Implementing agrarian reform in the Russian Far East.
Duncan, Jennifer ; Ruetschle, Michelle
Introduction
Agriculture is the Achilles heel of Pacific Russia. Its Northern
climate and remote location restrict commercial agricultural production
to a few Southern regions in the fertile Amur River valley and low lands
of Southern Primore. Yet, even there, the legacies of Stalin's
collectivization and deportation of East Asian peasants persist. (1) On
the eve of economic reform in 1990, the small agricultural sector was
organized into giant sovkhozes (state farms), kolkhozes (collective
farms), and agricultural subsidiaries of industrial factories. However,
most households depended on tiny private plots or communal gardens for
their produce. (2) Although the giant Soviet era organizations received
massive capital inflows and subsidies, their measured productivity was
little different from the productivity of pre-revolutionary peasant
agriculture in 1913. If peasant farmers in Amur territory produced an
average of 0.9 tons per hectare of grain and 7.4 tons per hectare of
potatoes in 1913, the same region produced average yields of 0.7 tons
per hectare of grain and 6 tons per hectare of potatoes in 1986-1990.
(3)
Thus, on the eve of reform, observers hoped that a series of laws
and decrees intended to underpin privatization of agricultural land,
beginning in 1991, would provide the institutional basis for new private
agricultural units and structural change of production, creating a
productive, expanding agricultural sector. However, the reality of
reform in agriculture has diverged from these initial expectations.
Beginning in 1997, the Rural Development Institute in Seattle,
Washington undertook a study of the process of agricultural reform in
the RFE, conducting interviews with territorial (oblast/krai) and county
(raion) officials, peasant farmers, managers of agricultural
enterprises, land shareowners, and rural pensioners. A 1997 paper by
Bradley Rorem and Renee Giovarelli based on the 1997 field work
concluded that implementation of large-scale agricultural reform was
proceeding slowly, while new private farms faced major institutional
barriers, including burdensome taxes and regulations and weak property
rights. (4) (Similar field research was conducted in 15 other
territories in Western Russia and Siberia.)
In October 1999, the present authors, both legal specialists on
land legislation and property rights, conducted a month-long follow-up
study in Khabarovsk and Amur territories in the RFE, investigating the
impact of land privatization and farm reorganization on agricultural
performance. Our interviews with jurists, legislators, and local
officials were supplemented with extensive site visits and interviews
with farm managers, private producers, and peasant shareholders. Local
officials provided and interpreted relevant local legislation and
implementing regulations and supplied economic data. While the interview
data may be viewed as "anecdotal," the full, in-depth access
that we had to officials and managers and the consistency of reports
with the 1997 RFE study leads us to conclude that our informants
attempted to provide us with a full and accurate picture of emerging
institutional and structural changes.
Our research investigated how local farmers, agricultural managers
and government officials were actually implementing an emerging body of
legislation redefining ownership rights in land. We sought evidence on
changes in the internal governance of agricultural units and
restructuring of farm management, collected data on land transactions
and land leasing, as well as formation and disappearance of new farms,
and studied changes in cropping, marketing, employment, input use,
investment, and government policies to provide explicit or implicit
subsidies to rural producers. The picture that emerges shows major
changes in the rural sector of the RFE, but it documents that
institutional barriers in the establishment and exercise of ownership
rights to land remain the most important barriers to agricultural reform
in Pacific Russia, and, by implication, in other regions of Russia as
well.
Agriculture in the Russian Far East
The commercial agricultural sector in the Russian Far East employs
a small and declining share of the labor force. Since 1990, official
employment in agriculture has fallen from 14 to 6 percent of the labor
force. (5) Primary crops are Soybeans, oats, wheat, barley, potatoes,
tomatoes, cucumbers, cabbage and livestock fodder crops. Meat, milk,
eggs and honey are also produced in the RFE. (6) Agriculture in the RFE
accounts for one percent of the total grain production in the Russian
Federation, five percent of the potato and vegetable production, 50
percent of the honey production and 74 percent of the soybean production. (7)
Soviet policies from the 1960s through the 1980s propelled the
expansion of agricultural production in the Far East through creation of
very large collective and state farms. (8) The total amount of plowed
land in the RFE peaked at 2,756,000 hectares in 1988, bolstered by heavy
subsidies from Moscow that propped up agriculture. (9) Even while highly
subsidized, however, the collective and state farms were unable to
produce at the level realized in market economies with similar northerly
locations, such as Finland and Canada. (10)
Commercial agriculture is concentrated in the South, in Amur,
Primore, Khabarovsk, and Jewish Autonomous Republic. Amur, alone
accounts for nearly 60 percent of the agricultural land and one-half of
the region's agricultural production.
Since the early 1990s, agriculture has experienced several shocks.
First, subsidies and federally mandated investment were slashed. Second,
there was a drastic fall in the purchasing power of the population.
Third, local producers were impacted by the availability of low-cost,
competitive foreign products--US chickens, New Zealand lamb, and Chinese
vegetables. In consequence, total agricultural output in the RFE
declined steadily from 1992-1998 as production of grains, meat, and
dairy products fell to less than half of former levels. Only a few
products, such as soybeans and potatoes remained competitive.
