Recent developments in the short-term employment in Kazakhstani firms.
Kalyuzhnova, Yelena ; Vagliasindi, Maria ; Casson, Mark 等
INTRODUCTION
Up to the first half of the 1990s, it was widely claimed that the
privatisation of enterprises in a transitional economy should improve
productivity and enhance national economic performance. This claim
reflected ah underlying assumption that state-owned enterprises are
inefficient. This inefficiency is usually attributed to the distortion
of management incentives under state ownership. The economic literature
comparing public and private ownership to assess the desirability of
(alternative types of) privatisation suggests that public ownership can
be preferred to private ownership only under a restricted set of
conditions. (1) Particularly for transition economies, this might not be
the case, since budget and regulation can be arbitrarily manipulated,
corruption is widespread and (capital and financial) markets work
imperfectly with the risk of tunnelling. Moreover, transition economies
present other challenges, as privatisation methods have not followed a
unitary path but varied extensively, so that an additional issue to
address is which type of privatised firms will behave in the most
similar way to private firms. The role that the State and policy makers
can play in designing appropriate privatisation methods can be crucial
and depends on the specific institutional settings. Privatisation
methods and design playa primary role in a successful privatisation
policy, because, determining private ownership structures, crucially
affect future corporate governance (and financial structure) and the
effective role played by shareholders.
There is strong empirical evidence in support of privatisation for
the more advanced countries of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE). For the
Former Soviet Union (FSU) countries, the impact of ownership changes in
terms of restructuring and improved enterprise performance appears less
important. The 1999 Journal of Comparative Economics' symposium
showed complex patterns resulting from privatisation in terms of
ownership and corporate governance across FSU countries. These papers
attribute the slow progress to weaknesses in the implementation of
effective privatisation policies and weaknesses and distortions in the
broader economic environment.
A recent survey by Djankov and Murrell (2002) on enterprise
restructuring highlighted that 'the largest positive effect on
enterprise restructuring, both in Eastern Europe and in the CIS' is
due to privatisation to outsiders and hard budget constraints.
Critics of rapid privatisation advocate a more gradual approach and
consider other factors, including competition, more important than
privatisation. (2) They argue that privatisation should be introduced
more slowly to allow the growing force of competition to discipline
state-owned enterprises. The recent theoretical work by Alexeev and
Kaganovich (2001) analyses the effect of the speed of privatisation for
transition economies in the presence of a subsistence constraint (due to
the presence of soft budget constraints), building upon the influential
work by Aghion and Blanchard (1998). (3)
This paper examines one particular example of the distortion of
incentives, namely the incentive for managers of state-owned enterprises
to maintain excessive levels of employment in their factories and
offices. (4) It draws upon a unique database constructed from quarterly
surveys of leading enterprises in Kazakhstan that allow us to provide
fresh new evidence drawing from a period marked by a great volatility,
including the aftermath of the Russian financial crisis. The database
includes both private and state-owned enterprises, and therefore
facilitates a direct comparison between them. It finds only limited
evidence for the view that state-owned enterprises maintain excessive
levels of employment. It therefore casts doubt on the view that private
enterprises in a transition economy behave very differently from
state-owned enterprises. It suggests that ownership matters only for
export-oriented enterprises; that is, those enterprises that were more
exposed to competitive pressures, including the vulnerability to the
1998 Russian financial crisis, (5)
Our data come from a survey of 701 Kazakhstani firms over a nearly
2-year period from the second quarter of 1998 through the fourth quarter
of 1999. It allows us to examine employment changes for periods prior
to, during and following the Russian financial crisis of August 1998.
The survey reports the major constraints on productivity growth and
market penetration facing enterprises in transition. Three-level
categorical data (increased, decreased of stayed the same) for most of
the survey's variables have been used by the Kazakh Economic
Research Institute.
A number of studies have investigated the relationship between
ownership structure and enterprise performance. A major difficulty with
these studies is the inability to obtain uninterrupted official data
from the industry census. Nevertheless, scholars are avoiding this
problem applying a survey methodology first employed in Central European
transition economies (Pinto et al., 1993; Carlin et al., 1995) and later
extended to CIS countries (Djankov, 1999a, b). (6)
Djankov and Nenova (2000) analyse financial statements from the
industrial census in Kazakhstan, including 6,000 enterprises from 1996
to 1999. This study includes virtually all enterprises registered in the
country with more than 10 employees. Despite the substantially larger
number of observations than in our study, there are well-documented
problems with the quality and reliability of accounting information (for
tax reasons) across CIS countries. Moreover, our survey, with its
broader set of variables, allows us to assess the perception of the
investment climate and main obstacles constraining growth and
development of enterprise as well as other questions.
The structure of the paper is as follows. The following section
describes the key theoretical propositions that will be tested by our
empirical analysis. The next section describes the main macroeconomic evolution in Kazakhstan. The subsequent sections describe the data,
comparing it with other surveys, while the penultimate section presents
the regression results. The concluding section proposes extensions for
future research and summarises the key policy implications of our work.
THE THEORETICAL PROPOSITIONS
The starting point for our analysis is the theoretical proposition
that demand for labour, as is demand for capital (Jorgenson, 1996), is
derived from the demand for output. Since our data are quarterly, it is
appropriate to focus on short-run employment functions rather than the
long run.
In a world of perfect certainty, and in the absence of adjustment
costs, profit maximisation implies that short-run labour demand will
adjust fully and immediately to any change in the demand for output.
Such a pattern of response would, however, generate considerable
volatility in the demand for labour--much more than is observed in
practice. To avoid this problem, employment functions are normally
derived by postulating that firms economise on adjustment costs by only
partially adjusting to changes in output in any given quarter (Fair,
1969).
When the product market is perfectly competitive, both output and
employment respond endogenously to changes in price. Employment changes
in the same direction as output, and both change in the same direction
as price. The causal relationship runs directly from price to
employment.
When the product market is in disequilibrium--that is, price is not
at its market-clearing level--a firm may be rationed by the amount of
output that it can sell at the prevailing price (Barro and Grossman,
1976). In this case, employment depends directly on output, and output
is independent of price. This is the case of excess supply in an
industry. (7) The disequilibrium approach is particularly useful for
short-run analysis, particularly in transitional economies where market
institutions are not yet fully developed, and where competitive
equilibrium will therefore prevail only in the very long run.
