policy instruments because these tools better facilitate political
trades. On the other hand, the IMF and other IFIs promoting broad
national and international goals are keen to see distortionary policy
instruments eliminated.
Key to understanding the revealed preference of interest groups for
inefficient means of taxation and redistribution is a classical
proposition from public finance. This proposition, which is due to
Diamond and Mirrlees (1971), asserts that the government can achieve
socially optimal redistribution by taxing final goods only, even in
second-best situations in which lumpsum taxes and transfers are not
available. Taxes or subsidies on intermediate inputs distort production
decisions and are inefficient. When governments are influenced by
special interests, however, the Diamond-Mirrlees result does not hold.
Groups that overcome the free-rider problems and fixed costs involved in
organising will expend resources to lobby for inefficient policy
instruments. The more inefficient the tools of redistributive politics,
the better is the bargaining position of organised interest groups
vis-a-vis policymakers (Grossman and Helpman, 2001, p. 279).
Conditionality as a commitment technology
One way in which IMF conditionality helps governments eschew inefficient policy instruments is by providing an external
'commitment technology.' As is well known, governments that
are unable to commit to sound policies in the future will be tempted to
adopt inferior, time-inconsistent policies. One-time, surprise taxes on
income from capital already in place, including unanticipated inflation,
involve a zero excess burden ex post and are efficient from an optimal
tax point of view. Anticipating such behaviour, the private sector will
reduce its productive capital investment and hold less domestic money
(dollarisation) than in the 'commitment' equilibrium. While
fully representative governments face incentives to resort to capital
levies, the incentive to engage in such tactics increases as the degree
to which a government cares about its citizens declines.
By making the IMF's assistance contingent on the adoption and
maintenance of non-distorting fiscal and monetary policies, the IMF
helps member countries come closer to first-best policies. Government
commitments to the IMF work synergistically with those to other
international organisations (such as the World Bank and the World Trade
Organization). The aggregate political influence of these external
actors assists governments in their efforts to steer clear of
inefficient taxation and redistribution. Decisions to reduce policy
distortions will be consistent with political equilibrium only if the
government's valuation of IFI membership to outweigh short-run
political costs. In normal times, this will depend on the relative
political influence of IFIs and domestic SIGS, which depends on the
SIGs' gains (and the IFIs' losses) from inefficient policies,
the government's time discount factor and remaining tenure in
office, and the other factors illustrated by the model. In crisis times,
the political cost-benefit calculus may change quite dramatically. When
the country is in the midst of a dire external crisis, the IFIs'
bargaining power increases and they can confront governments with
take-it-or-leave-it proposals that proscribe inefficient policy
instruments. On the other hand, if domestic conditions are not dire,
then more accommodative strategies may be needed.
Veto players
In practice, government policymaking involves the interaction of
multiple actors in the executive, legislative and judiciary branches of
government. Some of these actors have the power to block reform measures
agreed between the IMF and the executive. The theory of 'veto
players' (Tsebelis, 2001) analyses policy formation as equilibrium
interactions among veto players. The number, identities, and political
influence of these veto players depends on each country's
constitutional and political organisation. In presidential systems, the
legislature (one or two chambers) and the chief executive are veto
players. The congress has agenda-setting powers since it can make
take-it-or-leave-it offers to the president. The president can accept
these offers or veto legislative bills, in which case a qualified
majority in congress can over-rule the veto. In parliamentary systems,
the chief executive is selected by parliament. Veto players are
parliamentary parties and their coalitions since their agreement is
needed for the implementation of policy changes. In other systems, the
military may be a de facto veto player. And, in any political system,
the public can become an effective veto player through mass street
protests.
Our application of the theory of special interest politics to IMF
conditionality abstracts from within-government heterogeneity. For the
sake of tractability, the model of the political economy of IMF
conditionality presents a unitary view of government in borrowing
countries. In reality, conflicts of interest between the executive and
legislative branches are a key obstacle to the implementation of reform
measures agreed between the IMF and member governments and backed
financially by the IMF. Recent models (Drazen, 2002) analyse the
consequences for IMF conditionality of the presence of veto players. To
the extent that their policy preferences differ from those of the
executive, veto players use their leverage to ensure that adopted
policies are closer to their ideal positions. Like lobbying models, veto
player models of conditionality involve interactions of multiple
players. In Drazen's model, an agreement signed by the IMF and the
executive must be approved or implemented with the cooperation of the
legislature. Conditionality helps improve policies relative to
unconditional assistance, much as in models based on the theory of
special interest politics and common agency.