The precipitous fall in the value of the ruble in 1998, provided
some stimulus to domestic production, but under-capitalized farms facing
rising fuel prices have been slow to respond. Through out the period,
small household private plots played a unique role in household food
consumption, accounting for some 86 percent of potatoes, 74 percent of
vegetables, and almost half of meat and milk production. (11) Heavy
reliance on food imports leave the region vulnerable to fluctuations in
exchange rates, high domestic tariff barriers, and rising transport
costs.
Summary of the Agrarian Reform Process in the RFE
A series of laws and decrees, issued in 1991, ushered in the
privatization process in the agricultural sector in Russia. (12) As a
result of the reforms, the majority of land held by collectives and
state farms was to be allocated into land shares privately owned by farm
members. (13) Some of this land was later withdrawn by shareowners to
start peasant farm enterprises, or PFE's. A portion of land from
each collective also went to the raion land redistribution fund, to be
re-allocated by the raion governments to PFE's. Finally, the
reforms left household plots under the control of individual families,
and provided for full ownership rights to these plots.
Agrarian reform legislation also called for privatization of
nonland assets of collective and state farms. (14) This legislation
directs state and collective farms to determine the value of their total
non-land assets (known as property shares) by deducting net liabilities
from net assets, then dividing this total net value into shares among
several categories of people including farm workers, workers temporarily
absent from the farm, and pensioners. (15) Shares to eligible
individuals were to be determined by their former contribution to the
fund (e.g., by the relative number of hours worked). Persons withdrawing
from a collective or state farm have the right to withdraw their
property share in kind. While most farms originally completed the
process of dividing up non-land property and assigning monetary value to
individual shares, they have often prohibited individuals from
withdrawing a reasonable property share in-kind.
Nevertheless, following privatization, a private agricultural
sector emerged with three types of producers: large agricultural
enterprises, peasant farm enterprises, and household auxiliary plot
owners.
Large Agricultural Enterprises
Agricultural enterprises are former collective farms now registered
as agricultural production cooperatives, joint stock companies, limited
liability companies or, in some cases, even (mistakenly) as PFEs. Most
of these farms had barely changed in structure or productivity, with
only a cosmetic name change and the distribution of shares (on paper) to
reflect their quasiprivatization. One former collective we visited had
managed to make more significant changes through a radical change in
leadership. Such instances are rare, however. In 1998, Khabarovsk Krai had 58 large agricultural enterprises (down from 76 in 1993), and Amur
Oblast had 54 agricultural enterprises. (16)
One typical former collective we visited in Khabarovsk Krai
controlled 11,000 hectares, all of which were under production in 1999.
It was negotiating to acquire more of the neighboring land; however this
was difficult because that land was divided into land shares and
required the consent of numerous shareowners. The enterprise had
undergone some reorganization in 1991, when the collective's land
was converted into shares. In 1999, the enterprise rented shares from
500 people, while only 280 people actually worked on the farm. The
enterprise has three-year rental contracts with the shareholders, many
of whom are pensioners. Rental compensation was in kind, in the form of
one ton of grain per year, as well as various services, such as
transportation and plowing of household plots. Workers were paid
additional monthly wages, including advance and post-harvest payments,
and received favorable purchase rates for farm produce.
This enterprise, like many others in the region, is slowly failing.
(17) Workers are not paid on time, and may only be paid in-kind after
harvest. Many enterprises have had their bank accounts frozen for
failure to make timely payments to government budgets, forcing these
enterprises to operate almost completely through barter arrangements. In
1997, one Khabarovsk Krai official estimated that approximately 50
percent of all agricultural enterprises in the krai had their bank
accounts frozen pursuant to a 1996 Presidential Decree. (18)
While large agricultural enterprises use the majority of the
RFE's agricultural land, (19) these enterprises generally do not
have formal ownership rights. Rather, ownership rights are formally
exercised in common by individual share owners who are permitted to
dispose of their shares by permanently contributing them to the
enterprise charter capital, temporarily contributing them (for use) to
the enterprise, leasing them to the enterprise or to a peasant farm, or
withdrawing them to create a peasant farm, add to an existing peasant
farm, or to augment an existing small plot. (20) In the mid-1990s, some
108 million hectares, or 49 percent of Russia's 222 million
hectares of agricultural land, were transferred into this form of
ownership. (21)
The majority of land share owners in the Russian Far East have been
unable to formally dispose of their shares, and enterprise management
continues to use them with no written agreement to the share owner. (22)
For example, one female pensioner interviewed in the village of Korsakov
near Khabarovsk believed that her land was being used but did not dare
to request compensation from the boss of her former collective farm.
This same woman was also unable to afford the surveying cost to
ascertain the exact location of her land. Based on this and other
fieldwork findings, the absence of a written agreement often signifies
that the lessor/land share owner is in fact receiving little if any
compensation for the use of his or her land by the enterprise, and,
thus, derive no economic benefit or rights from "ownership."
Peasant Farm Enterprises
Peasant farms occupy about six percent of Russia's
agricultural land, and represent roughly the same percent of all
agricultural households. The relative size of the peasant farm sector in
the RFE roughly mirrors that of Russia as a whole, although the average
size of PFE's is larger in the Russian Far East. (23) In Amur, for
example, the average size of a PFE was 148 hectares. This average was
misleading, however, due to the registration of some large, former
collectives as PFE's. Most PFE members were formerly collective
farm members who had withdrawn their shares from the collective farm,
often leasing in or purchasing additional land.
