Exchange rate regime choice in Central and Eastern European transitional economies.
Klyuev, Vladimir
I. Introduction
The choice of exchange rate regimes by Central and Eastern European
(CEE) transitional economies exhibits a surprising degree of
heterogeneity both across countries and over time. The region features
several currency boards, fixed but adjustable pegs, crawling pegs,
bands, and crawling bands, as well as almost pure floats. A look at the
evolution of the exchange rate regimes summarized in the Appendix
reveals that this evolution does not seem to have a particular
direction. The Czech Republic, Poland and a number of other countries
fixed their exchange rates at the beginning of the transition, but later
gradually moved from pegs to more flexible regimes. Romania has had a
floating regime since 1991, but the extent to which the exchange rate
was managed first decreased and then increased. The Baltic states fixed
their exchange rates within a couple of years after obtaining
independence. Bulgaria introduced a currency board after several years
of floating.
This diversity seems surprising given the commonality of the
communist legacy and the shared vision of the future where all countries
in the region proclaim that they are building market economies and
democratic political regimes with membership in the European Union as
their goal. True, these countries are distinct in many aspects, but they
hardly differ more from each other than Western European countries,
which have maintained broadly similar arrangements for most of this
century.
The traditional economic literature developed from Mundell's
[1961] and McKinnon's [1963] seminal work on optimal currency areas
does not help explain the diversity of the choices. All small and open
economies, located in the same geographic region, similarly endowed with
natural resources, the CEE countries should all have opted for the same
regime. More sophisticated versions of the optimal currency area
literature focus on the statistical distributions of various shocks
(e.g., Tumovsky [1976]). The applicability of this approach to
explaining the regime choice is limited since, by the very nature of
transition, the countries of the region are not in steady-state
positions, and the distributions of shocks cannot be considered
stationary. Hence, the past offers little guidance with regard to future
disturbances, so there is no relevant history that would allow one to
apply this criterion.
The "new" theory of optimal currency areas, whose main
advances are summarized by Tavlas [1993], offers more insights into the
choices made by transitional economies. It allows for rational
expectations and brings political economy into the picture. As one
implication, it emphasizes the use of a fixed exchange rate as a nominal
anchor in fighting inflation. This issue is very relevant for
transitional economies, since price liberalization at the beginning of
transition resulted in a powerful outburst of inflation and in some
economies it started a wage-price inflationary spiral (Bruno, 1993).
Moreover, since not all regulated prices were liberalized at the same
time, increases in controlled prices provided further inflationary
shocks. An introduction of indirect taxes had a similar effect. In
addition, the rapid economic transformation of these countries required
continual relative price adjustment, which was inflationary in the
presence of downward price rigidity (Coorey et al, 1998). Finally, lax fiscal policies, in particular the support of loss-making state-owned
enterprises, in some cases resulted in budget deficits financed by money
creation (Fischer et al, 1996). (1) As a result, all the transitional
economies confronted the issue of curbing runaway inflation, even though
the extent of the problem was clearly different in different countries.
Fighting inflation requires a nominal anchor, and the choice is
generally between the money supply and the exchange rate. Calvo and Vegh
[1999] offer an excellent survey of the issues surrounding this choice.
An important advantage of the exchange rate is that it provides a highly
visible, easily verifiable target, while monitoring the behavior of the
money supply is quite complicated. Such a visible anchor helps
coordinate the expectations of price- and wage-setters around a
low-inflation equilibrium. It also serves to reinforce the
government's commitment to the stabilization effort. Monetary and
fiscal policies inconsistent with maintaining the exchange rate target
would result in a collapse of the regime on which the government has
staked its credibility and consequently damage its electoral prospects.
A fixed exchange rate regime facilitates the rebuilding of real money
balances by economic actors, which will be demanded if the inflation
rate is expected to go down. On the contrary, a reduction in the rate of
growth of the money supply under a money-based stabilization will leave
businesses and households starving for liquidity, which will drive
interest rates up and plunge the economy into a recession. (2) Providing
just enough cash at the beginning of the program (a one-time jump in the
level of the money supply, followed by a reduction in its rate of
growth) is problematic for two reasons. First of all, the credibility of
a money-based stabilization program that starts with an expansion of
domestic credit will be very much in question. In addition, the
unpredictability of money demand in transitional economies makes the
calculation of the right adjustment a highly precarious exercise, while
the unstable money multiplier and underdeveloped indirect instruments of
monetary policy make it difficult to meet a given target for broad
monetary aggregates.
The superiority of the exchange rate anchor is by no means
uncontested. Calvo and Vegh [1999] note that the choice between the two
nominal anchors involves a tradeoff of "recession now"
(money-based stabilization) versus "recession later"
(exchange-rate-based stabilization); the authors discuss both empirical
evidence to this effect and conceptual reasons why this may be so.
Tornell and Velasco [1995, 1998] cast doubt on the assumption that fixed
exchange rate regimes impose more fiscal discipline on the government.
They note that fiscal laxity will undermine a peg only after some time,
forcing a discrete devaluation in the future. Under a float, budget
deficits financed by money creation will lead to an immediate
depreciation. If the value of the domestic currency, and the overall
price level, which is linked to it, affect private citizens'
welfare and hence their level of support for the government, the latter
will face the consequences of fiscal profligacy later under a fixed
exchange rate regime and may well opt for higher spending under a peg
than under a float, if its time horizon is sufficiently short.
In spite of these reservations, the belief in the efficacy of the
exchange rate as a nominal anchor seems to have dominated the thinking
of economic policymakers and external advisors at the outset of
transition. Statements to this effect permeate such edited volumes as
Williamson [1991], Barth and Wong [1994], and Sweeney et al. [1999], as
well as numerous other books and articles. Floating was grudgingly recommended to countries that lacked sufficient foreign exchange
reserves, where the alternative was seen to be infeasible.
On the other hand, it is well known that enlisting the support of
an exchange-rate anchor to fight inflation is not without problems. Most
notably, the inflation rate does not drop immediately to trading-partner
levels, for a variety of reasons, including imperfect credibility and
explicit or implicit backward wage indexation. The result is a real
appreciation of the domestic currency, which undermines the
competitiveness of the country's exports and encourages imports.
This causes the trade balance and the current account balance to
deteriorate and raises the question of sustainability of this type of
stabilization in the long run. Indeed, the countries of the region that
have chosen to peg have typically seen a deterioration in the trade and
current account balances. It may be argued that restructuring and
productivity growth should lead to an appreciation of the equilibrium
real exchange rate, and that the current account deficits are
comfortably financed with capital inflows. At the same time, the
accounts of policy discussions in CEE countries indicate that real
appreciation, loss of competitiveness, and current account deficits have
been perceived as a problem, particularly in the wake of the Mexican and
the Asian financial crises. Hence, having reduced inflation to moderate
levels, a number of countries in the region (e.g., the Czech Republic,
Hungary, and Poland) have introduced more flexible arrangements.
This article offers a simple model of exchange rate regime
determination where the tradeoff between the use of the exchange rate as
an anti-inflation tool and as a competitiveness tool takes center stage.
While the discussions of the optimal choice of exchange rate regime
abound, relatively few formal models of this choice have been developed
in the literature. Our model is related to those where price stability
(facilitated by a fixed exchange rate) is traded off against a stimulus
to the real economy that may be produced by depreciation of domestic
currency. (3) Those models (e.g., Devarajan and Rodrik [1992]; Edwards
[1996]) approach the choice of exchange rate regime from the perspective
of long-term optimality. The policymakers choose a regime that will
minimize the expected value of their loss function, while the economy is
subject to shocks with a known probability distribution. (4) There are
no linkages between periods.
A key feature of our model is a link between past inflation and the
present, which comes in the form of backward wage indexation. In
addition, we take a shorter-run approach in view of the fluidity of the
choice of exchange rate regimes and the shortness of policymakers'
horizons in the economies in transition, especially in the earlier
years. (5) The regime is chosen for one period only, when past inflation
is known, so the choice is optimal ex post.
Our model predicts a nonlinear relationship between the inflation
rate and the degree of exchange rate flexibility. The optimal degree of
flexibility first increases with the rate of inflation, reflecting the
concern for maintaining external competitiveness. At very high rates,
however, inflation is seen as the most important problem, and the use of
a fixed exchange rate as a nominal anchor is called for. A set of
regressions confirms that this relationship indeed exists and is fairly
robust in the data. In the recent literature a similar nonlinear
relationship between inflation and exchange rate flexibility has been
found for Latin America (Collins [1996]; Frieden et al. [2000]). While
the justification for expecting high-inflation countries to opt for a
fixed exchange rate regime is the same nominal anchor argument that we
use, these papers do not convert the logic into a formal model.
Our model is an attempt to capture in a parsimonious form the
essential features of the actual choice of exchange rate arrangements
made by policymakers in the countries of Central and Eastern Europe.
While the optimal regime is derived from a minimization of an explicit
loss function, no direct link is made between this loss function and the
welfare of the citizens of those countries. This is a positive
description of the choices made rather than a normative model of what
the optimal exchange rate regime should be.
While the tradeoff between inflation and real appreciation is
relevant for the countries in the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) as well, we do not see our model as adequately describing their
choice of exchange rate regime. The main reason is that the model
assumes consistency between the exchange rate regime on the one hand and
monetary and fiscal policies on the other, and such consistency is
generally lacking in the CIS countries. Moreover, an important premise
of our theory--that a fixed exchange rate is used as an instrument of
choice in inflation stabilization programs--is not borne out by evidence
in that region. In addition, the CIS governments have been unable to
commit credibly to tight monetary and fiscal policies that would make a
peg sustainable. Important reasons for the difference between the CIS
and CEE countries may be the lack of a natural anchor currency for the
former, given their geographic location, their trade patterns, and the
inadequacy of foreign currency reserves.
The article is organized as follows. The next section introduces
the model, derives the optimal choice of exchange rate regime, and
discusses some comparative statics results. Then we study the dynamic
implications of the model for the evolution of inflation and exchange
rate regimes in the region. We discuss the limitations of the model in
Section III. Empirical results along with a number of robustness checks
are presented in Section IV.. The last section concludes.