Our database contains information on both changes in output and
changes in price. It is therefore useful to develop an approach that
permits both output and price to act as exogenous variables. Testing
hypotheses derived using this approach enables us to identify the
relative strength of price and output effects. Firms facing adjustment
costs are more likely to respond to permanent price changes than to
transitory price changes because there is less risk that they will have
to reverse their changes later on. A rational firm in short-run
disequilibrium will therefore adjust more fully to a fall in output when
it is accompanied by a fall in price, and conversely, it will adjust
more fully to an increase in output when it is accompanied by a rise in
price. While this argument implies that changes in price and changes in
output impact interactively on changes in employment, their effects may
be additive to a first-order approximation. Hence, we postulate that the
probability of change in employment depends additively on changes in
employment and changes in price.
Capacity utilisation is another indicator of whether a change in
demand is considered to be permanent of transitory. A firm facing a
transitory reduction in demand is quite likely to maintain production by
building up inventory in anticipation of recovery, and thereby maintain
capacity utilisation at a high level. The firm will not, therefore,
reduce employment in response to a fall in demand, because it wishes to
maintain production levels. On the other hand, a firm that faces a
permanent reduction in demand is likely to run-down inventory too,
leading to a low level of capacity utilisation, and encouraging a
reduction in employment. Thus, although capacity utilisation is, in one
sense, an endogenous variable, it may also serve as an indicator of the
nature of ah exogenous shock to demand. Lower capacity utilisation is an
indicator that the fall in demand is considered permanent, and increases
the probability that the firm will reduce employment. Conversely, higher
capacity utilisation is an indicator that the rail in demand is
considered transitory. This is associated with a lower probability that
the firm will reduce employment.
This approach can be generalised to consider whether other
variables are indicators of a transitory or permanent change. For
example, changes in export demand could be regarded by a firm as a
stronger signal of long-term change than a change in purely domestic
demand. A change in export demand may reflect shifting preferences and
emerging trends in global competition, while a change in domestic demand
could simply reflect macroeconomic volatility in the domestic economy.
Another reason why export changes may represent strong demand signals is
that export markets are often more competitive than domestic ones. Thus,
a strengthening of a firm's position in export markets may indicate
that it has improved its long-run competitive position--perhaps through
improvements in product design and quality. This suggests that
export-oriented firms will adjust employment more strongly to changes in
demand than will purely domestic-oriented firms.
The central concern of this paper is the influence of firm
ownership on employment decisions. The ownership variable distinguishes
between private and state-owned enterprises. Our principal hypothesis is
that state-owned firms pursue security maximisation, while private firms
pursue profit maximisation. Managers of state-owned firms have less
incentive to maximise profit because they are not subject to monitoring
and supervision by private shareholders, and so face softer budget
constraints. They are more likely to pursue security maximisation
because they are ideologically committed to this policy, or believe that
their reputation in the local community depends upon pursuing it.
The objective of a security maximising firm is to guarantee
employment to existing workers. This guarantee is subject to a financial
constraint set by the extent of the losses that the government is
willing to subsidise. Since a security-maximising firm is reluctant to
reduce employment, its response to reductions in output and price is
smaller than that of a profit-maximising firm.
A rational manager of a security-maximising firm will anticipate
that if workers are taken on in response to an increase in output of
price, then they may have to be laid off again later, if the budget
constraint becomes binding. A security-maximising firm will therefore
also adjust less than a profit-maximising firm to an increase in output
of price. A profit-maximising firm has no such scruples--the sole
constraint on its employment adjustment is the need to economise on
adjustment cost, as described above.
The testable propositions are summarised below.
Proposition 1. State-owned firms are less likely than private firms
to vary employment. The difference is greater for export-oriented firms.
This reflects the view that security-oriented firms predominate in
the state sector and that short-run profit maximisers predominate in the
private sector. The rationale is that the budget constraints of
state-owned firms are softer, and their managers feel more obligations
to maintain employment. Differences between state-owned and private
firms are likely to be greater among firms that are exporting. Export
markets are often much more competitive than domestic markets, and so a
strengthening of a firm's position in export markets may indicate
that it has improved its long-run competitive position. Private firms
are better able to innovate, and are therefore likely to do especially
well in export markets. Thus, export orientation may increase the
probability that the firm will hire additional labour in response to an
increase in output and reduce the probability that it will lay off
labour in response to a fall in output. Thus, the long-term prospects of
a firm depend not only upon whether it is private or state-owned, but
also upon whether it is export oriented or not.
Proposition 2. Firms are likely to increase employment as capacity
utilisation rises.
When there are costs of adjusting the labour force, and the capital
stock is fixed, the rate of utilisation of the labour force will vary in
the same direction as the rate of utilisation of the capital stock. When
capacity utilisation is high, the stock of labour is likely to be below
its equilibrium level, and so employment is likely to increase.
Conversely, when capacity utilisation is low, the stock of labour is
likely to be above its equilibrium level, and so employment is likely to
fall.
Proposition 3. Firms facing problems with customer's bad debts
(arrears/non-payments) are more likely to reduce employment. Private
firms are more likely then state-owned firms to reduce employment on
this account.
Firms with bad debts may lack funds to employ labour. Unless
workers are willing to accept wage payments in arrears, firms will have
to reduce employment. Private firms are more likely to be affected
because they face tighter budget constraints and may well have lower
liquidity. Also, workers in private firms may be less likely to accept
wage payments in arrears because they are more concerned that the firm
will go bankrupt before their wages are finally paid.
Proposition 4: Firms facing instability of tax policy are more
likely to reduce employment than other firms. Private sector firms are
more likely to reduce employment than state-owned firms.
An unexpected increase in tax instability may cause firms to reduce
employment through liquidity effects. An unexpected reduction in tax
instability will allow firms to increase employment, if they were
liquidity-constrained before. Instability of tax policy will also make
management more difficult and thereby inhibit the performance of firms.
The private sector is particularly vulnerable in this respect because
budget constraints are hard: tax instability increases the variability
of profit without any compensating increase in the average rate of
profit. This suggests that reductions in employment due to disincentive effects are likely to be common. (8)
Proposition 5. Small firms are more likely than large firms to
reduce employment, and are also more likely to increase employment.