A consolidation trend has emerged within the peasant farm sector in
the RFE as in the rest of Russia, where the amount of land owned and
leased by peasant farms has increased over recent years while the number
of peasant farms has decreased slightly. (24) This consolidation trend
has been especially prominent in Amur where the number of PFE's
decreased from 2,783 in 1993 to 1,926 in 1999 (a 31 percent drop). The
exception is Khabarovsk Krai, where both the number and size of PFEs
fell. One reason for this deviation from the national trend may be the
high concentration of PFE's producing livestock rather than crops.
On one PFE that we visited in Khabarovsk, the farmer had to travel
some distance to his 98-hectare farm. He began his PFE in 1992 by
purchasing virgin land from the rural administration. He purchased land
in parts, beginning with 30 hectares and gradually expanding. This
farmer was deeply discouraged by high fuel prices and feared that his
farm would fail as a result. Competition with middlemen purchasing
cheaper potatoes from Amur made it impossible to raise price enough to
cover his fuel costs. The farmer raised pigs as well as potatoes and
soy. However, he was unable to slaughter the 20 pigs he had prepared for
sale because he could not afford fuel to transport the meat to market.
He was also unable to afford the fuel necessary to harvest and transport
his soy crop.
Reported reasons for falls in the number of peasant farms included
lack of funds or credit for machinery, receipt of poor quality land from
the land redistribution fund, and a formal deregistration of many PFEs,
whose owners continue their farming activities in the informal sector.
Peasant farms in the RFE that have grown in size have done so by leasing
land from shareowners, from agricultural enterprises, or from the land
fund rather than increasing their nominal ownership.
Small Auxiliary Plots
Household auxiliary plots (or "small plots," which
include garden plots, household vegetable plots attached to houses in
former collective villages, and household vegetable plots located in a
field some distance away from the family house) constitute the most
intensively used agricultural land in the RFE. Almost all interviewees
obtained some significant portion of their daily subsistence food from
their household plot.
The only sector in which a nearly functional land market is
emerging in the RFE, and in Russia as a whole, is that of small plots,
which have been "owned" in the full sense for more than seven
years. The minimal capital requirements for small plot cultivation
contribute to higher market demand for small plot land. The ability to
transact small plots allows their allocation to more efficient users and
sustains high levels of production on these plots. More importantly,
tenure security encourages investment on this land.
Household plots are larger in the RFE than in Russia as a whole,
reflecting the high ratio of arable land per RFE resident. In
Khabarovsk, for example, garden plots are 1200 square meters on average,
compared with 600 square meters in Moscow oblast, according to one krai
official. In Khabarovsk and in Amur, as in the rest of Russia, household
plots produce a great quantity of high-value crops, such as vegetables
and potatoes. In 1995, household plots provided 86 percent of the
potatoes, 74 percent of the vegetables, and almost half of the meat and
milk. In contrast, private farms accounted for 2 percent of the
potatoes, 4 percent of the vegetables, 6 percent of the meat, and 4
percent of the milk produced in the region. (25)
Families producing on private plots consume most of their own
production, occasionally selling surpluses at local markets. Many
vendors we interviewed at the Khabarovsk central market, for example,
were selling pork from their family pigs or milk from a family cow.
Small plot vegetable growers sell potatoes, beets, carrots, and other
products along the roadside near the central market, since the central
market stalls are taken by vendors selling imported products.
Many families located in villages on former collective farms
receive some degree of subsidy for their small plots from the collective
farm management. This subsidy often takes the form of free plowing and
sometimes of reduced-cost inputs for planting. In some cases,
collectives offer to plow their members' household plots as a lease
payment for the use of the members' land shares. Resource transfers
(both explicit and implicit) from collectives to farm members for their
household plots, although of immediate benefit to small plot owners,
discourage members from withdrawing their land shares for private
farming, as this would terminate the flow of resources from the
collective.
Issues Related to Land Privatization and Farm Restructuring
Any attempts to raise the productivity of regional agriculture will
require major institutional changes in order to provide clearer title to
land and expanded rental markets. This is true for three reasons. First,
while much land currently goes unused, the supply of well located,
readily cultivable land that does not require a large initial investment
(in leveling or clearing) is limited. Second, the size and location of
available land plots are often undesirable. Existing land claims are
held in very small or very large parcels, far different from the
desirable scale of unit that private farmers would choose if credit and
capital markets were well developed. Plots near urban centers or
adjoining existing parcels are also scarce. Third, the transactions
costs of acquiring and assembling land parcels from current share owners
or PFEs may be high. Due to a poorly functioning land market, parcels
are usually available only from the raion land redistribution fund.
Significant barriers, therefore, remain to the transfer of land away
from less successful to more promising users, even if access to capital
improves.
Privatization and Farm Restructuring
Where collectives have been "privatized" into land
shares, share owners are often unable to exercise their rights to their
shares in any meaningful way. Most collective farms have undergone a
superficial restructuring at best, and continue to operate as
collectives with over 5,000 hectares. (26) Few operate productively, nor
would they be able to operate productively even with more capital. Most
have retained the exact dimensions and characteristics they had as
collectives in the past, including size (many remain as large as 10,000
to 12,000 hectares), a large number of employees, methods of production
and decision-making. In most cases the only change during the 90s has
been a marked drop in production resulting from the ending of state
subsidies. (27) While most managers we interviewed acknowledged that
workers and pensioners now hold ownership rights in the form of land
shares, they rarely compensated these land-share owners in any way for
the continued use of their shares.