II. The Model
The discussion in the introductory section singles out the nominal
anchor property of a fixed (or, more generally, pre-announced) exchange
rate, inflation inertia, and concern about real appreciation as issues
relevant for the choice of exchange rate regime in transitional
economies. A parsimonious model of an open economy that highlights these
features has been developed by Edwards [1993], and we take it as a
foundation for our political economy model.
The structure of the economy is described by equations (1)-(6)
below.
(1) [[pi].sub.t] = [alpha][[pi].sub.Tt] + (1-[alpha])[[pi].sub.Nt]
(2) [[pi].sub.Tt] = [d.sub.t]
(3) [d.sub.t] = [phi][[pi].sub.t-1], 0 [less than or equal to]
[phi] [less than or equal to] 1
(4) [N.sup.D] ([P.sub.N] / [P.sub.T], [Z.sub.t]) = [N.sup.S] (W /
[P.sub.N])
(4') [eta] ([[pi].sub.Nt]- [[pi].sub.Tt])+ [delta] [z.sub.t] =
[epsilon]([w.sub.t] - [[pi].sub.Nt]), [eta] < 0, [delta] > 0,
[epsilon] < 0
(5) [w.sub.t] = [gamma][[pi].sub.t-1] +
(1-[gamma])[[pi].sup.e.sub.t], 0 [less than or equal to] [gamma] [less
than or equal to] 1
(6) [[pi].sup.e.sub.t] = [[pi].sub.t]
The economy produces two types of goods: a tradable and a
nontradable commodity. Equation (1) defines overall inflation as a
weighted sum of the rates of tradable and nontradable price increases.
Equation (2) states that purchasing power parity holds for tradable
goods. Hence, an increase in the price of tradables equals the rate of
devaluation. Equation (3) defines the exchange rate regime of the
country as a passive crawling peg. Parameter [phi] determines the extent
to which devaluation compensates for past inflation, with [phi] = 0
corresponding to a fixed exchange rate regime and [phi] = 1
corresponding to real exchange rate targeting. Equation (4) states that
the demand for nontradables, expressed as a function of their relative
price and aggregate domestic demand [Z.sub.t], must equal the supply of
nontradables, which depends upon the real product wage in that sector.
Equation (4') is obtained by differentiating equation (4) with
respect to time. Here [eta] is the demand elasticity of nontradables
with respect to their relative price; [delta] is the demand elasticity
of nontradables with respect to aggregate demand pressures; and e is the
supply elasticity of nontradables with respect to the real product wage.
Equation (5) says that the growth rate of the nominal wage is a weighted
average of past and expected future inflation, and the parameter [gamma]
captures the degree to which wage formation is backward-looking.
Finally, equation (6) reflects the assumption that inflationary
expectations are formed rationally.
It is important to note that partial backward indexation of wages
should be seen as a means of introducing inertial elements into the
model rather than a way to capture a particular institutional mechanism.
Wage indexation may be implicit rather than explicit. Moreover,
inflation may have inertia because the exchange rate anchor is not
completely credible, or because inflationary expectations persist (some
sort of adaptive expectations). Any of these factors would make the rate
of inflation higher than the rate of depreciation and result in real
appreciation.
Equations (1) through (6) can be manipulated to obtain the
following autoregressive process for inflation:
(7) [[pi].sub.t] = a[[pi].sub.t-1] + b[z.sub.t],
where a = ([eta]+[epsilon][alpha])[phi]+[epsilon](1-[alpha])[gamma]
/ ([eta]+[epsilon][alpha])+[epsilon](1-[alpha])[gamma] and b=
-[delta](l-[alpha]) /
([eta]+[epsilon][alpha])+[epsilon](1-[alpha])[gamma],
0 [less than or equal to] a [less than or equal to] 1, b>0.
Expansionary policies (positive [z.sub.t],) fuel inflation, while a
contraction helps break the inflationary cycle. In this article we want
to focus on nominal anchor properties of the exchange rate, so we
abstract from aggregate demand management, or rather, posit that
monetary and fiscal policies are strictly in line with the chosen
exchange rate path. We discuss this important assumption in detail in
Section IV. Here we set [z.sub.t] = 0, and (7) becomes
(7') [[pi].sub.t] = a[[pi].sub.t-1].
We will also have:
(8) [[pi].sub.Tt] = [d.sub.t] = [phi][[pi].sub.t-1], and
(9) [w.sub.t], = [gamma] [[pi].sub.t-1] + (1 -
[gamma])a[[pi].sub.t-1],
so the rate of real appreciation is
(10) [s.sub.t], = [w.sub.t] - [[pi].sub.Tt] = [gamma](1 - [phi]) x
[eta]+[epsilon] / ([eta] + [epsilon][alpha])+[epsilon](1-[alpha])[gamma]
[[pi].sub.t-1].
Note that real appreciation is identified with an increase in the
product wage in the tradable sector and reflects a loss of
competitiveness in the international market. (6)
If [delta] = 1, then a = 1 and [s.sub.t]=0. The inflation process
has a unit root (there is no nominal anchor), and there is no real
appreciation. Of course, in reality a break on inflation may be provided
by policies other than a fixed exchange rate. These policies would be
reflected in the [z.sub.t] term.
Having [delta] = 0 (credibly fixed exchange rate) is not enough to
halt inflation in its tracks unless [gamma] = 0. If the wage formation
process is backward-looking, inflation will not drop to zero
immediately, and there will be some real appreciation.
Equations (7') and (10) describe the dynamics of inflation and
real appreciation for given parameter values and the initial inflation
rate. In keeping with our focus on the choice of exchange rate regime,
we now make [delta] (the degree to which the exchange rate accommodates
past inflation) a decision variable. We assume that the authorities
minimize the following loss function:
(11) L = [[pi].sup.2.sub.t] + k[([s.sub.t] - [s.sup.*].sup.2] +
m([[phi].sub.t]- [[phi].sub.t-1], k>0, m>0.
This reflects an aversion to inflation, an unwillingness to have a
real appreciation (and hence lose competitiveness in the tradables
sector), and the cost of changing exchange rate arrangements. As is
typical in the political economy literature, the loss function is
assumed to be a convex function of its arguments, so that, e.g., a given
increase of inflation is perceived to be more onerous if it starts from
a higher base. The preferred level of inflation is zero, while the
preferred rate of real appreciation is negative ([s.sup.*]<0). (7)
This assumption can be seen as a shortcut combining two common
suppositions (e.g., Devarajan and Rodrik [1992]); namely, that real
depreciation has an expansionary effect and that the government's
real output target is greater than the natural rate. Changing the regime
is presumed to be costly because of the status quo bias that has been
well documented in the political economy literature in various
incarnations (e.g., Alesina and Drazen [1991], Fernandez and Rodrik
[1991]). Changing an important rule by which the economy functions (and
even an anticipation of such a change) introduces uncertainty and
disruption in economic life, so this decision is not taken lightly.
Moreover, in view of the argument that the choice of exchange rate
regime has distributional consequences, an attempt to change the regime
would generate resistance on the part of negatively affected groups;
therefore, it is unlikely to be undertaken even by a benevolent government unless the net welfare benefit of such a change is high
(Rodrik [1994]). These institutional costs are incurred regardless of
the direction of the change, which explains the square term. The
assumption that the cost of the exchange rate regime adjustment depends
upon the magnitude of adjustment reflects the fact that marginal changes
of the regime (changing the rate of the crawl or playing with the width
of the band) are likely to introduce less disruption and generate less
resistance than a radical switch in the regime.
The authorities choose the regime [[phi].sub.t], to minimize L
taking [[phi].sub.t-1], and [[pi].sub.t-1] as given. L is a quadratic
function of [[phi].sub.t] with a positive coefficient on the square
term, so it is convex in [[phi].sub.t] and the point where the
derivative of L with respect to [[phi].sub.t], equals zero is the global
minimum. Of course, we should also take into account that [[phi].sub.t]
is only allowed to vary between zero and one. The first order condition
yields the following expression:
(12) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
This is a nonlinear function of [[pi].sub.t-1]. If [[pi].sub.t-1] =
0, then [[phi].sub.t] = [[phi].sub.t-1], and there is no reason to
change the regime in this framework. It is obvious that when
[[pi].sub.t] is small, [[phi].sub.t] is an increasing function of
[[pi].sub.t-1]. For large [[pi].sub.t-1], [phi], tends to a limit that
is less than one and could be negative. Of course, [[phi].sub.t] < 0
is not feasible; thus, for any inflation rate above a certain limit,
fixing the exchange rate may be the optimal response. Further analysis
shows that the expression in (12) first increases and then decreases
with [[pi].sub.t-1], so the model validates the logic of our informal
argument. (8)
Holding everything else constant, greater weight in the loss
function on real appreciation (increasing k) favors a more accommodative
stance (higher [[phi].sub.t]). More weight on inflation (reducing both k
and m) favors smaller [[phi].sub.t], and increasing the cost of
adjustment, m, makes the regime more sticky.
A greater degree of backward indexation of wages, [gamma],
increases [kappa], [zeta], and [theta], and decreases [xi]. The effect
on the exchange-rate regime is ambiguous and depends on parameter values
and initial conditions. There is no effect at zero inflation. At small
rates, a higher degree of indexation will be accommodated by choosing a
more flexible regime. At high rates of inflation, depending in
particular on the weight assigned to external competitiveness in the
loss function and on the regime in place at the moment, greater backward
indexation may be offset with more aggressive pegging, may be
accommodated through more flexibility, or may have no effect on the
choice of regime if the choice is already at one of the extremes.
For [gamma] < 1, [kappa] is a decreasing function of [alpha].
Hence, for low inflation (such that the quadratic terms in (12')
can be ignored), less flexibility in the exchange rate is preferred by
more open economies (since [alpha] is the share of tradables in the
consumer basket) for any given [[pi].sub.t-1]. [theta] declines with
[alpha]. How that affects the choice of regime depends on parameter
values and initial conditions. (9) [xi] is an increasing function of
[alpha], so the term that contains x contributes to making the regime
less flexible for more open economies. [xi] is a complicated function of
[alpha]. One can show (see Klyuev [2000]) that [differential][zeta] /
[differential][alpha]<0 whenever |[eta] + [epsilon][alpha]| >
[epsilon][gamma](1-[alpha])|. The last inequality will hold except in
quite closed economies with a high degree of wage indexation (low
[alpha], high [gamma]). Therefore, the term [zeta][[pi].sup.2.sub.t-1]
in the numerator somewhat mitigates the tendency of more open economies
to have more sticky exchange rates, but it acquires significance only
when the inflation rate is quite high. All in all, one can expect trade
openness to be associated with less exchange rate flexibility at low
rates of inflation, while at higher rates the result may be reversed.