This is because small firms are not dominant employers in the local
economy and their managers, therefore, feel less social obligation to
maintain employment. Although small firms may show loyalty to their
employees, this factor is not so strong as the sense of obligation to
the community affecting large firms. Small firms are more likely to
increase employment because they are less inclined to hoard labour, and
are therefore more likely to be under pressure when demand increases.
Overall, therefore, small firms are more likely than large firms to be
profit maximisers, and less likely to be security-oriented instead.
Finally, employment adjustments depend upon industry-specific,
region-specific and time-specific factors other than those listed above.
These effects can be captured by relevant sets of dummy variables. In
introducing regional dummy variables, we took into account that in 1998
Russia still remained one of Kazakhstan's main trading partners
(Kalyuzhnova, 2002). Our prediction is that Kazakhstani regions close to
either the Russian border or the Uzbek border were more affected by the
Russian financial crisis and also by the 200% import tariffs that were
established by the Kazakhstani government at that time in order to
prevent cheap imports from the neighbouring countries. A key measure of
vulnerability could be considered here--the Kazakhstani share of total
trade with Russia and Uzbekistan. Quarterly dummies help to show the
changes in firms' behaviour stemming from exogenous shocks (the
crisis itself) and endogenous macroeconomic changes. The industry dummy
variables capture the impact of sectoral changes--in particular,
firms' reactions to new competitive threats and to changing
patterns of trade.
The implications of these propositions are summarised in Table 1.
The explanatory variables are listed in the left-hand column. The next
two columns indicate the predicted signs of the impacts on employment of
changes in these variables. The first column indicates the predicted
sign so far as employment decrease is concerned, and the second column
indicates the predicted sign for employment increase. A double plus
indicates a strong positive effect, a single plus indicates a weak
positive effect, a single minus indicates a weak negative effect, and a
double minus indicates a strong negative effect. Thus, the first line of
the table indicates that ah increase in output has a strong effect in
both encouraging increases in employment and discouraging decreases in
employment. By contrast, instability of tax policy, shown lower down the
table, has a weak tendency to increase employment and a weak tendency to
reduce employment at the same time.
Some of these variables, such as output change and capacity
utilisation, can be measured directly from the data in the survey.
Others, however, represent interactions between different measurements
taken in the survey. In particular, ownership affects the way in which a
number of factors impact upon the firm. Thus ownership effects interact
with export-orientation. (9) State-owned non-exporters are taken as the
control group, and the interaction effects of ownership and exporting
are then accounted for using a set of dummy variables.
MACROECONOMIC OVERVIEW
The period being analysed (second quarter of 1998 to the last
quarter of 1999) was a complex one. Several factors influenced the
development of the macroeconomic situation until the end of 1998: the
continuation of low oil prices, the non-payment crisis, the South Asian
financial crisis, the deepening Russian financial crisis, unfavourable
weather conditions and negative trends in world market prices for raw
materials.
The metallurgical complex provided growth of production due to the
growth in the second quarter 1998 in volume ore extraction and
production of non-ferrous metals. In ferrous metallurgy, the tendency of
decline took place due to the decrease in the extraction volume of
iron-ore as well as the reduced demand in the external market for rolled
iron. The exception is Kazakhchrom, where production of ferrous-chrome
increased. In the first 6 months of 1998, there has been a sharp decline
in the machine building industry. In construction, food, consumer goods and light industries the decline also remains constant.
The negative situation continued in the third quarter of 1998. The
fall in world market prices for iron-ore, oil, and non-ferrous metals
due to financial crisis in South-East Asia led to decreased sales and
production. Capacity utilisation fell below 1997 levels. In 1997,
capacity utilisation was 43-44%. In the first quarter of 1998, it fell
to 38% and in the second quarter to 32%.
The rouble devaluation of nearly 50% damaged the Kazakhstani trade
balance with Russia and the rest of the world. In October 1998, 31% of
Kazakhstani exports went to Russia and 41% of imports carne from Russia.
In all, 27% of Kazakhstani export trade with Russia and 45% of import
tradefrom Russia was conducted in the national currencies, it is,
therefore, not surprising that the volume of Kazakhstani exports to
Russia fell by a quarter and the volume of imports increased by 150%.
Faced with stiff competition from Russian producers, Kazakhstani
producers reduced their production. As trade balance with Russia turned
negative, the deficit in balance of payments increased. The deficit
increased by US$700-900 million in the first half of 1998. The financing
of this deficit substantially reduced the reserves of the National Bank
of Kazakhstan.
As a result of the financial crisis in South East Asia, demand for
ferrous, non-ferrous metals and oil products fell. These products are
the main components of the Kazakhstani industry and made up
three-quarters of the total volume of exports. More than 20% of
industrial enterprises surveyed saw a deterioration in their financial
situation. Nearly 75% of enterprises did not notice any positive
changes. Half the enterprises pointed out that the main obstacle to
reviving industrial activity was the financial situation.
In 1998-1999, Kazakhstani enterprises experienced difficulty with
the competitiveness of their production in external markets, due to the
much lower wage costs in Asian countries. Kazakhstan as a manufacturing
producer became less attractive to the foreign investors. In April 1999,
the Kazakhstani government and the National Bank of Kazakhstan floated
the Tenge, as shown in Figure 1. Previous intervention by the National
Bank of Kazakhstan led to a drastic US$1 billion reduction in the
country's gold reserves. The major impact of the floating of the
exchange rate was expected to be the increase of competitiveness by
Kazakhstani producers and the abandonment of costly interventionist
policy previously conducted by the National Bank.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Major Kazakhstani enterprises welcomed the decision to float the
Tenge. The 30% depreciation made it possible for oil and metallurgical
firms to compete with enterprises in neighbouring countries. Kazakhstani
producers demanded a governmental programme of import substitution. The
main elements were changes in the VAT and elimination of customers'
tariffs on raw materials. These changes only took place in subsequent
years, outside the period analysed in this paper. In March 2000,
Kazakhstani government made some changes to the 'Resolution of the
Government of Kazakhstan on 14 November 1996, N1389', which were
directed to 'the support of the domestic producers and the creation
of the competitive environment for the domestic market'.