Moreover, some collective farms in Khabarovsk Krai have done no
restructuring and have not been divided into land shares, as directed by
agrarian reform legislation. (28) According to the Khabarovsk land
committee, 23 out of 53 former collective farms in the krai
(representing 29,700 hectares, or about 14% of the total agricultural
land in the krai) have been "reorganized," but without
privatizing the land and property that are supposed to be owned by the
members. It is unclear why this has happened. (These 23 enterprises are
distinct from those enterprises exempted from privatization for purposes
of specialized state production.) Officials attributed such arrangements
to the adoption of a provision in the new enterprise charter that allows
all land shares held by individual members to be permanently contributed
to the new enterprise. This explanation is not sufficient, however, as
these shares should then have been included among the official tallies of "permanently contributed shares." Instead, it appears that
land shares were never even calculated on the twenty-three farms,
depriving farm members of all rights to the land to which they were
entitled.
One of the defining characteristics of agrarian reform in the RFE
relative to anywhere else in Russia is the great amount of land that
regional governments have retained in the land redistribution funds. In
fact, the majority of agricultural land in the RFE remains unprivatized
in the raion land redistribution funds. In 1999, Khabarovskii krai held
93,900 hectares of arable land in its fund, while Amurskai oblast held
over 900,000 hectares of arable land. In 1999, the Amur land committee
leased out 251,176 hectares from the fund to agricultural enterprises
and only 700 hectares to peasant farmers. (29) The amount of land held
in the land fund in both regions has increased since 1997 (in Amur by 13
percent and in Khabarovsk by 45 percent). (30)
It is unclear exactly how the land funds in Khabarovskii krai and
Amurskaia oblast became so large. In Amur, the size of the fund may be
related to the oblast land committee's aggressive policy of land
monitoring and penalties pursued in the years following reforms. (31) It
may also be related to an oblast-wide policy limiting land shares to ten
hectares each, which caused large amounts of land on some farms to be
classified as unallocated "residual" land slated for the land
fund. It also reflects a depressed demand for agricultural land, which
in turn is related to the economic inefficiencies of farming in the Far
East given current input/output price ratios and, above all, lack of
credit.
The notably high level of land held in state control through the
land funds in the RFE indicates that the oblast and raion-level
officials in the RFE have only partially implemented federal
privatization and agrarian reform policies. The purpose behind the funds
was to redistribute land to peasant farmers, not to hold it en masse at
the local or regional level. Reform-oriented legislators certainly did
not anticipate that over 50 percent of the arable land would be withheld
from privatization in the land funds.
Land Transactions
Working land markets function as a powerful tool for moving land
and capital to higher value users. Rather than allocate ownership of
this land to agricultural enterprises or PFEs, regional governments have
chosen to lease some of it out on five-year terms (for free or, at most,
nominal rates), retaining the option to terminate the lease at the end
of the term in the event of misuse or nonuse. The Amur land committee
has shifted its policies over the last two years to encourage more land
to be in production, partly by allocating land in lease (or use) to
almost anyone who applies for it. In some cases the land committee has
allowed immigrant farmers from China, Korea, Holland, and the United
States to lease land in the fund for farming.
The strategy of Amur oblast appears to be to maximize agricultural
production by retaining ownership of most arable land and allocating it
to private users for short terms. This policy, coupled with strict
management policies toward land held in private ownership, is justified
by the local bureaucracy as an attempt to reduce inefficient land use by
private owners, reflecting the bureaucratic bias, which assumes the
supremacy of central state planning.
The policy of retaining most arable land under state control is
harmful for several reasons. First, it assumes the state is a better
regulator than the market for moving land into efficient use. Second,
the resource wealth retained by the raion and oblast-level governments
creates opportunities for corruption and nepotism. Third, the government
accrues administrative costs for monitoring the land, making and
reviewing lease contracts, and executing penalties. (These costs could,
of course, be considered advantageous from the perspective of the oblast
and raion-level officials whose employment currently depends on them.)
Fourth, short-term leases fail to provide the type of security of rights
required by farmers to make long-term investments to boost productivity.
Any government policy of strict monitoring and intervention into the
nonuse of privately held land is also likely to decrease farmers'
incentives to make these longer-term investments.
Finally, holding large quantities of land in state ownership,
available for lease at subsidized rates (quoted as anywhere between zero
and five rubles per hectare per year) creates a non-transparent
alternative source of land, which retards emergence of genuine markets.
A market for agricultural land would allow farmers to acquire collateral
and to borrow for investment.
Lack of a market for land also imposes transactions costs on the
ability of labor to move between activities. With commercial labor
markets, land owners could lease out or sell their land, leaving the
farming sector. This may be especially important for pensioners and for
people wishing to migrate to urban settings. Without real land
privatization and the development of a functioning land market to
facilitate the movement of agricultural land from inefficient to
efficient users, obsolete farm units will continue to sit on large
tracts of land and production will continue to stagnate. Furthermore,
banks cannot accept land for collateral in the absence of a land market,
impeding farmers from leveraging credit for major infrastructure
improvements. Clearly, the best way to hasten the development of a
functional agricultural land market in the Russian Far East would be to
privatize the great majority of land that is currently contained in
raion land redistribution funds.