III. Dynamic Implications
In the model developed above the policymakers look only one period
ahead--an assumption that could be justified by uncertainty about more
remote horizons, be it uncertainty about economic developments,
geopolitical developments, or simply about the chances of being
reelected. It might be interesting, however, to see what kind of
dynamics the model implies for inflation and exchange rate regimes over
several periods if the system suffers no major disturbances.
Specifically, the following experiment is performed. We fix the
structure of the economy as described by equations (1) through (6),
choose a starting point (initial exchange rate regime and initial
inflation), and let a sequence of governments, which minimize one-period
loss function (11), determine the time path of the economy. We assume
there are no shocks along the way. Each government will choose the
regime [??] as in (12), given the regime and the inflation rate it has
inherited from the previous government, and will leave this regime and
inflation determined by (7') as a legacy to its successor.
Equations (7') and (12) determine the time path of inflation
and the exchange- rate rule from any point onward, provided the loss
function does not change and the system is not subject to any shocks. A
phase diagram can be used to analyze the behavior of the system.
Inflation is stationary in two cases: when inflation is zero or
when the exchange rate regime parameter [??] equals one. If [??], is
less than one, inflation decreases in period t.
Equation (12) can be manipulated to obtain a change in the degree
of exchange rate flexibility between two periods:
[[??].sub.t] - [[??].sub.t-1] = [kappa] + ([theta] -
[zeta])[[pi].sub.t-1] - ([theta] + [xi]) [p.sup.2] [[pi].sub.t-1]
[[??].sub.t-1] / 1 + ([theta] + [xi])[[pi].sup.2.sub.t-1] /
[[pi].sub.t-1]
The degree of flexibility does not change in two cases: when
inflation is zero or along the downward-sloping line
[??] = [kappa] / ([theta] + [xi])[pi] + ([theta] - [zeta]) /
([theta] + [xi])
Above this line, flexibility decreases over time. Below,
flexibility increases provided inflation is still above zero. The phase
diagram is shown in Figure I. If the parameter [??] is forced to lie
between zero and one, the system will end up in one of a continuum of
steady states. The economy may converge to zero inflation, and then it
will keep the regime at which inflation first hit zero. Alternatively,
it may converge to the fully flexible regime ([??] = 1) and an inflation
rate between zero and [kappa]//([xi]+[zeta]. (10)
(FIGURE I OMITTED]
Figure II displays the results of simulating the dynamic path of a
fictional economy described by our model. The starting point was chosen
to represent a typical situation of a Central European economy at the
beginning of transition with high inflation and a flexible exchange rate
regime. The two panels present cases corresponding to two possible
steady states: a flexible exchange rate regime at low inflation (Panel
a) and a zero inflation at an intermediate regime (Panel b).
Irrespective of the eventual steady state, a notable feature of
transitional dynamics is a dramatic initial decrease in the degree of
exchange rate flexibility, followed by a gradual increase in
flexibility, while inflation decreases monotonically. This kind of
dynamics fits very well the stylized description of the evolution of
exchange rate regimes and inflation in a large number of Central and
Eastern European countries (Koch [1997], Masson [1999]), as well as the
path suggested by prominent western advisors (e.g., Sachs [1996]).
[FIGURE II OMITTED]
IV. Discussion and Limitations of the Model
Certainly a simple model cannot capture all the complexity
surrounding the issue of exchange rate policy. In this section we will
try to address the most obvious questions that arise vis-a-vis the
model.
Credibility
The model does not distinguish between credible and incredible
policy announcements. The exchange rate rule is assumed to be known to
the public and followed by the government. In reality, public
pronouncements are not always reliable, and rules are not always obeyed.
While recognizing the importance of the issue of credibility, we
circumvented it in our model so that we could focus in a tractable way
on the central point of the argument: the conflict between the internal
and external balance, or the trade-of-between inflation and real
appreciation. To a degree, imperfect credibility of exchange-rate
announcements is captured in backward indexation of wage contracts.
Choice of policy rule
An important question is how one can quantify exchange-rate policy
to move from description to a tractable model, while still reflecting
the multitude of possible arrangements. The prevalent answer is to
reduce the diversity to just two regimes. Most commonly, the countries
are assumed to face a choice between a flexible regime and a fixed
regime with (Edwards, 1996) or without (Devereux and Engel, 1998) the
possibility of devaluation or abandoning the peg. Occasionally, some
version of a managed float is pitted against a peg, immutable or not
(Collins, 1996). This dichotomy serves poorly our objective of
accounting for the tremendous diversity of exchange rate arrangements in
Central and Eastern Europe and tracing the evolution of exchange rate
regimes within individual countries, which we read as a history of
mostly marginal adjustments with occasional sharp breaks. Conceptually,
we much prefer a continuous measure of exchange rate regime, even though
for an empirical implementation we will have to go to a cruder scale.
(11)
The question still remains, of course, whether this particular
continuous variable is an adequate representation of exchange-rate
regime. The policy variable f was defined as the fraction of the
previous period's inflation that the monetary authority was willing
to accommodate through devaluation. Certainly, no country formulates its
foreign exchange policy by announcing its [??]. The actual choices may
include using foreign currency as legal tender; introducing a currency
board; announcing a peg to a foreign currency or a basket of currencies
in a less rigid way; announcing a crawling peg with a particular rate of
crawl; specifying a fluctuation band; combining the latter two
arrangements in a crawling band; a managed float without specifying (or
committing to) an exchange rate target; or an independent float. One
would hardly dispute associating [??] = 0 with a peg or a currency
board. A value of [??] between zero and one can be thought of as
describing a crawling peg. Of course, in the actual crawling pegs, the
rate of crawl is specified directly rather than as a fraction of past
inflation, but the correspondence is fairly close. One just has to be
careful not to interpret a reduction in the rate of crawl, as inflation
declines, as a change in regime. What crawling pegs attempt to achieve
is to provide a nominal anchor (pre-announced path of the exchange rate)
to focus inflationary expectations while accommodating inflation
inertia. What differentiates crawling pegs is how aggressive they are in
their anti-inflationary stance, which means how small the rate of crawl
is relative to inflation registered in the past.
The correspondence between the model and reality is much looser
when one brings wide currency bands or floating regimes into the
picture. In the model, the path of the exchange rate is always
pre-announced. In the discussion, we have associated higher values of
[??] with a greater degree of flexibility. The logic for this assignment
is that in the real world (at least in transitional economies during the
initial stabilization), a lower degree of exchange rate flexibility is
typically associated with a tougher stance on inflation, at the risk of
allowing real appreciation. In the model, this stance is conveyed by a
lower [??].
Aggregate demand management
In the original Edwards [1993] model, inflation could be brought
down without using the exchange rate as a nominal anchor. Instead, the
authorities could suppress aggregate demand, which would be reflected in
a negative [z.sub.t] term in equation (7). Our neglect of this term
amounts to assuming that countries that pre-announce the path of the
exchange rate conduct policies consistent with maintaining this path. In
addition, given our interpretation of [??] as a degree of exchange rate
flexibility, we are presuming that countries that opt for a flexible
regime do not try to bring inflation down through other means.
Certainly neither of the assumptions is true in every case, but
individual deviations would be captured in the error term, and we do not
expect the deviations to have a systematic pattern. First, for reasons
noted in the introduction, money-based stabilization programs have
rarely been attempted in Central and Eastern Europe. Slovenia may be a
major exception, but even there the exchange rate was not allowed to
float freely. Secondly, it has been noted that among the transitional
economies of Central and Eastern Europe, those with more sound fiscal
policies tended to adopt a pegged exchange rate (Begg, 1998). Whether
the reason for that correlation is that less disciplined countries
realized that exchange rate pegs would not be sustainable and did not
even try to launch such an infeasible regime, or whether the story of a
fixed exchange rate tying government's hands has some validity,
this fact allows us to use the exchange rate regime as a sufficient
statistic for government policy and reduces the decision making of the
government to a uni-dimensional problem. On the other hand, it is
extremely important to ascertain which story is the right one before
attempting to formulate the government's problem, since if the
decision concerning the choice of exchange rate regime is driven by the
state of public finances, rather than the other way around, this would
impose a constraint on the government that is not recognized in our
model. Romania may be a case in point. It is a high-inflation country
that should have embarked on an exchange-rate based stabilization
program according to the model, but it has continually been unable to
muster the necessary macroeconomic discipline, which in particular has
been reflected in a sorrowful state of public finances. One may easily
question institutional capacity in other Southern European countries.
Still, on the whole, in Central and Eastern Europe macroeconomic
policies appear to be relatively consistent and governance is adequate
compared to countries further east, where the application of the model
would seem to be unwarranted.
Currency boards
One would be right to argue that a currency board is a type of
exchange-rate regime quite different from a simple peg. The principal
difference is the degree of institutional commitment to maintaining the
peg and the consequent difficulty of changing the regime, which is much
greater under a currency board. This translates into an empirical fact
that currency boards are much more stable than other regimes. In
particular, no country in Central and Eastern Europe has ever revoked
this arrangement. (12) The model would handle the introduction of a
currency board, which follows an episode of high inflation, as
decreasing the rate of crawl, [??], to zero and a rise in the cost of
changing the exchange rate regime, m. A sharp increase in m is a natural
way in the model to capture what is special about a currency board--the
institutional difficulty of changing this arrangement, which will
generate, albeit somewhat tautologically, the persistence of such a
regime (both in real life and in the model). What the model does not
explain is why some countries choose ordinary pegs in the face of high
inflation while others go all the way to currency boards.
V. Empirical Analysis
The purpose of this section is to demonstrate the validity of the
model by comparing its predictions with the actual behavior of exchange
rate regimes. We use panel data for the years 1990-98 for 13 Central and
Eastern European transitional economies: Albania, Bulgaria, Croatia, the
Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Poland,
Romania, Slovakia, and Slovenia. This exhausts the list of countries in
the region for which adequate data are available. The year 1990 is taken
to be the starting year of the economic transformation in the region.