('Resolution of the Government of Kazakhstan on 31 March 2000,
N473'). Import tariffs were increased (of introduced) on a number
of agricultural/food processing goods, chemical products, ceramics and
various equipment items. As a consequence, the volume of import tariffs
rose by more than 300% between 1998 and 2001.
At the beginning of 1999, the Kazakhstani economy was in recession,
which was due in part to the internal economic instability and weakness
of the CIS systems. Attempts by the Kazakhstani government to improve
the situation by the introduction of import restrictions on goods from
Russia, Kyrgyzstan and Uzbekistan were unsuccessful. During several
months of 1998-1999, imports flora these countries were totally banned.
Unfortunately, Kazakhstan did not take advantage of the high exchange
rate of the Tenge to re-orientate its imports away flora consumer goods
towards the equipment and machinery required for the renovation of
industry.
Generally, the economic decline continued through the first 6
months of 1999. For example, the volume of industrial production,
investment, export and import fell to 95.1%, 94.1%, 66.4% and 78.6%,
respectively, of the 1998 levels. GDP fell 3.3% for the same period of
1998. There is a clear decline compared with the respective period of
the previous year. The situation is exaggerated due to the fact that the
GDP structure has deteriorated, as illustrated in Figure 2. There was a
decline in the shares of industrial production, transport services and
other sectors of the services in GDP.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
At the Almaty Investment Summit (3-4 June 1999) the Kazakhstani
President, N. Nazarbayev, highlighted the obstacles that the previous
stages of the Kazakhstani privatisation had caused by the failings in
the country's legislation, court system, tax administration,
bureaucracy and corruption. Undoubtedly, Kazakhstan needed to create a
new Concept of Privatisation. At the end of 1999, the economic situation
was still fragile.
DATABASE DESCRIPTION
The survey data used in this paper are concerned primarily with
quarterly changes in levels of employment and output in individual
enterprises. The data comprise 1633 observations on 701 enterprises in
Kazakhstan, collected from the second quarter of 1998 to the last
quarter of 1999 inclusive. Some enterprises were sampled repeatedly, and
other only once.
The data were compiled by the Institute of Economic Research under
the authority of the Ministry of Economy and Trade of the Republic of
Kazakhstan. The Institute especially designed this questionnaire for
explaining the conditions of the Kazakhstani economy. The data are
derived from responses to a postal questionnaire, which was completed by
top managers and chief specialists of industrial enterprises. The survey
covered 70% of industry as a whole. The data have been electronically
processed by the Centre for Euro-Asian Studies of the University of
Reading (UK).
The questions include information about general production
activity, economic situation of enterprises, changes in number of
employees, prices of output and input. All questions are closed; that
is, the possible variants of answers are suggested for the questions.
Participation was voluntary and confidentiality ensured for all
enterprises involved. The goal of the survey was to:
* establish a source of information about the level of business
activity, independent from government statistics;
* combine data from the survey with government statistical data for
the purposes of analysing current economic and business trends;
* obtain additional data to facilitate estimation of short-term
trends in different industries.
The advantages of the survey are: (1) speedy feedback and
flexibility in comparison with official statistics, (2) independent
presentation of perception of enterprise management, (3) the possibility
of assessment of current trends for middle- and small-scale enterprises
that is not available in official statistics, (4) the possibility to
estimate short-term trends in a particular industry and (5) the
possibility to get essential information about main factors that
influence the level of economic activity, trends and their changes.
There were some weaknesses in the survey. Some questions were not
informative. For example, the situation in the export sector is
difficult to measure due to the very small volume of exports for many
firms. Secondly, due to the advanced stage of privatisation by the time
of the survey a relatively small percentage of the firms surveyed were
state-owned enterprises.
The sample distribution by ownership, size and industry is reported
in Table 2.
Ownership classes include state-owned enterprises, joint ventures,
joint stock companies, privatised enterprises and other types of
enterprises. The predominant form of ownership is represented by
joint-stock companies, which represent nearly 80% of the enterprises.
Over 80% of industrial enterprises, 66% of construction enterprises and
over half of wholesale enterprises were privatised through joint stock
companies (see Kalyuzhnova, 1998). Size of enterprises varies from under
50 employees to more than 5,000 employees, with a significant
representation of all size categories. The industries covered include
chemicals, construction and building materials, fuel, light, food,
drink, machinery construction and steel, metallurgical industries, power
and woodwork. Regions include 20 oblasts, representative of the main
territorial division of Kazakhstan.
Figures 3 and 4 compare the distribution by ownership and size in
the sample and in the overall population during the sample period to
test how the sample is representative of the underlying population.
[FIGURES 3&4 OMITTED]
Figure 3 shows that in the 2 years analysed privatisation had
already reached a fairly advanced stage, with an initial percentage of
state-owned enterprises close to 10% (identical in the population and
the sample) decreasing to 6% and 3% in the population and sample,
respectively. While the sample analysed in the survey underestimates the
percentage of state-owned enterprises in the quarters following the
second quarter of 1998, it follows closely the quarterly trend of the
population. Regarding the size of enterprises, the distribution of the
sample and the population are very close and do not vary over time, as
shown in Figure 4, which reports the average value across the 2-year
period analysed.
DATA AND STATISTICAL METHODS
During the period analysed, macroeconomic volatility suddenly
increases as it covers a period of relatively stable recession preceding
the Russian financial crisis of the third quarter of 1998, to a period
of rapidly intensifying competition from Russian imports, which
terminated with the devaluation of the Tenge in April 1999.
Table 3 describes the changing economic conditions for the firms in
the sample. It is evident from the quarterly data on changes in
industrial output and employment that the economic situation of
Kazakhstani enterprises in 1998 was deteriorating, with a significant
proportion of enterprises suffering decline in output as well as
reduction of employment. The percentage of enterprises with the
employment decline peaked during the last quarter of 1998, whereas the
percentage of enterprises with the decline in output has been also very
pronounced, though it reached its peak in the last quarter of 1999. Some
signs of recovery occurred in the third quarter of 1999, following the
devaluation of the Tenge.