One particularly vulnerable group of farms is made up of the
peasant enterprises established on land-fund land at the start of
reform. These "pioneer" peasant farms received extremely low
quality land. Thus, even in cases where they received subsidized credit
for purchase of machinery, they have little prospect of long-term
survival. One official in Khabarovskii krai estimated that only 70 out
of 307 PFEs in one raion land any long-term prospects of survival due to
their poor land.
A final problem with privatization and restructuring in the RFE, is
the inclination of large farm enterprises to impede people from
withdrawing property shares in kind when they leave to start a peasant
farm. Property shares are still a largely untapped source for machinery
and equipment for peasant farms, and the laws regarding property share
valuation and withdrawal are largely ignored. Presently, individuals who
leave agricultural enterprises continue to have great difficulty
exercising their right to withdraw property in kind or to receive the
cash value of their property shares. Many agricultural enterprises hold
small stocks of working machinery, much of it in poor repair. Nor do the
enterprises have sufficient funds to redeem the property shares for
cash. Moreover, property shares on the great majority of farms have not
been adjusted for inflation for several years, so the denominated value
of property shares is ridiculously low, sometimes being undervalued by a
factor of several thousand, making it difficult for share owners to
demand high values for their land rights in the absence of any true
market measures.
Government Regulation of Privately Held Land
The land committees in both Khabarovsk krai and Amur oblast
continue to monitor privately held land used by PFEs for nonuse or what
they term "irrational use", whether this land is leased from
the land fund or owned. Punishment for irrational or nonuse by a lessee is refusal to renew the lease contract upon its expiration; punishment
for irrational or nonuse by a private owner ranges from warnings or
fines to outright confiscation. Although land committee personnel in
both Khabarovsk and Amur strongly believe they have the legal right to
enforce land use regulations on farmers who hold land in ownership, they
have become increasingly reluctant to do so since the amount of land not
being cultivated has increased steadily. (32)
Between 1997 and 1999, the threat of confiscation seems to have
fallen. In our fieldwork in fall 1999, farmers did not appear to be
concerned that the land committee might fine them or confiscate land for
failure to use it properly. However, it is important to note
farmers' concerns in interviews in 1997 that the land committee
could fine them or withdraw their land if they did not use it in a
manner that satisfied the land inspector. The threat of withdrawal
affected the manner in which peasant farmers chose to expand their
operations. The difference between 1997 and 1999 in perceived threat of
land committee interference appears to be due to oblast/krai decisions
to relax strict monitoring and penalties on private land.
Lease
A land share lease market is developing in the RFE in place of
outright ownership. The most common type of lease agreement between
private actors takes place when a land share owner leases out his or her
share to the agricultural enterprise (former collective farm) that
occupies it. Sometimes an agricultural enterprise leases land from
shareowners on a neighboring enterprise. In a few instances, peasant
farmers also lease land from shareowners, usually at a higher rate than
the average paid by agricultural enterprises.
Lease agreements between land share owners and large enterprises
vary greatly in their terms and level of payment. In most instances,
terms are for three to five years, with an option to renew at the end of
the term. Terms offered by at least one former collective we visited
were much longer, however, ranging from 10 to 49 years. Payment ranged
from zero to 10 percent of the gross production and was usually in kind,
offered in a combination of grain, soy, and discounts on items such as
hay and coal (bought in bulk by the enterprise). Payment sometimes also
included plowing the lessor's household auxiliary plot. Some farm
managers also cited payment of land tax as part of their lease payment
to the land share owner.
Many lease transactions take place between the land fund (making
the raion government the lessor) and private farms as lessees, including
both former collectives and PFEs. In a few instances, peasant farmers
work out informal "sublease" arrangements where one larger,
wealthier farmer leases land from the land fund and smaller, neighboring
farmers use part of this land for a very nominal fee paid to the primary
lessee.
Where former collectives produce on only a portion of the land they
possess, they generally provide lease payments for only those
shareowners whose shares are located in the fields under production (if
they provide lease payments at all). This is true even though a land
share represents a right to common ownership of the enterprise land: if
one hectare of land is cultivated, that hectare represents a minute part
of everyone's land share. At a former collective in Amurskaia
oblast, for example, one pensioner told us she had approached the farm
management about lease payments on her land share, which the farm was
currently using. The manager, who was also the chairman of the former
collective, responded that if she demanded payments, he would simply
stop cultivating her land and shift production to another field where
shareowners did not make such demands. This response underscores the
imbalance of power between the management of agricultural enterprises
and former collective farm members who are now land share owners and
indicates a low level of organization among former members/shareowners.
Most importantly, this response exposes illegal activity by the
enterprise management.
Further reports by land share owners at the same farm in the RFE
attested to the level of coercion employed by management in avoiding
payments for use of land shares. One pensioner couple reported that
their shares were located in a field the farm management was not
currently cultivating. The couple approached the farm manager, asking
him to lease in their shares. Management responded with an offer for a
ten-year lease at 1,000 rubles ($40.00) per year. This, said the couple,
was "crazy!" The manager went on to say that he would only
lease the land on these terms if and when the couple convinced the
additional ten people who owned land shares in their field to lease out
on the same terms.