Before that, the developments were mostly on the political front and
centered on demonopolizing political power and gaining de facto independence from the Soviet Union. The foreign exchange regimes were
largely unreformed, and currencies were not convertible. Of course, not
all of the countries existed in 1990, so for them the series start with
independence.
The most serious conceptual difficulty to overcome when testing the
model against the data is finding an appropriate proxy for the dependent
variable. The first conceptual peril, as discussed above, is to
associate the policy parameter, f, in the model with the degree of
exchange rate flexibility. Once this leap of faith is made, the
remaining steps are classifying the existing regimes into a number of
categories and arranging the categories in the order of increasing
flexibility.
We mostly rely on the IMF's publications to classify exchange
rate regimes. The monthly issues of International Financial Statistics
feature a table of exchange rate arrangements. Until 1999, this
classification contained three categories relevant for Central and
Eastern European economies: pegged to a currency or a basket of
currencies; managed float; independent float. We use the IMF classification as of December 31 of a given year and assign the value of
0, 1, or 2, respectively, to the dependent variable for the three
regimes. The variable increases with the degree of flexibility.
This classification is quite coarse, and we have constructed an
alternative coding for the dependent variable based on our reading of
the IMF's reports on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange
Restrictions, as well as on the Economist Intelligence Unit's
Country Profiles and Country Reports. The coding, in the order of
increasing flexibility, is: 0- currency board; 1--peg; 2--crawling peg;
3--band; 4--crawling band; 5--managed float; 6--independent float. This
classification is essentially the format currently used in the
International Financial Statistics. While this classification scheme is
much richer than the first one, its disadvantage is that the coding has
been done by the author and hence may reflect some subjective bias. In
any case, the two variables are highly correlated, and the empirical
results turn out to be quite similar.
The main explanatory variables are the lagged value of the
dependent variables, the rate of inflation, and inflation squared. The
model suggests a nonlinear relationship between these and the dependent
variable. Estimating a nonlinear equation presents high demands on the
data and is hardly justified since the exact functional form depends on
the specification of the loss function and is unlikely to be robust. The
main message that we take from the model is that the desired degree of
exchange rate flexibility first increases and then decreases with
inflation. The exchange rate regimes are "sticky" and are not
readily changed. The spirit of the model will be retained by simply
putting a linear combination of the three explanatory variables on the
right hand side.
Of course, the parameters of the economy and the weights in the
loss function may change from country to country. Smaller foreign
reserves would make a country more wary about real appreciation, so k in
the loss function increases, or s* becomes more negative, or both, and
the country will prefer a more flexible regime for any given rate of
inflation. Similarly, higher unemployment may increase the target for
output growth and make a country more averse to real appreciation, which
would translate into a more flexible arrangement. More engagement in
international trade corresponds to a greater a in the model. As the
analysis indicates, at low levels of inflation a country heavily
involved in trade will favor a fixed exchange rate regime, but it may
prefer more flexibility when the inflation rate is high and when a fixed
exchange rate would lead to a loss of competitiveness. To test this
hypothesis, total trade (exports plus imports) as a share of GDP is
included in the regression as a separate variable and interacted with
inflation.
The authorities of countries saddled with large external debt tend
to be wary of devaluation of their currency, as it would increase the
debt burden expressed in domestic currency. On the other hand, servicing
the debt requires earning foreign exchange, which is easier when the
economy is more competitive. Given this trade-off, it is difficult to
tell exactly how high external debt ratios would influence the
"preferred" level of the exchange rate. What seems to happen
in practice is that the first argument prevails for some time, as
policymakers cling to the old exchange rate for fear of creating balance
sheet problems, but eventually balance-of-payments difficulties arise,
and the currency is allowed to depreciate. It should also be noticed
that large step devaluations may occur without a change in the exchange
rate regime (e.g., under an adjustable peg). Alternatively, devaluations
are frequently associated with changes in the exchange regime, but not
with a particular direction of the change. Indeed, countries commonly
fix the exchange rate at a level more depreciated than the pre-existing
floating rate, while a transition from a peg to a float often occurs
under speculative pressure, which leads to depreciation as soon as the
currency is floated. Because of this, we cannot predict the direction in
which external indebtedness would influence the exchange-rate regime,
but we include the ratio of external debt to GDP in the analysis to
investigate the matter empirically.
Tables I and II give summary statistics for the sample for the
baseline regression. The data for all non-categorical variables come
from the International Financial Statistics of the IMF. As we can see,
all three exchange rate regimes distinguished by the IMF are almost
equally represented in the sample, with independent floating occurring
somewhat less frequently than the two other options. The mean inflation
rate in the sample is 68.1 percent per year, which is quite high. At the
same time, the median inflation in the sample is much lower, 22.5
percent. The mean is drawn to the right by relatively rare occurrences
of very high inflation. The countries in the region trade a great deal
with the outside world. There is considerable variation within the
sample in the level of international reserves, which ranges from very
low to quite high magnitudes. So does external debt. The unemployment
rate also varies substantially.
The ordered logit regression results are summarized in Table III.
Our baseline regression (Column 1) includes inflation, inflation
squared, and dummies for lagged regime. There is a considerable degree
of stickiness in exchange rate regime choice, as indicated by a large
and highly statistically significant coefficient on the lagged dependent
variable.
The idea of a nonlinear relationship between the inflation rate and
the degree of exchange rate flexibility is confirmed by the regression.
Both coefficients have the predicted signs and are highly statistically
significant. The pseudo R-squared of 56 percent is fairly decent for
such a parsimonious specification. (13)
The partial relationship between inflation and the degree of
exchange rate flexibility, as given by the baseline regression, peaks at
the inflation rate of 300 percent per year. When inflation is lower, the
relationship is positive: the probability of choosing a fixed regime
diminishes, and the probability of choosing an independent float rises
if the rate of inflation increases, ceteris paribus. In this range,
external competitiveness is the dominant concern. Above 300 percent per
year, more inflation is more likely to be followed by a tightening of
the exchange regime. Internal stability comes to center stage, and the
exchange rate is used as a nominal anchor.
Table IV shows how the regime would be chosen if inflation and the
previous regime were its only determinants. At low inflation the regime
is likely to remain unchanged, (14) while at very high inflation a peg
becomes the preferred alternative. While these outcomes comply with the
model, the cutoff points are higher than what we had expected. At the
same time, this table traces quite well the experiences of high
inflation countries, as demonstrated by Table V. (15) The table
accurately predicts Romania's drift from a peg to a managed float
and to an independent float, Lithuania staying with its independent
float, Poland staying with a peg, and Bulgaria switching to a fixed
regime developments, or simply about the chances of being reelected. It
might be interesting, however, to see what kind of dynamics the model
implies for inflation and exchange rate regimes over several periods if
the system suffers no major disturbances. Specifically, the following
experiment is performed. We fix the structure of the economy as
described by equations (1) through (6), choose a starting point (initial
exchange rate regime and initial inflation), and let a sequence of
governments, which minimize one-period loss function (11), determine the
time path of the economy. We assume there are no shocks along the way.
Each government will choose the regime [phi] as in (12), given the
regime and the inflation rate it has inherited from the previous
government, and will leave this regime and inflation determined by
(7') as a legacy to its successor.
Equations (7') and (12) determine the time path of inflation
and the exchange- rate rule from any point onward, provided the loss
function does not change and the system is not subject to any shocks. A
phase diagram can be used to analyze the behavior of the system.
Inflation is stationary in two cases: when inflation is zero or
when the exchange rate regime parameter [phi] equals one. If [phi], is
less than one, inflation decreases in period t.
Equation (12) can be manipulated to obtain a change in the degree
of exchange rate flexibility between two periods:
[[phi].sub.t] - [[phi].sub.t-1] = [kappa] + ([theta] -
[zeta])[[pi].sub.t-1] - ([theta] + [xi]) [p.sup.2] [[pi].sub.t-1]
[[phi].sub.t-1] / 1 + ([theta] + [xi])[[pi].sup.2.sub.t-1] /
[[pi].sub.t-1]
The degree of flexibility does not change in two cases: when
inflation is zero or along the downward-sloping line
[phi] = [kappa] / ([theta] + [xi])[pi] + ([theta] - [zeta]) /
([theta] + [xi])
Above this line, flexibility decreases over time. Below,
flexibility increases provided inflation is still above zero. The phase
diagram is shown in Figure I. If the parameter [phi] is forced to lie
between zero and one, the system will end up in one of a continuum of
steady states. The economy may converge to zero inflation, and then it
will keep the regime at which inflation first hit zero. Alternatively,
it may converge to the fully flexible regime ([phi] = 1) and an
inflation rate between zero and [kappa]//([xi]+[zeta]. (10)
[FIGURE I OMITTED]
Figure II displays the results of simulating the dynamic path of a
fictional economy described by our model. The starting point was chosen
to represent a typical situation of a Central European economy at the
beginning of transition with high inflation and a flexible exchange rate
regime. The two panels present cases corresponding to two possible
steady states: a flexible exchange rate regime at low inflation (Panel
a) and a zero inflation at an intermediate regime (Panel b).
Irrespective of the eventual steady state, a notable feature of
transitional dynamics is a dramatic initial decrease in the degree of
exchange rate flexibility, followed by a gradual increase in
flexibility, while inflation decreases monotonically. This kind of
dynamics fits very well the stylized description of the evolution of
exchange rate regimes and inflation in a large number of Central and
Eastern European countries (Koch [1997], Masson [1999]), as well as the
path suggested by prominent western advisors (e.g., Sachs [1996]).
[FIGURE II OMITTED]
IV. Discussion and Limitations of the Model
Certainly a simple model cannot capture all the complexity
surrounding the issue of exchange rate policy. In this section we will
try to address the most obvious questions that arise vis-a-vis the
model.
Credibility
The model does not distinguish between credible and incredible
policy announcements. The exchange rate rule is assumed to be known to
the public and followed by the government. In reality, public
pronouncements are not always reliable, and rules are not always obeyed.