A careful consideration of the industries most affected by the
South Asian and Russian crises, such as the metallurgical industry,
corroborates the overall picture, both according to the trends in the
population and in the sample considered. In ferrous metallurgy, the
decline, which was more pronounced, was caused by the decrease in the
extraction volume of iron-ore as a response to the reduced demand for
rolled iron. This trend is clear in both Table 3 and Figure 5, which
reports the quarterly trend in industrial production for the industry as
a whole and for the metallurgical industry.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
The critical situation was also reflected in the exceptionally low
level of capacity utilisation--below 40%--which then began to increase
significantly from the second quarter of 1999, becoming close to 50% in
the last quarter of 1999. Decline in exports hit Kazakhstani industrial
enterprises in the last quarter of 1998 when the proportion of
enterprises facing a decline rose from about 17% in the third quarter to
23% in the last quarter and 31% in the first quarter of 1999. A
substantial improvement took place subsequently in the second quarter of
1999. This reflected the direct impact of the rouble devaluation on the
Kazakhstani trade balance with Russia and the rest of the world, due to
the strong economic inter-dependence between Russia and Kazakhstan.
As a result of the South Asian financial crisis, demand for
Kazakhstani raw material decreased, particularly for metallurgical
production. Looking at the sub-sample of metallurgical industries, it
can be seen that a sharp decline in export performance occurred in the
third quarter of 1998, when the proportion of enterprises facing decline
rose from 9% to about 17%, although the data also show a very
significant improvement in the export trend in the second quarter of
1999. For oil and metallurgical sectors, this positive trend was
associated with the Tenge flotation that allowed them to compete with
enterprises in neighbouring countries. To balance their position with
the Russian producers, the Kazakhstani exporters needed 30% devaluation,
which, in fact, took place.
RESULTS
Multinomial regression analysis is used to analyse the pattern of
short-run adjustment in employment. The dependent variables are defined
as increases and decreases in employment versus the group comparison of
firms with no change in employment. Increases and decreases are
identified separately in order to capture the asymmetries associated
with the security-oriented firm. Table 4 presents the results of the
multinomial (logit) regression for the change in employment.
The dependent variable is defined as a three-outcome variable,
equal to -1 (or + 1) it the enterprise experienced a decrease (or
increase) in employment with respect to the previous quarter and equal
to 0 if the enterprise experienced no change in employment. The
remaining variables are independent variables. The results are reported
in a standard format that indicates the estimated effect of each
independent variable, together with test statistics, significance levels
and diagnostic information, together with measures of goodness of fit for the regression as a whole. We focus first on the decrease in
employment and secondly on the increase in employment, both analysed
with respect to the comparison group of no-change in employment.
Employment decrease versos no change in employment
The change in output is highly significant and carries the expected
negative sign. Capacity utilisation is also highly significant, and
carries the expected negative sign. If capacity utilisation is higher,
the firm is more likely not to decrease employment. This supports
Proposition 2.
The dummy variables capturing ownership effects take the
state-owned firms as the control group, and distinguish different types
of private sector firms. None of the ownership dummies is significant.
Also, the interaction dummies between ownership and export orientation
are not significant either. Thus, private firms are not significantly
more likely than state-owned enterprises to reduce employment in
export-oriented sectors. Hence, the empirical evidence rejects
Proposition 1. This may be explained by the fact that privatisation did
not fundamentally change the behaviour of enterprises. At the very
least, ownership effects soon after the initial period of privatisation
were modest.
There is also some evidence of downward adjustments in employment
with respect to input price increases: an increase in raw material
prices is significant at 10% confidence level and carries the expected
positive sign. There is no evidence of downward adjustment of employment
with respect to output price decreases, though the coefficient carries
the expected negative sign.
The dummy representing the perception of uncertainty in tax policy
is significant at the 10% level and carries the expected positive sign,
making a decline in employment more likely. This confirms Proposition 4.
There is little support for Proposition 3, however, as the coefficient
associated to the presence of bad debt is insignificant, though it
carries the expected positive sign.
Our proposition on size (Proposition 5) is not supported. Large
firms are more likely than small firms to reduce employment. A possible
explanation of this result is that the number of employees in small
enterprises is close to the optimal one, while larger firms tend to hire
excessive numbers of employees.
The only significant time dummy corresponds to the third and fourth
quarters of 1999, and carries the expected negative sign, reflecting the
start of some recovery from the Russian crisis after the free flotation
of the Tenge in April 1999. Concerning regional dummies, the regions
neighbouring Russia that were the most vulnerable to the Russian
financial crisis through direct trade linkages are the most responsive
to downward employment adjustments compared to other regions. The
relevant coefficient is positive and significant at the 5% significance
level. The regions neighbouring Kyrgyzstan are negatively associated
with a decrease in employment, at the 10% significance level, suggesting
that these regions were relatively immune to the financial crisis. A
possible explanation is that industrial collapse has already proceeded
to such an extent that the crisis had little effect (especially for some
parts of Almatinskaya and South Kazakhstan). (10)
Employment increase versus no change in employment
Consider now the results for the increase of employment. The change
in output is highly significant and carries the expected positive sign.
Capacity utilisation is not significant, though it carries the expected
positive sign.
Hence, Proposition 2 is no longer confirmed. A possible explanation
is that in many cases employees of Kazakhstani enterprises were sent on
unpaid leave (up to 6 months) while remaining technically employed by
the enterprises when capacity utilisation was low. In other words, firms
were able to adjust to increased capacity utilisation simply by reducing
unpaid leave.
As before, none of the ownership dummies is significant. However,
in this case, the interaction dummies with export orientation are mostly
significant and suggest that private firms are more likely to increase
employment if they belong to export-oriented sectors. Hence, the
empirical evidence supports Proposition 1--at least in terms of
employment increase--suggesting a more dynamic entrepreneurial spirit by
export-oriented enterprises and a quicker response to better export
opportunities after the recovery from the Russian crisis.
There is also some evidence of upward employment adjustments in
response to price increases. In particular, an increase in output prices
is significant at 10% confidence level and carries the expected positive
sign. There is no evidence of upward adjustment of employment with
respect to input price decreases, though the coefficient carries the
expected negative sign.
The dummy representing the perception of uncertainty in tax policy
is again significant at the 10% level and carries the expected positive
sign, making an increase in employment more likely. This confirms
Proposition 4. With respect to Proposition 3, the coefficient associated
with bad debts is significant at the 10% level, but it carries an
unexpected positive sign. The explanation could be that firms which are
expanding output and employment most rapidly are doing so by taking on
new customers who are 'unknown quantities' and who are not
paying for their goods; the problem may be 'passed through' to
employees, who are then paid in arrears.