A final problem relating to the lease market is that even when farm
managers do make lease agreements, they often breach them without
suffering consequences. In several cases we encountered, farm managers
(of agricultural enterprises and, in one case, a peasant farm) claimed
they were "unable" to pay the in-kind lease payments they had
contracted to, and so did not plan on making any payments in that year.
In another case, the manager of a former collective in Amurskaia oblast
planned on "renegotiating" the terms of his five-year leases
with shareowners after only three years. The first shareowners selected
for termination of the lease agreement or who received reduced payment
would be those who were no longer employees of the farm, and the last
shareowners selected would be pensioners, he said.
Inheritance
Inheritance transactions are, and will continue to be, an essential
component in transferring the lasting benefits of agrarian reforms to
rural households. Of the roughly 108 million hectares, or 49 percent, of
Russia's 222 million hectares of agricultural land that were
transferred into private ownership through land shares in the early to
mid-1990s, about 40 percent of these shares went to pensioners. By 2010,
it is likely that rights to roughly three-quarters of these
pensioner-owned land shares, representing about 32 million hectares,
will have passed by inheritance to their children.
Despite the importance of inheritance as a means of transferring
land rights within rural households, apparently only 158,512
"successions" (inheritances), with an average size of less
than one-third hectare each, were formally registered in all of Russia
in 1997. (33) Virtually no inheritances of land shares, which are likely
the principal source of land for new and expanded family farms, are
being formally documented and registered. Many collective farm managers
currently attempt to restrict the inheritance of land shares, leading to
additional delay, expense, and discouragement for the heir attempting to
claim his or her rights to the land share or to sell or lease out those
rights.
In the RFE, however, many heirs simply do not claim inherited land
shares or plots. This may be because land taxes are extremely high and,
with an insecure legal framework about their rights to dispose of the
land through sale or lease, they may view assuming rights to the land as
a net liability. This scenario is especially likely for heirs living in
urban areas who are unable to benefit from farming the land themselves.
Purchase and Sale
As in the rest of Russia, a market in agricultural land purchase
and sale has been slow to develop in the Russian Far East. (34) A number
of factors impede the development of a market in the purchase and sale
of agricultural land in the RFE. First, farmers and officials are
unclear about legal rights to purchase and sell land. Current
legislation does not provide a solid framework for buying and selling
agricultural land and land shares. On one hand, Article 36 of the
Constitution of the Russian Federation establishes a right to dispose of
land, and presidential decrees clearly provide for private purchase-sale
transactions in agricultural land. However, new legislation adopted by
the Duma legalizing the sale of urban land specifically excludes
agricultural land. This absence of parliamentary law (zakon) has led
many rural residents to believe these rights are not secure. The unclear
legality of purchase-sale transactions depresses demand for land in two
ways: people do not want to buy land for fear the transactions could be
revoked at a later time; and people do not want to own land because,
although they must pay high taxes on it, they are not certain they would
be able to sell it in the future. Perceptions that it is illegal for
PFEs to lease out their land also reduce the demand for land purchases
and ownership.
Even when share sales are taking place, the transactions costs are
high. Share owners must go through a time-consuming and difficult
process to obtain approval from farm management and/or the farm's
general meeting to sell their shares. The widespread availability of
land at subsidized rates from the raion land fund creates little
incentive for purchase.
Mortgage and Credit Markets
The federal law "On Mortgage" explicitly prohibits the
mortgage of agricultural land. (35) Even if mortgage becomes legal,
until a stronger agricultural land market develops in the RFE, it is
unlikely that banks will engage in mortgage transactions. Meanwhile,
farmers are unable to secure credit for machinery and inputs, which
would foster higher productivity and thus contribute to increased land
values. The majority of peasant farmers in Khabarovsk and Amur were
familiar with the concept of using land for collateral, and many
expressed an interest in mortgaging their land if federal law allowed.
Most farmers would use credit secured through mortgage for the purchase
of much-needed machinery or processing equipment.
Registration
The registration and mapping processes in Russia give rise to
several issues that affect sale transactions, including delays in and
costs of demarcation and registration of land plots, and broader
institutional shortcomings related to the establishment of a new
registration apparatus under the Ministry of Justice. The 1997 law
"On Land Registration" and accompanying regulations
transferred land registration functions from the land committee to the
Ministry of Justice. (36) The ministry has been working to set up
registration offices (known as "chambers") in every raion in
Russia. According to officials in the land committee and Ministry of
Agriculture, the Amur oblast government has yet to implement the new
chambers, with the result that the land committee continues to perform
registration functions, as well as to manage and allocate state and
privately held land. Maintaining both functions allows a consolidation
of a large amount of authority within one branch of government, an
outcome the new system avoids.
In Amur oblast and Khabarovskii krai, procedural requirements
related to demarcation and registration may deter some land share owners
from selling their plots, according to reports by pensioners and other
shareowners. Anyone wishing to sell his or her land must first confirm
the boundaries with the oblast/krai land committee, then register it
with the land committee (or in the case of Khabarovsk, with the Ministry
of Justice). The registration process costs 200 rubles ($8) and takes
two to three days, according to krai officials. Perceptions of the
demarcation/registration process by land share owners vary from
straightforward and fairly efficient to extremely onerous, expensive,
and time-consuming.
Bankruptcy
It may be possible to use bankruptcy as a tool for transferring
land and other resources from broken, inefficient agricultural
enterprises to productive new or existing enterprises. (37) Officials in
Amur have, in fact, exercised bankruptcy on roughly 20 farms. In some
cases, outside buyers have purchased farm resources (often one or two of
the "productive sections" of the former collective) from the
state after it has carried out bankruptcy proceedings.