While recognizing the importance of the issue of credibility, we
circumvented it in our model so that we could focus in a tractable way
on the central point of the argument: the conflict between the internal
and external balance, or the trade-of-between inflation and real
appreciation. To a degree, imperfect credibility of exchange-rate
announcements is captured in backward indexation of wage contracts.
Choice of policy rule
An important question is how one can quantify exchange-rate policy
to move from description to a tractable model, while still reflecting
the multitude of possible arrangements. The prevalent answer is to
reduce the diversity to just two regimes. Most commonly, the countries
are assumed to face a choice between a flexible regime and a fixed
regime with (Edwards, 1996) or without (Devereux and Engel, 1998) the
possibility of devaluation or abandoning the peg. Occasionally, some
version of a managed float is pitted against a peg, immutable or not
(Collins, 1996). This dichotomy serves poorly our objective of
accounting for the tremendous diversity of exchange rate arrangements in
Central and Eastern Europe and tracing the evolution of exchange rate
regimes within individual countries, which we read as a history of
mostly marginal adjustments with occasional sharp breaks. Conceptually,
we much prefer a continuous measure of exchange rate regime, even though
for an empirical implementation we will have to go to a cruder scale.
(11)
The question still remains, of course, whether this particular
continuous variable is an adequate representation of exchange-rate
regime. The policy variable f was defined as the fraction of the
previous period's inflation that the monetary authority was willing
to accommodate through devaluation. Certainly, no country formulates its
foreign exchange policy by announcing its [phi]. The actual choices may
include using foreign currency as legal tender; introducing a currency
board; announcing a peg to a foreign currency or a basket of currencies
in a less rigid way; announcing a crawling peg with a particular rate of
crawl; specifying a fluctuation band; combining the latter two
arrangements in a crawling band; a managed float without specifying (or
committing to) an exchange rate target; or an independent float. One
would hardly dispute associating [phi] = 0 with a peg or a currency
board. A value of [phi] between zero and one can be thought of as
describing a crawling peg. Of course, in the actual crawling pegs, the
rate of crawl is specified directly rather than as a fraction of past
inflation, but the correspondence is fairly close. One just has to be
careful not to interpret a reduction in the rate of crawl, as inflation
declines, as a change in regime. What crawling pegs attempt to achieve
is to provide a nominal anchor (pre-announced path of the exchange rate)
to focus inflationary expectations while accommodating inflation
inertia. What differentiates crawling pegs is how aggressive they are in
their anti-inflationary stance, which means how small the rate of crawl
is relative to inflation registered in the past.
The correspondence between the model and reality is much looser
when one brings wide currency bands or floating regimes into the
picture. In the model, the path of the exchange rate is always
pre-announced. In the discussion, we have associated higher values of
[phi] with a greater degree of flexibility. The logic for this
assignment is that in the real world (at least in transitional economies
during the initial stabilization), a lower degree of exchange rate
flexibility is typically associated with a tougher stance on inflation,
at the risk of allowing real appreciation. In the model, this stance is
conveyed by a lower [phi].
Aggregate demand management
In the original Edwards [1993] model, inflation could be brought
down without using the exchange rate as a nominal anchor. Instead, the
authorities could suppress aggregate demand, which would be reflected in
a negative [z.sub.t] term in equation (7). Our neglect of this term
amounts to assuming that countries that pre-announce the path of the
exchange rate conduct policies consistent with maintaining this path. In
addition, given our interpretation of [phi] as a degree of exchange rate
flexibility, we are presuming that countries that opt for a flexible
regime do not try to bring inflation down through other means.
Certainly neither of the assumptions is true in every case, but
individual deviations would be captured in the error term, and we do not
expect the deviations to have a systematic pattern. First, for reasons
noted in the introduction, money-based stabilization programs have
rarely been attempted in Central and Eastern Europe. Slovenia may be a
major exception, but even there the exchange rate was not allowed to
float freely. Secondly, it has been noted that among the transitional
economies of Central and Eastern Europe, those with more sound fiscal
policies tended to adopt a pegged exchange rate (Begg, 1998). Whether
the reason for that correlation is that less disciplined countries
realized that exchange rate pegs would not be sustainable and did not
even try to launch such an infeasible regime, or whether the story of a
fixed exchange rate tying government's hands has some validity,
this fact allows us to use the exchange rate regime as a sufficient
statistic for government policy and reduces the decision making of the
government to a uni-dimensional problem. On the other hand, it is
extremely important to ascertain which story is the right one before
attempting to formulate the government's problem, since if the
decision concerning the choice of exchange rate regime is driven by the
state of public finances, rather than the other way around, this would
impose a constraint on the government that is not recognized in our
model. Romania may be a case in point. It is a high-inflation country
that should have embarked on an exchange-rate based stabilization
program according to the model, but it has continually been unable to
muster the necessary macroeconomic discipline, which in particular has
been reflected in a sorrowful state of public finances. One may easily
question institutional capacity in other Southern European countries.
Still, on the whole, in Central and Eastern Europe macroeconomic
policies appear to be relatively consistent and governance is adequate
compared to countries further east, where the application of the model
would seem to be unwarranted.
Currency boards
One would be right to argue that a currency board is a type of
exchange-rate regime quite different from a simple peg. The principal
difference is the degree of institutional commitment to maintaining the
peg and the consequent difficulty of changing the regime, which is much
greater under a currency board. This translates into an empirical fact
that currency boards are much more stable than other regimes. In
particular, no country in Central and Eastern Europe has ever revoked
this arrangement. (12) The model would handle the introduction of a
currency board, which follows an episode of high inflation, as
decreasing the rate of crawl, [phi], to zero and a rise in the cost of
changing the exchange rate regime, m. A sharp increase in m is a natural
way in the model to capture what is special about a currency board--the
institutional difficulty of changing this arrangement, which will
generate, albeit somewhat tautologically, the persistence of such a
regime (both in real life and in the model). What the model does not
explain is why some countries choose ordinary pegs in the face of high
inflation while others go all the way to currency boards.
V. Empirical Analysis
The purpose of this section is to demonstrate the validity of the
model by comparing its predictions with the actual behavior of exchange
rate regimes. We use panel data for the years 1990-98 for 13 Central and
Eastern European transitional economies: Albania, Bulgaria, Croatia, the
Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Poland,
Romania, Slovakia, and Slovenia. This exhausts the list of countries in
the region for which adequate data are available. The year 1990 is taken
to be the starting year of the economic transformation in the region.
Before that, the developments were mostly on the political front and
centered on demonopolizing political power and gaining de facto
independence from the Soviet Union. The foreign exchange regimes were
largely unreformed, and currencies were not convertible. Of course, not
all of the countries existed in 1990, so for them the series start with
independence.
The most serious conceptual difficulty to overcome when testing the
model against the data is finding an appropriate proxy for the dependent
variable. The first conceptual peril, as discussed above, is to
associate the policy parameter, f, in the model with the degree of
exchange rate flexibility. Once this leap of faith is made, the
remaining steps are classifying the existing regimes into a number of
categories and arranging the categories in the order of increasing
flexibility.
We mostly rely on the IMF's publications to classify exchange
rate regimes. The monthly issues of International Financial Statistics
feature a table of exchange rate arrangements. Until 1999, this
classification contained three categories relevant for Central and
Eastern European economies: pegged to a currency or a basket of
currencies; managed float; independent float. We use the IMF
classification as of December 31 of a given year and assign the value of
0, 1, or 2, respectively, to the dependent variable for the three
regimes. The variable increases with the degree of flexibility.
This classification is quite coarse, and we have constructed an
alternative coding for the dependent variable based on our reading of
the IMF's reports on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange
Restrictions, as well as on the Economist Intelligence Unit's
Country Profiles and Country Reports. The coding, in the order of
increasing flexibility, is: 0- currency board; 1--peg; 2--crawling peg;
3--band; 4--crawling band; 5--managed float; 6--independent float. This
classification is essentially the format currently used in the
International Financial Statistics. While this classification scheme is
much richer than the first one, its disadvantage is that the coding has
been done by the author and hence may reflect some subjective bias. In
any case, the two variables are highly correlated, and the empirical
results turn out to be quite similar.
The main explanatory variables are the lagged value of the
dependent variables, the rate of inflation, and inflation squared. The
model suggests a nonlinear relationship between these and the dependent
variable. Estimating a nonlinear equation presents high demands on the
data and is hardly justified since the exact functional form depends on
the specification of the loss function and is unlikely to be robust. The
main message that we take from the model is that the desired degree of
exchange rate flexibility first increases and then decreases with
inflation. The exchange rate regimes are "sticky" and are not
readily changed. The spirit of the model will be retained by simply
putting a linear combination of the three explanatory variables on the
right hand side.
Of course, the parameters of the economy and the weights in the
loss function may change from country to country. Smaller foreign
reserves would make a country more wary about real appreciation, so k in
the loss function increases, or s* becomes more negative, or both, and
the country will prefer a more flexible regime for any given rate of
inflation. Similarly, higher unemployment may increase the target for
output growth and make a country more averse to real appreciation, which
would translate into a more flexible arrangement. More engagement in
international trade corresponds to a greater a in the model. As the
analysis indicates, at low levels of inflation a country heavily
involved in trade will favor a fixed exchange rate regime, but it may
prefer more flexibility when the inflation rate is high and when a fixed
exchange rate would lead to a loss of competitiveness. To test this
hypothesis, total trade (exports plus imports) as a share of GDP is
included in the regression as a separate variable and interacted with
inflation.
The authorities of countries saddled with large external debt tend
to be wary of devaluation of their currency, as it would increase the
debt burden expressed in domestic currency. On the other hand, servicing
the debt requires earning foreign exchange, which is easier when the
economy is more competitive. Given this trade-off, it is difficult to
tell exactly how high external debt ratios would influence the
"preferred" level of the exchange rate. What seems to happen
in practice is that the first argument prevails for some time, as
policymakers cling to the old exchange rate for fear of creating balance
sheet problems, but eventually balance-of-payments difficulties arise,
and the currency is allowed to depreciate. It should also be noticed
that large step devaluations may occur without a change in the exchange
rate regime (e.g., under an adjustable peg). Alternatively, devaluations
are frequently associated with changes in the exchange regime, but not
with a particular direction of the change. Indeed, countries commonly
fix the exchange rate at a level more depreciated than the pre-existing
floating rate, while a transition from a peg to a float often occurs
under speculative pressure, which leads to depreciation as soon as the
currency is floated. Because of this, we cannot predict the direction in
which external indebtedness would influence the exchange-rate regime,
but we include the ratio of external debt to GDP in the analysis to
investigate the matter empirically.