Proposition 5 on size is supported, as indicated by a negative
coefficient, which is significant at the 10% confidence level. Large
firms are less likely to increase employment, which is consistent with
the view that they are security-oriented firms. Unfortunately, though,
this view is inconsistent with the results for employment decrease
presented above. The overall pattern of the results is that large firms
decrease employment more, and increase employment less, than small
firms. The most obvious explanation is that this is part of a long-term
pattern in which small firms are growing faster than large firms. This
cannot be the whole story, however, for the impact of output-induced
growth on small firms will be captured directly by the employment change
variable, and so might not show up in the size variable. A plausible
explanation is that small firms are more optimistic about their future
prospects than are large firms, and so have the confidence to commit to
increasing employment that larger firms lack. They are, therefore, more
disposed to increase employment whether output in the current period has
increased or not. An alternative explanation is that small firms are
more responsive to positive output shocks due to the fact that large
firms are more likely to be initially overstocked with employees (due to
a selection effect).
In terms of time dummies, the most interesting result is that they
all carry a negative sign. The most significant dummy--and also the one
with the highest coefficient--corresponds to the aftermath of the
Russian crisis in the first quarter of 1999, and carries the expected
negative sign. The regional dummies show that regions neighbouring
Uzbekistan are the most responsive to upward employment adjustment--the
relevant coefficient is positive and significant at the 5% level.
Overall, these suggest that the ownership of the firm is a
significant influence on employment policy only for those enterprises
that have been hit by the Russian financial crisis. In particular, there
is evidence that state-owned exporters are more reluctant to increase
employment than their private sector counterparts. (11)
Moreover, there is some evidence that the price change variables
have a significant influence on employment adjustment, once the effect
of the additional control variables have been taken into account.
Uncertainty in tax policy also affects employment adjustment. There is,
therefore, some evidence in favour of employment-maximising strategies
being pursued by state-owned enterprises more severely affected by the
Russian crisis.
To check whether there are significant asymmetries with respect to
increases and decreases in employment in our model, we run the test that
the parameters in the two columns of Table 4 are identical (apart from a
minus sign). The null hypothesis could not be rejected, so we proceeded
to compare the results of the previous regression analysis using ordered
probit analysis. The results are reported in Table 5.
As expected, the results are very similar. The variables that are
highly significant using a multinomial logit analysis, both with regards
to increases and decreases in employment, are also highly significantly
using the ordered probit analysis. Notably, an increase in output is
also positively and highly significantly (at 1% confidence level)
correlated to an increase in employment. An increase in capacity
utilisation is also positively and significantly associated with an
increase in employment, even when in the previous analysis it was only
significant in the case of decreases in employment.
Regarding ownership effects, just as before none of the ownership
dummies is significant. However, the interaction dummies with export
orientation are significant and suggest that some of the private sector
categories that we identified are more likely to increase employment if
they belong to export-oriented sectors. This confirms the more dynamic
entrepreneurial spirit by export-oriented enterprises and a quicker
response to better export opportunities after the recovery from the
Russian crisis.
There is also evidence of upward employment adjustments in response
to price increases and input price decreases that was previously holding
only respectively in the case of employment increase and decreases.
Unlike the analysis above, the dummies representing the perception of
uncertainty in tax policy and bad debts are no longer significant, but
it should be noted that they were not consistent in the cases of
increases and decreases in employment. Finally, large firms are less
likely to increase employment, supporting Proposition 5, whereas an
inconsistent message was coming from the previous set of regression.
To determine the size of the effects, we also estimated the
marginal effects of the coefficients associated with increases and
decreases in employment for both regressions. A unitary increase in
output increases the likelihood of increase in employment by 8.5%. A
unitary increase (decrease) in the price of output (input) increases
(decreases) the likelihood of employment increases by around 2% (1.5%).
A unitary increase in output decreases the likelihood of decrease in
employment by 17.5%. A unitary increase (decrease) in the price of
output (input) decrease (increase) the likelihood of employment
decreases by around 2% (4%). Similar results hold for the ordered probit
analysis.
CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Our results suggest that, with the notable exception of
export-oriented enterprises, there is little difference between
state-owned and private sector firms in their short-run behaviour at the
time the survey was conducted. One explanation is that the private firms
in our sample had all been privatised fairly recently (1997-1998), and
therefore their behaviour was little changed. If true, this explanation
would suggest that changing the incentives that managers faced did not
produce immediate results in terms of modified behaviour. It suggests,
instead, that patterns of behaviour change slowly, perhaps because they
were more responsive to long-run 'culture change' than to
short-run incentive changes brought about by ownership change.
An alternative explanation is that the state acted just as
effectively as an owner or as a group of private shareholders. Although
many commentators might consider this view implausible, it must be
recognised that corporate governance issues were not as severe in a
state-owned firmas they could be in a private partnership or joint stock
firm. Where civil servants are imbued with a public service ethic, and
are willing to hold the managers of state-owned enterprises to account,
the state-owned enterprise may be forced to maximise profit in the same
way as a private firm. The only difference is that the profit in a
state-owned enterprise is used to reduce taxes, of finance public
expenditure, rather than as a source of personal income.
This argument can also be applied where the state does not fulfil its ownership role in a responsible manner. In this case, the managers
of state-owned enterprises may maximise perks. The enterprises may still
behave in the same way as private enterprises, however, because the
maximisation of perks leads to the same short-run behaviour as the
maximisation of profit. Only the distribution of profit is different in
the two cases. This has important implications in the case of a very
severe output shock, because it affects investment decisions. Salaried
managers counting perks do not have the funds to finance new investment,
but private shareholders often do have such funds. One could argue that
profits can be used for investment or perks. If the manager does not
have confidence that his/her position is secure, the expenditures will
be on immediately consumable goods rather than long-term rewards.
'... although everyone expected a deep restructuring in
post-privatisation time that will eventually lead to the transformation
of employment, and potential contributions to growth from the highly
skilled workforces, the experience of Kazakhstan illustrates the
weakness in the conducting privatisation with the weak institutions,
policies and practices' (Kalyuzhnova and Andreff, 2005, p. 8).