An important question relates to the outcome of individuals'
rights to land and property shares in the event that the state declares
bankruptcy of an agricultural enterprise. According to federal
legislation, land shares that have not been formally contributed to the
charter capital of the agricultural enterprise belong to the individual
land share owners (not the enterprise), and can be withdrawn or
transferred at any point through the liquidation process in accordance
with Presidential Decree No. 337. Land shares that have been contributed
to an enterprise may still be withdrawn if allowed by the
enterprise's charter. In this case, however, the land to be
allocated in kind may be subject to some debt, since the land was
"owned" by the enterprise (subject to withdrawal rights). What
has actually happened to shareowners' rights in the 20 cases of
bankruptcy in Amur oblast is not clear.
Machinery
Farmers cited inability to acquire machinery as their most
significant impediments to effective land use. Particularly in the Far
East, where land is abundant and farms are larger, an aging arsenal of
farm machinery has significantly constrained growth and production.
Statistics show a steady decline in agricultural machinery available and
in use throughout the Russian Far East. Throughout the region, tractor
supplies have decreased 47 percent and grain harvesting combines 44
percent between 1991 and 1997. Taking into account the deteriorating condition of the remaining supply, this sharp decline in machinery
reduces the plowing and harvesting potential of the region by almost
half. (38)
With the passage of time, the situation has only grown worse. The
price of farm machinery and equipment across Russia rose more rapidly
than food prices between 1990 and 1997. Some farmers predicted that they
would only continue to farm for a short time before the inevitable
breakdown of their machinery. Without access to new machinery in the
near future, those farmers still able to farm at all will be forced to
work smaller and smaller plots of land with fewer and fewer modern
agricultural aids. In Amur oblast, lack of machinery was cited as the
main cause for the removal of 200,000 hectares from production between
1997 and 1999.
Most farmers have not purchased new machinery since the beginning
of the land reform in 1991-92, when subsidized credit was widely
available. Others had received their machines as property shares from
their former collectives. This option is also largely obsolete today, as
many of the most valuable machines have already been distributed among
the earliest shareowners to withdraw from collective farms. What
machinery remains is decrepit and unsuited to the smaller parcels farmed
by peasant (farm) enterprises. In fact, unusually large numbers of
farmers stated that they had sufficient machinery, but that it was of
poor quality or unsuitable for their needs. Moreover, due to the
mismatch between inherited equipment and current production activities,
many agricultural enterprises, including small farmers, used tractors
and combines well in excess of their recommended capacity--in some cases
more than double the standard amount.
Lack of access to long-term credit prevents farmers from purchasing
appropriate small-scale machinery. In 1999, rates of credit from banks
could be obtained with interest rates as high as 180-200 percent, when
the underlying rate of inflation was about 37 percent, for the maximum
period of one year. The fragile state of Russia's undercapitalized and institutionally unstable banks has contributed to unpredictable and
often very high interest rates. Moreover, agriculture is seen as a risky
investment due to the low profitability of farms. The credit histories
of small farmers further discourage loans, and mountains of paperwork
hamper even the initial application process. As noted, land cannot be
used as collateral under the existing moratorium on mortgages, and the
practice of using the new machinery itself as collateral for loans is
still uncommon and unreliable.
Lack of machinery and high prices of soy relative to other crops
leads to a draw-down of land fertility by creating incentives to produce
a single crop, which draws down soil fertility. To grow soy over an
extended period of time, it must be rotated annually with other crops.
Without fertilizers, soy can be grown on only two-fifths of the land
each year. Even under ideal circumstances with fertilizers, it can be
grown on only one-half of a farmer's arable land. Currently,
farmers often violate crop rotation norms by increasing the relative
amount of land grown in soy. Overuse endangers the already fragile
quality of the soil and the sustainability of production.
Storage
Inadequate storage further reduces farmers' profitability.
Where storage is available, farmers are able to increase profits by
storing their produce until spring, when prices are higher. Where
storage is not available, however, farmers attempt to sell all their
produce (at lower prices) in the autumn, leaving any surplus to spoil.
In some cases, vegetable farmers without access to storage report losing
up to 45 percent of their production to rot. Meat-producers also have
difficulty finding storage for their fodder hay through the winter
season.
Farmers living near former collectives sometimes have the option of
leasing storage space from the collectives. The cost of leasing was
often deemed excessive, however. The possibility of cooperation in
building and sharing storage facilities, while attractive, is considered
unrealistic.
Chinese farmers across the border do trade in the Russian market to
reduce seasonal variability in prices, buying produce in the fall and
selling in the spring. According to reports from farmers and officials
in the RFE, Chinese farmers purchased vegetables at low prices from the
Russians in the autumn and sold their own produce on the Russian market
at higher prices in the spring. One farmer complained that even though
he managed to save his produce for the spring, the early sale of large
quantities of Chinese products that spring drove down prices, reducing
his profit, but providing benefit to consumers.
Seasonal Production Inputs
A rising disparity between the high costs of inputs and the low
prices of agricultural products threatens farmers' profitability.
Fuel prices, for example, went up twice as fast as prices of produce.