Tables I and II give summary statistics for the sample for the
baseline regression. The data for all non-categorical variables come
from the International Financial Statistics of the IMF. As we can see,
all three exchange rate regimes distinguished by the IMF are almost
equally represented in the sample, with independent floating occurring
somewhat less frequently than the two other options. The mean inflation
rate in the sample is 68.1 percent per year, which is quite high. At the
same time, the median inflation in the sample is much lower, 22.5
percent. The mean is drawn to the right by relatively rare occurrences
of very high inflation. The countries in the region trade a great deal
with the outside world. There is considerable variation within the
sample in the level of international reserves, which ranges from very
low to quite high magnitudes. So does external debt. The unemployment
rate also varies substantially.
The ordered logit regression results are summarized in Table III.
Our baseline regression (Column 1) includes inflation, inflation
squared, and dummies for lagged regime. There is a considerable degree
of stickiness in exchange rate regime choice, as indicated by a large
and highly statistically significant coefficient on the lagged dependent
variable.
The idea of a nonlinear relationship between the inflation rate and
the degree of exchange rate flexibility is confirmed by the regression.
Both coefficients have the predicted signs and are highly statistically
significant. The pseudo R-squared of 56 percent is fairly decent for
such a parsimonious specification. (13)
The partial relationship between inflation and the degree of
exchange rate flexibility, as given by the baseline regression, peaks at
the inflation rate of 300 percent per year. When inflation is lower, the
relationship is positive: the probability of choosing a fixed regime
diminishes, and the probability of choosing an independent float rises
if the rate of inflation increases, ceteris paribus. In this range,
external competitiveness is the dominant concern. Above 300 percent per
year, more inflation is more likely to be followed by a tightening of
the exchange regime. Internal stability comes to center stage, and the
exchange rate is used as a nominal anchor.
Table IV shows how the regime would be chosen if inflation and the
previous regime were its only determinants. At low inflation the regime
is likely to remain unchanged, (14) while at very high inflation a peg
becomes the preferred alternative. While these outcomes comply with the
model, the cutoff points are higher than what we had expected. At the
same time, this table traces quite well the experiences of high
inflation countries, as demonstrated by Table V. (15) The table
accurately predicts Romania's drift from a peg to a managed float
and to an independent float, Lithuania staying with its independent
float, Poland staying with a peg, and Bulgaria switching to a fixed
regime after its hyperinflation. In the cases of Albania in 1991 and
Bulgaria in 1993, the model predicts a move from a fixed regime to
managed floating, while the countries actually moved all the way to
independent floating; these are the only discrepancies between predicted
and actual outcomes. Still, it must be acknowledged that, while the
model describes reasonably well, the behavior of the economies to the
right of the "hump" of the regression curve, the experiences
of the bulk of the economies are in the area to the left of the hump. In
that sense one may say that the existence of concavity in the
relationship between exchange rate flexibility and inflation is more
firmly established by the evidence presented here than the fact that the
slope of the relationship actually turns from positive to negative in
the empirically relevant range.
When added to the baseline, the other control variables enter the
regression with expected signs. The coefficient on the ratio of
international reserves to M2 is negative and statistically significant.
Economies with higher unemployment choose to have more flexible regimes,
but the quantitative effect is quite small and statistically significant
only at the 20 percent level. Openness to trade does not seem to be a
major factor affecting the choice of exchange rate regime. The
coefficient on trade is negative, and the coefficient on the interaction
term between trade and inflation is positive, which is consistent with
the model, but neither coefficient is statistically significant. The
coefficient on the ratio of external debt to GDP turns out positive and
statistically significant. (16) Apparently, countries with a high level
of external indebtedness opt for flexible regimes, which tend to be
associated with greater external competitiveness and facilitate earning
foreign exchange necessary for servicing the debt. Throughout these
exercises, the coefficients on previous regime dummies, inflation, and
inflation squared change fairly little and retain high statistical
significance. (17)
A potential problem with these regressions is endogeneity of the
explanatory variables. In particular, inflation can certainly be
affected by the choice of the exchange rate regime; this is both common
wisdom and an empirical regularity, (18) as well as an important premise
of the model. In the model, the exchange regime is determined on the
basis of what inflation was in the past, and in the data the realization
of inflation, calculated on the basis of average prices in a given year
and in the preceding year, antedates the realization of the regime,
taken at the beginning of the next year. This timing solves the problem
of causality. The persistence of both the regressors and the dependent
variable does not necessarily imply a bias in the results, since we
explicitly control for the persistence of the regime in the regressions
by including a lagged value of the dependent variable. As long as the
functional form is correct and the disturbances themselves are not
serially correlated, the regressors (lagged regime and inflation) will
not be correlated with the disturbances, so the timing resolves the
problem of simultaneity. Still, it would be comforting to find an
appropriate instrument for inflation that would be highly correlated
with the inflation rate and arguably uncorrelated with the future choice
of the regime.
As noted in the introduction, all transition economies in Central
and Eastern Europe experienced major inflationary shocks when they
liberalized their price systems. We use a change in the index of
liberalization of internal markets developed by de Melo et al. [1996].
The index reflects the authors' judgment, informed by country
reports and expert opinions, on the extent of liberalization of domestic
prices and abolition of state trading monopolies. It ranges from zero to
one, with a 0.1 gradation, and increases with liberalization. The index
is available for all the countries in our sample for the years 1989-94.
(19) As Column 1 of Table VI indicates, the baseline regression in this
subsample looks similar to the one for the entire sample (Cf. Table III,
Column 1). (20)
Our measure of liberalization is simply the difference in the
liberalization index between two consecutive years. A sharper change in
this index would have a more dramatic impact on prices, so this change
should be correlated with inflation. Indeed, the correlation coefficient is 0.52. To be sure, price liberalization is not the only reason for
inflation, but it is an important one. On the other hand, the decision
to liberalize prices is presumably independent of the exchange rate
regime. Hence, this variable is a promising instrument. As the
regressions include both inflation and its square, we need two
instruments. We obtain a second instrument simply by squaring the change
in the liberalization index.
Instrument variable estimation results are presented in the second
column of Table VI. Compared with the simple regression, we lose some
explanatory power. All the coefficients still have the expected signs
and remain statistically significant. The absolute values of the
coefficients on the two inflation terms approximately treble. We take
this as a confirmation of our story. When only the exogenous components
of inflation are considered, the reaction to inflation looks even
sharper.
Table VII contains the results of fixed effects estimation. One
might posit that each country has inherent characteristics that barely
move over time. These might determine the choice of regime, and all the
action we get in our regression comes from the lagged regime term, which
captures these characteristics. If this were true, all the explanatory
variables would have been rendered insignificant by an inclusion of
country fixed effects. In fact, the nonlinear relationship between
inflation and the choice of regime is still there when country fixed
effects are included (Column 2). We get the same story from
intra-country temporal variation that we get from the full panel.
Controlling for year fixed effects (Column 3) does not change the
picture either. This means that the assumption that disturbances are
uncorrelated across countries in a given year is not crucial. Adding
both country and year fixed effects (Column 4) still does not disturb
the main message of the model.
Finally, we estimate the relationships above using our own
codification of the degree of exchange rate flexibility rather than
relying on the IMF's classification. This scheme has seven
gradations, which are, in the order of increasing flexibility: a
currency board, a conventional peg, a crawling peg, a horizontal band, a
crawling band, a managed float, and an independent float. We assigned
regimes to individual observations on the basis of the IMF's
reports on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions as well as
Country Reports and Country Profiles by the Economist Intelligence Unit.
The Pearson correlation coefficient between this and the IMF's
measures of exchange rate flexibility is 0.81, and the Spearman rank
correlation coefficient is 0.85.
Not surprisingly, the results are quite close to those obtained
using the IMF classification. These regressions appear in Table VIII.
The story on the importance of previous regime and inflation for the
choice of the regime holds in this specification. The availability of
foreign exchange reserves and the rate of unemployment influence the
choice in the predicted way, but the former is only marginally
significant and the latter is statistically insignificant. The level of
trade openness does not seem to affect the choice of the regime.
The main message that we take from this regression exercise is that
the nominal anchor versus the competitiveness tradeoff can be traced
quite well in the choice of exchange-rate regimes in transition
economies. In addition, exchange-rate regimes are shown to be sticky.
This fact is obvious, but it is usually implicitly attributed to the
stickiness of the variables underlying the choice, and the inclusion of
a lagged dependent variable on the right-hand-side (motivated by
institutional costs of adjustment) is rare in the literature. (21)
Other controls, such as foreign exchange reserves and the rate of
unemployment, behave mostly in the predicted way. Countries with less
international reserves are less likely to peg, as it is more difficult
for them to peg. Countries with high unemployment want more room for
expansionary policies and are less willing to sacrifice flexibility for
low inflation. Openness to trade does not seem to affect the choice once
we control for lagged regime and inflation.
VI. Conclusion
In this article we have developed a model of exchange rate regime
determination which emphasizes the tradeoff between the use of the
exchange rate to promote external competitiveness and its use to promote
domestic price stability. This tradeoff is relevant for transition
economies which have been subject to numerous inflationary shocks. The
main implication of the model is that the relationship between the rate
of inflation and the degree of exchange rate flexibility is expected to
be nonlinear. A rise in inflation from a low level would call for more
flexible arrangement. On the other hand, an increase in already high
inflation would call for fixing the exchange rate.
I have tested this hypothesis on a sample of 13 transition
economies for the years 1990-98. Ordered logit regressions confirm the
main implication: the terms on inflation and its square have predicted
signs and are highly statistically significant. The model has also
passed a number of robustness checks, such as instrumental variable
estimation, inclusion of country and year dummies, addition of other
explanatory variables, truncation of the sample, and estimation using
alternative coding for the dependent variable. After controlling for
inflation, exchange rate regimes have been found to be highly
persistent. The propensity to fix the exchange rate is weakened by low
levels of international reserves with respect to broad money and by high
unemployment.