Our results confirm the conclusions reached by Djankov (2000) that
privatised enterprises and state-owned enterprises perform in a similar
way, at least in the short run. Our results also suggest that only
private enterprises that experienced the most severe consequences of an
adverse external output shock behaved in a significantly different way
from state-owned enterprises. This suggests that the incentives of
privatised enterprises to move towards profit maximisation have been
strengthened by the discipline imposed by the 1998 Russian crisis.
Table 1: Main testable propositions
Employment decrease Employment increase
Output increase -- ++
Capacity utilisation -- ++
Private ownership + +
Export orientation + +
Size -- --
Bad debts + --
Instability of tax policy + +
Table 2: Summary statistics of sample firms
Ownership Freq. Percent
State 73 4.53
Joint ventures (JV) 26 1.61
Joint stock (JS) 1,264 78.36
Private 38 2.36
Other 212 13.14
Total 1,613 100
Size Freq. Percent
<50 76 4.68
51-100 231 14.22
101-200 368 22.66
201-500 414 25.49
501-2000 380 23.4
2001-5000 100 6.16
>5000 55 3.39
Total 1,624 100
Industry Freq. Percent
Chemical 50 3.06
Constr. and build. Mat, 140 8.57
Fuel 114 6.98
Light 174 10.66
Food 375 22.96
Drink 140 8.57
Machinery, constr. And steel 288 17.64
Metallurgical 175 10.72
Power 136 8.33
Woodwork 41 2.51
Total 1,633 100
Source: Kazakhstani Institute of Economic Research's Survey, The Centre
for Euro-Asian Studies Database
Note: JV-assume at least one foreign partner; JS-the first stage of
privatisation, which is required a formal registration with the
Ministry of Privatisation/Property; Priv-implies that a private owner
has a majority of the ownership of the company.
Table 3: Distribution by quarters (II quarter 1998-IV quarter 1999)
Q2 1998 Q3 1998 Q4 1998 Q1 1999
Employment change (Empchg)
-1 26.63 19.8 31.03 29.21
0 58.29 67.58 59.91 67.82
1 15.08 12.63 9.05 2.97
Output change (Outchg)
-1 23.65 23.21 32.9 32.34
0 36.45 37.2 35.06 36.32
1 39.9 39.59 32.03 31.34
Output change metallurgical industry (outchg
metal. ind)
-1 7.14 17.24 31.03 30
0 14.29 31.03 27.59 50
1 78.57 51.72 41.38 20
Export change (Expchg)
-1 19.57 16.67 22.95 31.37
0 47.83 58.89 57.38 56.86
1 32.61 24.44 19.67 11.76
Export change metallurgical industry (expchg
metal. in d)
-1 9.09 16.67 25 20
0 27.27 50 37.5 70
1 63.64 33.33 37.5 10
Output price change (Prchg)
-1 17 14.88 14.29 18.69
0 76 76.82 78.79 77.78
1 7 8.3 6.93 3.54
Input price change (Inprchg)
-1 5.61 5.19 6.58 4.81
0 63.78 65.4 65.35 71.66
1 30.61 29.41 28.07 23.53
Debt
0 38.42 35.35 36.48 37.62
1 61.58 64.65 63.52 62.38
Tax policy (Taxpol)
0 79.8 77.1 83.26 78.22
1 20.20 22.9 16.74 21.78
Capacity utilisation (Caput)
Mean 38.95 40.37 39.6 43.6
Q2 1999 Q3 1999 Q4 1999
Employment change (Empchg)
-1 28.51 17.16 21.34
0 59.5 70.59 69.04
1 11.98 12.25 9.62
Output change (Outchg)
-1 32.37 22.93 35.56
0 31.54 29.76 26.78
1 36.1 47.32 37.66
Output change metallurgical industry
(outchg metal. ind)
-1 17.86 10.34 41.67
0 25 41.38 20.83
1 57.14 48.28 37.5
Export change (Expchg)
-1 12.7 14.75 28.27
0 53.97 59.02 51.43
1 33.33 26.23 20
Export change metallurgical industry
(expchg metal. in d)
-1 6.25 5.88 31.25
0 56.25 52.94 37.5
1 37.5 41.18 31.25
Output price change (Prchg)
-1 11.16 9.31 9.24
0 73.14 67.16 73.53
1 15.7 23.53 17.23
Input price change (Inprchg)
-1 3.4 2.05 2.99
0 52.34 46.15 48.72
1 44.26 51.79 48.29
Debt
0 35.8 32.2 40.42
1 64.2 67.8 59.58
Tax policy (Taxpol)
0 68.72 73.17 72.92
1 31.28 26.83 27.08
Capacity utilisation (Caput)
Mean 43.75 47.85 48.44
Source: Kazakhstani Institute of Economic Research's Survey, The Centre
for Euro-Asian Studies Database.
Notes: Empchg, outchg, expchg, prchg, inprchg is 1 (-1) if,
respectively employment, output, export, output and input prices
increase (decrease) and 0 if constant. Debt and Taxpol are equal to 1
if, respectively, bad debt from customers and uncertainty in tax policy
are perceived as a main impediment to economic activity and 0
otherwise. Caput is the percentage of capacity utilisation.
Table 4: Determinants of employment change-multinomial logit
Empchg Empdec Empinc
Outchg -1.079 *** 1.587 ***
(0.106) (0.204)
Caput -0.016 *** 0.0007
(0.001) (0.004)
JS 0.071 -0.562
(0.407) (0.542)
JV -1.042 -2.019
(1.190) (1.329)
Priv -0.455 -1.947
(0.775) (1.280)
Other -0.078 -0.510
(0.464) (0.600)
JSExp -0.780 2.224 *
(0.849) (1.245)
JVExp 0.459 3.387 *
(1.834) (2.101)
PrivExp 0.755 3.504 *
(1.338) (1.942)
OtherExp -1.222 2.156
(1.059) (1.440)
Exp 0.769 -2.126 *
(0.843) (1.230)
Prchg -0.099 0.378 *
(0.157) (0.201)
Inprchg 0.254 * -0.248
(0.142) (0.191)
Debt 0.227 0.378 *
(0.174) (0.225)
TaxPol 0.322 * 0.408 *
(0.178) (0.227)
Size 0.158 ** -0.160 *
(0.069) (0.095)
Ind. dummies Yes Yes
Regional dummies Yes Yes
Quarterly dummies Yes Yes
N 1,365
[chi square] 498.17 ***
Log-Likelihood 932.20
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.2109
Notes: *** Statistically significant at 1%; ** statistically
significant at 5%; * statistically significant at 10%. Standard
errors in parentheses. The comparison group is represented by empchg=0,
that is enterprises for which there is no change in employment.