Conditionality and cooperation
Conditionality can be useful in promoting cooperative arrangements
('trust') in group politico-economic interactions in member
countries subject to domestic divisions. According to game theory's
folk theorem, cooperation can evolve spontaneously as the outcome of
non-cooperative interaction among selfish agents in a repeated
interaction. (11) In some countries, domestic divisions are so severe
that such equilibria do not arise in the absence of external influence.
This might be the case when the government is under the control of a
single ethnic, religious or regional group that looks after its own
narrow interests at the expense of the general welfare. In countries
with divided polities, each group's incentives to cooperate in the
one-shot game are therefore limited. The group in power is a
'bandit' in Olson's sense, pilfering society's
resources while it can. If two such groups alternate in power in an
infinitely repeated interaction, incentives for mutual cooperation arise
that do not exist in the one-shot game (Dixit, 2001). Such
self-enforcing inter-group cooperation is more likely the greater is
each group's patience (i.e., the lower is each group's
subjective rate of time preference) and the greater is each group's
risk aversion. Cooperation is also more likely the greater is the
likelihood of switch in power by either party. While some persistence in
power is consistent with the emergence of spontaneous cooperation, such
an outcome is made impossible if one or both groups have a highly
persistent lock on power.
In countries with divided polities, IMF conditional assistance can
be designed to strengthen the domestic warring groups' incentives
to cooperate. As the IMF is involved in repeated interaction with member
countries" governments, the conditions for meeting the folk theorem
could be applicable to this interaction. These conditions are well
known. The IMF's and member governments' time discount factors
must be sufficiently high, so that the 'shadow of the future'
is large enough to make cooperative strategies worthwhile. It is an open
question what types of strategies are appropriate for the IMF to follow
to induce cooperation. Since the IMF and borrowing countries engage in
repeated interactions, it may be optimal for the IMF to use a
combination of 'stick and carrot' incentives, as opposed to
relying on trigger strategies alone in which aid is cutoff permanently
following noncompliance. In countries with poor track records of policy
implementation and weak ownership, it may be appropriate for IMF loans
to be made available on the basis of result-based conditionality.
Disbursing loans after a country has met certain verifiable conditions
and not on the basis of promises to deliver policy changes in the future
may discipline both the IMF and borrowing countries.
The IMF and special interests in practice
As emphasised by the public choice literature, IMF conditionality
may be influenced by political pressures from shareholders that use the
IMF to obtain advantages in their bilateral economic and financial
relationships with debtor countries. Some critics of the IMF (Stiglitz,
2002), have put forward an extreme version of this 'capture
theory" of the IMF. They claim that the institution does not
represent the interests of developing countries, having been captured by
the financial lobbies of creditor countries. While Stiglitz's
theory is the polar opposite of the public-interest view of the IMF
presented in this paper, it can be evaluated using the same tools of the
theory of special interest politics. Altering the IMF's objective
function in the way suggested by Stiglitz will reduce the effectiveness
of conditionality, since the IMF ceases to be representative of the poor
and disenfranchised in developing countries.
But while the IMF may not be fully representative, Stiglitz's
theory flies in the face of the IMF's constitution, which focuses
on the global public interest. In addition, as already indicated,
changes in the IMF's operations in low-income countries in the late
1990 s have increased the voice and participation of poor in
decision-making, including in the design and implementation of national
poverty reduction strategies being supported by the IFIs. The IMF
counters the influence of special interests regardless of their country
of origin. In a number of occasions, the IMF has advocated the need for
industrial countries to improve market access for developing countries.
For example, in an open letter published in May 2002, the heads of the
World Trade Organization, World Bank and IMF called on the industrial
countries to follow through on their commitment from the Doha Round of
Trade negotiations to help developing countries better engage in the
global trading system. The IMF has also refocused its surveillance to
provide more detailed and critical analysis of trade policies in
industrial and large developing countries. The IMF has repeatedly called
for wealthy countries to fulfil their commitment to provide Overseas
Development Assistance equivalent to the United Nations target of 0.7
percent of GNP. Finally, the IMF also speaks up against governance and
corruption problems in countries receiving IFI resources.
A comprehensive analysis of the IMF's objectives and
incentives is, however, beyond the scope of the paper. The extent to
which the IMF can resist political pressures depends on its
institutional independence and the degree to which it can apply its
rules-based approach to lending. Suffice it to say that while the
IMF's choices cannot deviate too much from those of its member
governments (Martin, 2000), the institution does enjoy a reasonable
degree of discretion that helps insulate it from outside pressures. The
IMF's operational independence derives from the powers delegated to
it by its membership and also by informational advantages vis-a-vis
individual members (the IMF typically has more troops on the ground in
debtor countries than individual member countries).