While the model demonstrates the working of the exchange rate
regime tradeoff, and the empirical results are supportive, the next
challenge is to incorporate fiscal policy in the framework for analyzing
inflation and exchange rate policy.
Appendix
Brief History of Exchange Arrangements in Central and
Eastern Europe (1990-1998)
Country Brief History
Albania The exchange rate for the lek is determined on the
basis of supply and demand for foreign exchange.
Bulgaria The lev became internally convertible in 1991.
A currency board was introduced in July 1997,
pegging the lev to the DM.
Croatia The exchange rate of the kuna is determined in the
interbank foreign exchange market. The National Bank
of Croatia may set intervention exchange rates to
level undue fluctuations in the exchange rate.
Czech Republic The koruna was pegged to a USD/DM combination in a
narrow band in 1993.
The band was broadened to 7.5% in 1996.
The koruna was devalued and floated in 1997.
Estonia The kroon has been pegged to the DM in a currency
board system since 1992.
Hungary The central rate of the forint was formally pegged
to a basket (whose composition varied) in 1989, but
5% fluctuations were allowed and frequent
compensatory devaluations were taking place. A policy
of preannounced monthly devaluations has been
followed since May 1995.
Latvia Latvia gradually passed from the Russian ruble
through the Latvian rublis to the Latvian lats,
which became the sole legal tender in October 1993.
Since February 1994, the lats has been pegged
informally to the SDR.
Lithuania Similar transition from the ruble through the talonas
to the litas. In April 1994 a currency board was
introduced, pegging the litas to the USD.
Macedonia The National Bank of Macedonia participates in the
wholesale foreign exchange market to maintain the
value of the denar against the DM at a level that
would meet balance of payments objectives.
Poland The zloty was pegged to the USD in January 1990. In
May 1991, the zloty was devalued and pegged to a
basket. In October 1991, a preannounced crawling peg
was introduced, with occasional step devaluations.
The fluctuation margin was widened to 2% in March
1995, 7% in May 1995, and 10% in February 1998.
Romania The exchange rate for the leu was unified in
November 1991. Still, the rationing of hard currency
occurs and controls are applied to the markets for
foreign exchange. Full internal convertibility of
the leu was introduced on January 30, 1998.
Slovakia From July 1994 to October 1998 the koruna was pegged
to a combination of the USD and the DM. The initial
fluctuation band of 1.5% was widened to 3% in
January 1996, 5% in July 1996, and 7% in January
1997. On October 2, 1998 the currency basket and
the fluctuation band were abolished.
Slovenia The tolar has been floating since its introduction in
October 1991. The central bank interferes in the
foreign exchange market with the objective of
stabilizing the real exchange rate.
Table Ia
Exchange Rate Regime--IMF Classification
O-fixed; 1-managed floating; 2-independently floating
Regime Frequency Percent
0 30 34.88
1 33 38.37
2 23 26.74
Total 86 100.00
Table Ib
Exchange Rate Regime--Author's Classification
0-currency board; 1 -peg; 2-crawling peg; 3-band; 4-crawling band;
5-managed float; 6-independent float
Flex Frequency Percent
0 13 15.12
1 16 18.60
2 8 9.30
3 3 3.49
4 4 4.65
5 20 23.26
6 22 25.58
Total 86 100.00
Table II
Continuous Variables--Summary Statistics
Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
inflation 86 68.1 143.8 0.50 1082.60
trade_ratio 60 0.924 0.349 0.327 1.679
unempl 57 9.26 3.56 3.0 16.5
res_m2 81 0.348 0.189 0.035 1.235
debt_ratio 86 0.432 0.315 0.045 1.605
inflation--year-on-year percentage increase in the CPI
trade_ratio--(exports+imports/GDP)
unempl--year average unemployment rate, percent
res_m2--international reserves / M2 , end of year
debt_ratio--external debt/GDP
Table III
Ordered Logit Estimation
Dependent variable--degree of exchange rate flexibility according to
the IMF
Regressor 1 2 3
Reg_pr=1 dummy 4.19 4.83 3.90
(5.10) (4.92) (3.81)
Reg_pr=2 dummy 6.67 7.37 6.36
(6.21) (5.91) (4.43)
Inflation 0.0440 0.0329 0.0499
(3.97) (2.88) (3.52)
Inflation Squared -0.0000733 -0.0000545 -0.0000830
(-3.37) (-2.46) (-3.03)
Foreign Reserves -- -3.81 --
(-2.12)
Unemployment -- -- 0.173
(1.32)
Trade Ratio -- -- --
Trade*Inflation -- -- --
Debt Ratio -- -- --
Number of Observ 86 81 57
Pseudo R-squared 0.56 0.59 0.60
Regressor 4 5
Reg_pr=1 dummy 4.42 5.21
(3.98) (5.09)
Reg_pr=2 dummy 7.94 8.69
(4.53) (5.59)
Inflation 0.0506 0.0390
(1.72) (3.70)
Inflation Squared -0.0000954 -0.0000722
(-2.61) (-3.25)
Foreign Reserves -- --
Unemployment -- --
Trade Ratio -0.842 --
(-0.49)
Trade*Inflation 0.00923 --
(0.37)
Debt Ratio -- 5.02
(2.93)
Number of Observ 60 86
Pseudo R-squared 0.67 0.63
z-statistics in parentheses
Table IV
Ordered Logit Estimation--Predicted Distribution
Regime--degree of exchange rate flexibility according to the IMF
Previous Regime
New Fixed
Regime
Fixed [pi]<69.2; [pi]>531.6
MF 69.2<[pi]<531.6
IF --
Previous Regime
New Managed Float Independent Float
Regime
Fixed [pi]>633.0 >680.5
MF [pi]<83.7; 517.1<[pi]<633.0 [pi]<16.1; 584.7<[pi]<680.5
IF 83.7<[pi]<517.1 16.1<[pi]<584.7
Table V
Outcomes for High Inflation Countries
Regime--degree of exchange rate flexibility according to the IMF
Regime
Country Year Inflation Previous Predicted Actual
Romania 1992 211 1 2 2
Albania 1992 226 0 1 2
Romania 1991 231 0 1 1
Romania 1993 255 2 2 2
Bulgaria 1991 339 0 1 2
Lithuania 1993 410 2 2 2
Poland 1990 555 0 0 0
Bulgaria 1997 1083 2 0 0
Table VI
Instrumental Variable Estimation
Dependent variable--degree of exchange rate flexibility according to
the IMF Instruments--change in price liberalization index, square of
change in price liberalization index
Sample--1990-94
Regressor 1 2
Ordered Logit IV
Previous Regime = MF 3.84 3.74
(2.66) (2.83)
Previous Regime = IF 5.05 6.19
(3.41) (4.05)
Inflation 0.0474 0.1444
(3.20) (2.03)
Inflation Squared -0.0000786 -0.0002507
(-2.79) (-1.91)
Number of Observations 34 34
Pseudo R-squared 0.55 0.47
z-statistics in parentheses
Table VII
Fixed Effect Estimation
Dependent variable--degree of exchange rate flexibility according
to the IMF
regressor 1 2
Baseline Country FE
previous regime = MF 4.19 627
(5.10) (3.24)
previous regime = IF 6.67 9.30
(6.21) (3.93)
inflation 0.0440 0.0736
(3.97) (3.65)
inflation squared -0.0000733 -0.000119
(-3.37) (-3.44)
number of observations 86 86
Pseudo R-squared 0.56 0.71
regressor 3 4
Year FE Country and
Year FE
previous regime = MF 4.39 6.24
(4.95) (2.90)
previous regime = IF 7.55 10.06
(6.02) (3.67)
inflation 0.0425 0.0784
(2.91) (3.09)
inflation squared -0.0000713 -0.0001285
(-2.51) (-2.79)
number of observations 86 86
Pseudo R-squared 0.59 0.73
z-statistics in parentheses
Table VIII
Ordered Logit Estimation
Dependent variable--author's classification of exchange rate regimes.
Regressors include dummies for categories: peg; CP--crawling peg;
HB--horizontal band; CB--crawling band; MF--managed float;
IF--independent float. Omitted category--currency board.
regressor 1 2 3 4
Prev. Regime=peg 4.97 4.08 5.77 4.28
(3.77) (3.00) (2.91) (3.09)
Prev. Regime=CP 6.38 5.49 7.68 5.37
(4.37) (3.35) (3.20) (3.34)
Prev. Regime=HB 9.13 8.24 10.79 8.10
(4.97) (4.31) (4.61) (3.98)
Prev. Regime=DB 7.97 7.53 9.65 7.29
(4.80) (4.47) (3.65) (4.07)
Prev. Regime=MF 9.62 9.76 11.05 8.04
(6.06) (5.90) (5.07) (4.62)
Prev. Regime=IF 13.3 13.55 15.36 12.15
(7.31) (6.82) (5.09) (5.57)
Inflation 0.0238 0.0145 0.0243 0.0224
(2.10) (2.15) (1.57) (1.63)
Inflation Squared -0.0000413 -0.0000253 -0.0000507 -0.0000376
(-1.87) (-2.53) (-2.35) (-1.44)
Foreign Reserves -- -2.87 -- --
(-1.58)
Trade Ratio -- -- 0.112 --
(0.06)
Trade*Inflation -- -- 0.0123 --
(0.70)
Unemployment -- -- -- 0.0908
(0.86)
Number of Observ 86 81 60 57
Pseudo R-squared 0.49 0.53 0.53 0.45
z-statistics in parentheses
Notes
(1.) Unlike the previous factors, which are essentially
transitional and almost exogenous, fiscal laxity reflects the policy
stance. As such, it may be the source of persistent inflationary
pressure, particularly if the deficits are financed by borrowing from
the banking system. If that is the case, the choice of the nominal
anchor is largely irrelevant, as no anchor can be consistent with fiscal
profligacy, except in the very short run. The focus of this article is
on fighting transitional inflation in the presence of inertial elements.
Extending the model to a situation where the government keeps adding
fuel to the inflationary fire is a matter for future research.