Table 5: Determinants of employment change-ordered probit
Empchg
Outchg 0.711 ***
(0.048)
Caput 0.005 ***
(0.001)
JS -0.159
(0.192)
JV -0.045
(0.396)
Priv -0.256
(0.373)
Other -0.160
(0.214)
JSExp 0.850 **
(0.414)
JVExp 0.654
(0.706)
PrivExp 0.619
(0.652)
OtherExp 1.005 **
(0.489)
Exp -0.812 **
(0.411)
Prchg 0.120 *
(0.070)
Inprchg -0.130 *
(0.065)
Debt -0.021
(0.076)
TaxPol -0.035
(0.080)
Size -0.088 ***
(0.032)
Ind. dummies Yes
Regional dummies Yes
Quarterly dummies Yes
n 1,365
[chi square] 380.86 ***
Log-likelihood 990.86
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.1612
Notes. *** Statistically significant at 1%; ** statistically
significant at 5%; * statistically significant at 10%. Standard errors
in parentheses.
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Wladimir Andreff, John Bonin, Ken Charman, Jeff
Miller and the anonymous referees for their helpful comments and
discussion. All remaining errors and omissions are our own
responsibilities. The views expressed in this paper are those of the
authors and do not reflect the official position of the EBRD.
(1) For a recent survey on privatisation, see Megginson and Netter
(2001).
(2) See Stiglitz (1994).
(3) For a comprehensive survey of soft budget constraints, see
Maskin and Xu (2001).
(4) The paper by Djankov (1999a, b) illustrates the effects of
different modalities of privatisation to insiders on the restructuring
process, highlighting the fact that restructuring is more rapid in
enterprises bought out by their managers.
(5) For a description of trade linkages as channels of contagion through the region, see EBRD (1998).
(6) Djankov (1999b)'s survey include 960 privatised
manufacturing companies from 1995 to 1997 in Georgia, Kazakhstan, the
Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, Russia and the Ukraine.
(7) It is also possible to have a disequilibrium of excess demand,
in which the output is set simply by the capacity limits of the firm;
this case is not considered here because of its limited relevance to
transitional economies in recession.
(8) In addition, firms are more likely to report that instability
of tax policy is a problem when other adverse changes in government
policy occur, which reinforces the tendency for employment to be
reduced.
(9) By export orientation, we mean whether the enterprise is
exporting outside the country including CIS countries and the rest of
the world.
(10) We introduce industry, time and regional dummies to control
for specific effects related to these dimension. However, we also run
the regressions in the absence of such dummies and the results still
hold.
(11) The interaction terms between ownership and the other
variables, such as price changes, policy changes and bad debt are not
reported, as they are not significant.
REFERENCES
Aghion, P and Blanchard, O. 1998: On privatization methods in
Eastern Europe and their implications. Economics of Transition 61:
87-99.
Alexeev, M and Kaganovich, M. 2001: Dynamics of privatization under
a subsistence constraint. Journal of Comparative Economics 293: 417-447.
Barro, R and Grossman, HI. 1976: Money employment and inflation.
Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.
Carlin, W, van Reenen. J and Wolfe, T. 1995: Enterprise
restructuring in early transition: the case study evidence from Central
and Eastern Europe. Economics of Transition 3: 427-458.
Djankov, S. 1999a: The restructuring of insider--dominated firms.
Economics of Transition 72: 467-479.
Djankov, S. 1999b: Ownership structure and enterprise restructuring
in six newly independent states. Working paper 2047, World Bank,
February 1999.
Djankov, S and Murrell, P. 2002: Enterprise restructuring in
transition: A quantitative survey. Journal of Economic Literature XV:
739-792.
Djankov, S and Nenova, T, 2000: Why did privatisation failed in
Kazaklzstan? Mimeo, World Bank.
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). 1998:
Transition report. EBRD: London.
Fair, RC. 1969: The short-run demand for workers and hours.
North-Holland: Amsterdam.
Ferguson, CE. 1977: The neoclassical theory of production and
distribution. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, MA.
Jorgenson, DW. 1996: Capital theory and investment behaviour. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. 1998: The Kazakstani economy: Independence and
transition. Macmillan Press: Basingstoke.
Kalyuzhnova, Y. 2002: Economies and energy. Caspian Energy: Present
and Future, Chapter 3. In: Kalyuzhnova, Y, Myers, AJ, Lynch D and
Sickles, R (eds). Palgrave: Basingstoke and New York.
Kalyuzhnova, Y and Andreff W (eds). 200,3: Privatisation and
structural change in transition economies. Palgrave: Basingstoke and New
York.
Kazakhstan Economic Trends. 2000: TACIS. January 2000, Brussels.
Maskin, E and Xu, C. 2001: Soft budget constraint theories: From
centralisation to the market. Economics of Transition 91: 1-27.
Megginson, W and Netter, J. 2001: From state to market: A survey of
empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature
39:321-389.
National Statistical Office. (1998-2000): Socialiono-Ekonomicheskoe
Polozhenie Respubliki Kazakhstan. Monthly national statistics. Almaty.
Pinto, B, Belka, M and Krajewski, S. 1993: Transforming state
enterprises in Poland: Evidence on adjustment by manufacturing firms.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 213-270.
Resolution of the Government of Kazakhstan on 14 November 1996,
N1389.
Resolution of the Government of Kazakhstan on 31 March 2000, N473.
Stiglitz, J. 1994: Whither socialism? The Wicksell lectures. MIT
Press: Cambridge, MA.
YELENA KALYUZHNOVA (1), MARIA VAGLIASINDI (2) & MARK CASSON (1)
(1) The centre for Euro-Asian Studies, The University of Reading,
Whiteknights, PO Box 218, Reading, UK. E-mail:
y.kaluyzhnova@reading.ac.uk; (2) European Bank for Reconstruction and
Development, London, UK