CONCLUDING REMARKS
Left on their own, some countries' economic and political
systems would generate highly inefficient and distorted economic policy
choices. IMF loans and their associated conditionality assist these
countries in their efforts to reduce these distortions. This paper
illustrated the incentive effects of IMF conditionality with the help of
a perfect-information model of the world economy. In this model, in
which the IMF is a benevolent lobby that maximises world welfare,
conditional loans help governments counter the political influence of
interest groups that lobby for policies that are harmful to national and
international welfare. Conditionality improves world resource allocation relative to either unconditional assistance or no assistance while
economising on the amount of assistance--conditional assistance achieves
a greater 'bang' relative to unconditional assistance.
However, while IMF conditionality can help reconcile the narrowly
focused objectives of national authorities with the IMF's broader
internationalist objectives, its application must be tailored to the
domestic political realities in borrowing countries. The need for
conditionality was also affirmed in the IMF's conditionality
review. The review validated the need for country-tailored programmes
and a critical mass of ownership in order to ensure reasonably good
programme implementation.
As already discussed, while the theoretical case for conditionality
is strong, the empirical evidence regarding its application is more
varied. Policy programmes agreed between the IMF and governments of
member countries and backed by IMF financial assistance are often
disrupted by economic and political shocks and by policy disagreements.
In practice, such 'on-off' application of conditionality
compromises its effectiveness. Understanding the reasons behind the
relatively poor record of implementation of IMF-supported programmes and
finding ways to make programs more robust to economic and political
shocks is a priority of future research. The key to reconciling the
empirical evidence with the rosy analytical predictions lies in relaxing
some of the strong assumptions made in this paper. Chief among these are
the incentive problems which altruistic lenders, including the IMF,
face. Abstracting from issues of time inconsistency (the
Samaritan's dilemma) helps ensure tractability but may paint an
excessively favourable picture of the conditions in which the IMF is
operating--perfect information, no credibility problems, etc. Working
out the implications of relaxing these assumptions will also need to be
a priority in future work.
(1) The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and
should not be attributed to the International Monetary Fund.
(2) While technically IMF financing is a currency exchange and not
a formal loan, this distinction is not important in practice. The IMF is
treated as a senior creditor and almost always gets repaid. Instances of
protracted arrears to the IMF are rare and involve a small number of
countries with intractable economic, political, and social problems. On
the other hand, the problem of 'evergreening of IMF loans,' or
defensive lending, is occasionally an important issue in decisions to
renew IMF financing. The present paper focuses on the incentive issues
facing debtor countries a and abstracts from incentive problems that the
IMF may face.
(3) Mayer and Mourmouras (2002) develop a lobbying model of the
IMF. Drazen (2002) presents a veto player model.
(4) Common agency was developed by Bernheim and Winston (1986) and
applied to the positive analysis of trade policy and public finance by
Grossman and Helpman (1994, 2001) and Dixit et al. (1997).
(5) Such conflicts would persist even if debtor governments were
not under the influence of special interests but rather pursued
legitimate national goals (such as redistribution) that created
international policy externalities.
(6) On rent seeking and vested interests see Krueger (1974),
Havrylyshyn and Odling-Smee (2000), Helhnan and Kaufmann (2001), and IMF
(2001c).
(7) The Working Paper version of this paper reviews in greater
detail the recent empirical literature on the implementation and
effectiveness of IMF-supported programmes. See also Ul Haque and Khan
(1998).
(8) The theory of special interest politics can be used to analyse
the impact of conditional IMF financial assistance on economic policy
choices in debtor countries under alternative assumptions about the
IMF's objective function. See the section on Implication of special
interest politics for the IMF.
(9) By contrast, the unconditional assistance equilibrium (point B
in Figure 1) is not Pareto optimal. Starting from the point of tangency
between the IMF's indifference curve and the government's
reaction function, there exist unexploited mutual welfare gains for the
IMF and the recipient government.
(10) Domestic distortions, such as the production subsidy
considered in the political economy of IMF conditionality, may have
international impacts as well.
(11) See Rasmusen (2001, pp. 112-114) for a statement, Axelrod
(1984) provides a thorough discussion of the evolution of cooperative
arrangements in environments in which self-interested players must
interact without the presence of a central authority.
REFERENCES
Axelrod, R. 1984: The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books: New
York.
Bernheim, BD and Winston, MD. 1986: Menu auctions, resource
allocation, and economic influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 101(1): 1-32 (February).
Bird, G. 2002: Conditionality and ownership: how to improve the
implementation of IMF programmes Working paper, University of Surrey:
UK.