(2.) Of course, output declined in all CEE countries in early years
of transition regardless of the choice of exchange rate regime. There
are numerous "structural" reasons for this "transition
recession." Still, a liquidity squeeze imposed by a money-based
stabilization would smother production further. Fischer et al (1996)
find a positive impact of a fixed exchange rate regime on real GDP
growth in transition economies.
(3.) These models take root in the closed-economy literature
looking at optimal conduct of monetary policy in the face of a trade-off
between inflation and unemployment (e.g., Barro and Gordon [1983]).
(4.) Uncertainty in these models comes from terms of trade shocks.
(5.) The shortness of policymaker horizons is posited because of
the difficulty of political and economic forecasting far into the future
during transition and because of the fairly short average tenure of
governments in the countries of Central and Eastern Europe (see, e.g.,
EBRD [1999, Chart 5.6]).
(6.) I am following Edwards in identifying the real exchange rate
with the product wage in the tradable sector (or, equivalently, with the
wage in dollars). Nothing of substance would change if I defined it as
the ratio of nontradable to tradable prices. With this definition, the
rate of real appreciation would equal
[s.sub.t] = [[pi].sub.Nt] - [[pi].sub.Tt] = [gamma](1 - [phi]) x
[epsilon] / ([eta] + [epsilon][alpha] + [epsilon](1 - [alpha]) [gamma]
[[pi].sub.t-1]
which is nearly identical to equation (10).
(7.) One might argue that as the countries of Central and Eastern
Europe are catching up in terms of income with the western world, their
currencies should experience equilibrium real appreciation, and s*>
might be a reasonable target. It should be noted, however, that the loss
function is attached to a model of the economy which does not
incorporate such equilibrium real appreciation. One could allow for such
appreciation by assuming [z.sub.t] to be positive in equation (4').
In that case inflation and real appreciation would be greater than the
magnitudes given by equations (7') and (10), respectively. Hence,
s, given by (10), can be seen as real appreciation on top of the
equilibrium one.
(8.) d[[phi].sub.t] / d[[pi].sub.t-1] = [kappa] - 2[[zeta] -
[theta]) + ([xi] + [theta]) [[phi].sub.t-1] - [kappa]([xi] +
[theta])[[pi].sup.2.sub.t-1] / [[1 + ([xi] +
[theta])[[pi].sup.2.sub.t-1]].sup.2]
This expression is positive when [[pi].sub.t-1] is small, negative
when [[pi].sub.t-1] is large, and it has one positive root.
(9.) If [[phi].sub.t-1] + [kappa][[pi].sub.t-1] -
[zeta][[pi].sup.2.sub.t-1] > 1 + [xi][[pi].sup.2.sub.t-1] then higher
e will lead to less exchange rate flexibility.
(10.) When inflation is above zero but below [kappa]/([xi] +
[zeta], the desired degree of exchange rate flexibility, [phi], is
greater than 1, so it is the constraint 0 [is less than or equal to]
[phi] [is less than or equal to] 1 that makes this whole segment a locus
of possible steady states. If this constraint is removed, possible
steady states are the whole horizontal axes (zero inflation) plus the
point [phi] (= 1, [pi] = [kappa]([xi] + [zeta]). The path toward the
latter steady state may look like a spiral.
(11.) For most authors the problem is just the opposite--the
available characterization of exchange rate regimes is too detailed for
them, and they have to decide how to aggregate across categories in
order to create a dichotomous measure for testing their theories.
(12.) Currency boards have been established in Estonia (1992),
Lithuania (1994), Bulgaria (1997), and Bosnia (1998). Lithuania pegged
its currency to the US dollar, while the three other countries pegged to
the deutsche mark.
(13.) Adding the two inflation terms to a regression of regime on
the two previous regime dummies increases the pseudo R-squared by 17
percentage points and log likelihood by 16 units.
(14.) The right-hand side of the regression equation at zero
inflation is just below the high cutoff point (and well within
estimation errors) when the previous regime is an independent float, so
16.1 in the bottom right cell of the table is statistically
indistinguishable from zero.
(15.) Arbitrarily defined here as countries having inflation over
200 percent per annum.
(16.) This is true regardless of the exchange rate used for
conversion (end-of-period or period average). The result does not change
if the ratio of external debt to exports is used.
(17.) Change is more pronounced when trade is included in the
regression because of the interaction term.
(18.) See, for example, Fischer et al. [1996] or Ghosh et al.
[1997].
(19.) Since 1994, a similar index has been produced by the European
Bank for Reconstruction and Development and published in its Transition
Reports. The index has remained virtually unchanged since 1994.
(20.) This truncation of the sample is an additional robustness
check. We have also experimented with excluding certain countries from
the sample, such as Bulgaria which had very high inflation in 1997 and
appears to be an outlier, the Baltic states which were part of the
former Soviet Union, and Albania, Croatia, and Macedonia where quality
of the data might be low. The results were essentially the same as in
the full sample.
(21.) I know of only one article, Bernhard and Leblang [1999],
where this is done.
References
Alesina, Alberto and Allan Drazen, "Why Are Stabilizations
Delayed?," American Economic Review, 81, 1991, pp. 1170-88.
Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon, "A Positive Theory of
Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model," Journal of Political
Economy, 91, 1983, pp. 589-610.
Barth, Richard C. and Chorng-Huey Wong, (eds.), Approaches to
Exchange Rate Policy Choices for Developing and Transitional Economies,
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1994.
Begg, David, "Disinflation in Central and Eastern Europe: The
Experience to Date," in Cottarelli, Carlo and Gyorgy Szapary
(eds.), Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transitional Economies,
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1998.
Bernhard, William and David Leblang, "Democratic Institutions
and Exchange-rate Commitments," International Organization, 53,
1999.
Bruno, Michael, "Stabilization and the Macroeconomics of
Transition: How Different is Eastern Europe?," Journal of Economics
of Transition, 1, 1993, pp. 5-19.
Calvo, Guillermo A. and Carlos A. Vegh, "Inflation
Stabilization and BOP Crises in Developing Countries," NBER Working
Paper No. 6925, 1999.
Collins, Susan, "On Becoming Flexible: Exchange Rate Regimes
in Latin America and the Caribbean," Journal of Development
Economics, 41, 1996, pp. 117-138.
Coorey, Sharmini, Mauro Mecagni and Erik Offerdal,
"Disinflation in Transition Economies: The Role of Relative Price
Adjustment," in Cottarelli, Carlo and Gyorgy Szapary, (eds.),
Moderate Inflation: The Experience of Transitional Economies,
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1998.
Devarajan, Shantayanan, and Dard Rodrik, "Do the Benefits of
Fixed Exchange Rates Outweigh Their Costs? The CFA Zone in Africa,"
in Ian Goldin and L. Alan Winters, (eds.), Open Economies: Structural
Adjustment and Agriculture, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press,
1992.
De Melo, Martha, Cevdet Denizer and Alan Gelb, "From Plan to
Market: Patterns of Transition" Working Paper No. 1564, Policy
Research Department, World Bank, 1996.
Devereux, Michael and Charles Engel, "Fixed vs. Floating
Exchange Rates: How Price Setting Affects the Optimal Choice of
Exchange-Rate Regime," NBER Working Paper No. 6857, 1998.
EBRD, Transition Report 1999: Ten Years of Transition, London, UK:
EBRD, 1999.
Edwards, Sebastian, "Exchange Rates as NominalAnchors,"
Weltwirschaftliches Archiv, 129, 1993.
Edwards, Sebastian, "The Determinants of the Choice Between
Fixed and Flexible Exchange-Rate Regimes," NBER Working Paper No.
5756, 1996.
Fernandez, Raquel and Dani Rodrik, "Resistance to Reform:
Status Quo Bias in the Presence of Individual-Specific
Uncertainty," American Economic Review, 81, 1991, pp. 1146-55.
Fisher, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos Vegh, "Stabilization
and Growth in Transition Economies," Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 10, 1996, pp. 45-66.
Frieden, Jeffry, Piero Ghezzi, and Ernesto Stein, "Politics
and Exchange Rates: A Cross-Country Approach to Latin America,"
IADB Research Network Working Paper No. R-421, 2000.
Ghosh, Atish R., Anne-Marie Guide, Jonathan D. Ostry, and Holger C.
Wolf, "Does the Nominal Exchange Rate Regime Matter?" NBER
Working Paper No. 5874, 1997.
Klyuev, Vladimir, Essays on Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy in
Transition Economies, Doctoral Thesis, Harvard University, 2000.
Koch, Elmar B., "Exchange Rates and Monetary Policy in Central
Europe--a Survey of Some Issues," Working Paper No. 24, Austrian
National Bank, 1997.
Masson, Paul R., "Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy of
Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe after the Launch of
EMU," Policy Discussion Paper No. 99/5, International Monetary
Fund, 1999.
McKinnon, Ronald D., "Optimal Currency Areas" American
Economic Review, 53, 1963, pp. 717-725.
Mundell, Robert A., "A Theory of Optimal Currency Areas,"
American Economic Review, 51, 1961, pp. 657-665.
Rodrik, Dani, "The Rush to Free Trade in the Developing World:
Why So Late? Why Now? Will It Last?" in Stephan Haggard and Steven
B. Webb, (eds.), Voting for Reform: Democracy, Political Liberalization,
and Economic Adjustment, New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 1994.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., "Economic Transition and the Exchange-Rate
Regime," American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 56,
1996, pp. 147-152.
Sweeney, Richard. J., Clas G. Wihlborg, and Thomas D. Willett,
(eds.), Exchange-Rate Policies for Emerging Market Economies, Boulder,
CO: Westview Press, 1999.
Tavlas, George, "The New Theory of Optimal Currency
Areas" World Economy, 16, 1993, pp. 663-85.
Tornell, Aaron and Andr6s Velasco, "Money-Based versus
Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization with Exogenous Fiscal Policy,"
NBER Working Paper No. 5300, 1995.
Tomell, Aaron and Andres Velasco, "Fiscal Discipline and the
Choice of Nominal Anchor in Stabilization," Journal of
International Economics, 46, 1998, pp. 1-30.
Turnovsky, Stephen J., "The Relative Stability of Alternative
Exchange Rate Systems in the Presence of Random Disturbances"
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 8, 1976, pp. 29-50.
Williamson, John, (ed.), Currency Convertibility in Eastern Europe,
Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1991.
Vladimir Klyuev
International Monetary Fund