Boughton, JM and Mourmouras, A. 2002: Is policy ownership an
operational concept? IMF Working Paper 02/72.
Burnside, C and Dollar, D. 1998: Aid, the incentive regime, and
poverty reduction. Working paper, Macroeconomics and Growth Group, World
Bank.
Burnside, C and Dollar, D. 2000: Aid, policies, and growth.
American Economic Review 90(4): 847-868.
Diamond, P and Mirrlees, J. 1971: Optimal taxation and public
production: I. production efficiency, and II. tax rules. American
Economic Review 61:8-27 and 261-278.
Dixit, A. 2001: Some lessons from transaction-cost politics for
less-developed countries. Olson Memorial Lecture delivered at the
University of Maryland (October). Available at:
http://www/bsos.umd.edu/umccc/olson_memorial_lecture_series_schedule.htm.
Dixit, A. 2000: IMF programs as incentive mechanisms. Mimeo,
International Monetary Fund (June).
Dixit, A, Grossman, GM and Helpman, E. 1997: Common agency and
coordination: general theory and application to government policy
making. Journal of Political Economy 105(4): 752-769 (August).
Dollar, D and Svensson, J. 2000: What explains the success or
failure of structural adjustment programmes? Economic Journal 110
(October): 894-917.
Drazen, A. 2002: Conditionality and ownership in IMF lending: a
political economy approach. IMF Staff Papers 49(Special Issue): 36-67.
Grossman, GM and Helpman, E. 1994: Protection for sale. American
Economic Review 84(September): 833-850.
Grossman, GM and Helpman, E. 2001: Special interest politics. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.
Havrylyshyn, O and Odling-Smee, J. 2000: Political economy of
stalled reforms. Finance and Development 37(3). Available at
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2000/09/havrylys.htm.
Hellman, J. and Kaufmann, D. 2001: Confronting the challenge of
state capture in transition economies. Finance and Development 38(3):
(September). Available at
bttp://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/09/hellman.htm.
International Monetary Fund. 2001a: Conditionality in IMF-supported
programs--policy issues (February 16). Available at
http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/eond/2001/eng/policy/index.htm.
International Monetary Fund. 2001b: Structural conditionality in
IMF supported programs (February 16). Available at
http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/cond/2001/eng/struct/index.htm.
International Monetary Fund. 2001c: Strengthening country ownership
of fund-supported programs (December 5). Available at
http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/cond/2001/eng/strength/120501.htm.
International Monetary Fund. 2002: Guidelines on conditionality
(September 25). Available at
http://www.imf.org/External/np/pdr/cond/2002/eng/guid/092302.pdf.
Ivanova, A, Mourmouras, A, Mayer, W and Anayiotos, G. 2003: What
determines the implementation of IMF-supported programs?. IMF Working
paper 03/08 (January).
Khan, MS. and Sbarma, S. 2003: IMF conditionality and country
ownership of adjustment programs. World Bank Research Observer
18:249-273 (Fall).
Krueger, A. 1974: The political economy of a rent-seeking society.
American Economic Review 64(3): 291-303.
Martin, LL. 2000: Agency and delegation in IMF conditionality.
Manuscript, Department of Government, Harvard University (October).
Mayer, W. and Mourmouras, A. 2002: Vested interests in a positive
theory of IFI conditionality. IMF Working paper 02/73.
Mayer, W. and Mourmouras, A. 2004: The political economy of foreign
assistance: grants versus loan rollovers. IMF Working paper 04/4.
Nsouli,, S, Atoian, R and Mourmouras, A. 2004: Institutions,
program implementation, and macroeconomic performance. IMF Working paper
(forthcoming).
Olson, M. 1965: The logic of collective action. Harvard University
Press: Cambridge, MA.
Rasmusen, E. 2001: Games and information: an introduction to game
theory. Blackwell Oxford.
Stiglitz, J. 2002: Globalization and its Discontents. Norton: New
York.
Stone, RW. 2002: Lending credibility: the international monetary
fund and the post communist transition. Princeton University Press:
Princeton.
Tsebelis, G. 2001: Veto players: how political institutions work.
Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Foundation: Princeton, NJ.
Ul Haque, N and Khan, MS. 1998: Do IMF-supported programs work, a
survey of the cross-country empirical evidence. IMF Working paper 98/16
(December).
Willett, T. 2003: IMF conditionality and the new political economy
of ownership. Working Paper, Claremont Graduate School.
WOLFGANG MAYER (1) & ALEX MOURMOURAS (2)
(1) University of Cincinnati, Cincinnati, OH 45221, USA. E-mail:
amourmouras@imf.org;
(2) International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC 20431, USA.