With profits already slim, these differential increases between expenses
and returns have been sufficient to seriously harm farmers. Some were
unable to use their machines or harvest their entire crops because they
could not afford fuel. Other farmers located far from urban areas and
markets were still more hard-pressed because of the high cost of
transporting their produce.
In addition to high fuel costs, high costs of fertilizers and
herbicides raise farmers' production expenses. Prohibitively high
prices force many farmers to abandon using these inputs altogether.
Since fertilizer is both difficult to obtain and expensive, farmers
often mulch with hay or use crop rotation to maintain fertility. The
1998 fall in the value of the ruble greatly increased the price of
herbicides, which are imported from Japan, Germany, and the United
States.
Cooperation among farmers may help to reduce the cost of inputs. In
Romnetskii raion in Amur, for example, the Organization of Peasant Farms
and Cooperatives of Russia (AKKOR) purchased large quantities of fuel at
reduced prices from wholesale suppliers and resold them at no profit to
member enterprises. Again, one of the underlying problems is lack of
available short-term credit at reasonable rates to purchase inputs. Many
farmers are forced to rely on contracts with state organizations or
processors at disadvantageous rates of exchange to receive the desired
inputs.
Processing Facilities
As in any economy, processing greatly increases the value and
profitability of agricultural products in the Russian Far East. Without
adequate capital or access to credit, however, the agricultural
processing industry has grown slowly. The processing facilities that do
exist appear to exercise monopoly power in the sector, forwarding
farmers fuel and other inputs in exchange for a promise from the farmers
to deliver produce after fall harvest at prices substantially below
market levels. Most farmers we interviewed complained bitterly about
these future contracts with processors, saying they paid dearly in the
fall for advances of fuel and fertilizer the previous spring. Many,
however, said they had no other option either for obtaining seasonal
credit for planting or for selling their products.
In Amur, for example, there is no local processing capacity and
several processing plants in Irkutsk, Khabarovsk, and Ussuriisk dominate
soy processing. We found one exception in Romnetskii raion, where
several farmers purchased their own small-scale soy processing
equipment. The AKKOR helped these farmers to obtain loans to purchase
processing equipment from an agricultural bank at an interest rate of
just 18 percent, with the AKKOR serving as the guarantor. After ensuring
capacity to process their own raw soy, the equipment owners give
priority to other farmers in the raion, and then to farmers from
neighboring raions.
A few firms have received foreign direct investment for food
processing equipment. When the ruble collapsed in August 1998, some
processors in the RFE realized net losses due to the increased loan
repayment burden to foreign investors, during a period when they could
have benefited from the increased demand for domestic production created
by the high cost of imports. (39)
Public Infrastructure
Several farmers located in more remote areas complained of lack of
road access to fields. Roads once actively used by collectives are now
falling into disrepair as more and more land falls out of production.
Electricity supply lines often do not reach remote "homestead"
farms, and many farmers operate without reliable electricity or are
forced to invest in their own power sources. In one garden plot
community, all the electric power lines had been stolen and (reportedly)
sold in China, leaving the community without electricity. One
enterprising farmer had installed his own wind propeller to produce an
increased amount of electricity to his remote farm.
Credit
Farmers reported that commercial bank credits were affordable or
easily obtained. A much more common form of credit is the "budget
loan," a state-subsidized loan from a commercial bank at a fixed
low interest rate of approximately 18 percent. These can enable
significant capital purchases and investments to those who qualify,
although qualification (requiring solid credit history, a lengthy
application procedure, and proof of sufficient collateral) may elude many farmers. Cooperative loan efforts with AKKOR-type assistance may be
an effective means to overcome the stringent requirements needed to
receive state subsidized bank loans.
Another type of credit involves contracts with state organizations.
In Khabarovsk, for example, the krai administration helps farmers with
spring planting in return for delivery contracts with state
organizations. Farmers who agree to deliver a fixed amount of their
production to a state institution such as a military barracks, hospital,
or public school may be eligible for these contracts. The state agrees
to pay for the delivery in two parts: an initial payment for operating
expenses (fuel, fertilizer, herbicide) in the spring and a second
payment in cash upon delivery in the fall. The agreement resembles a
commercial forward contract; the advantage to farmers is low interest
rates for the value of the forwarded inputs.
In practice these contracts have been problematic. Most noticeably,
the state repays contracts late, often one to three years after
delivery. With high inflation rates, these delays cause payments to be
virtually worthless. Furthermore, state payments generally consist of in
kind deliveries of fuel or other inputs or offset of old loans. Thus, if
farmers need cash for any other needs, state delivery contracts are not
an option.
An alternative form of credit available mainly to soy producers is
a future contract with a processing enterprise. Under these contracts,
processors lend farmers in kind operating expenses (such as fuel and
fertilizers) for the spring planting season and charge high interest
rates that must be paid by the farmers upon delivery of their goods.
Farmers who participate in these contracts (only some of which are
written) receive inputs in the spring for no cash up front but receive
lower than market price later. (But exchange at low nominal prices allows both partners to reduce tax obligations.)
The formation of credit cooperatives may offer an alternative means
for farmers in the RFE to secure credit. Although these are not common
among farmers in the Far East, we did encounter one example of a
successful credit cooperative in Amur. Membership in the cooperative
consisted of 12 PFEs, one former collective, and AKKOR. Members
contributed machines and cash as charter capital and collateral.
While this innovative method of credit access appears promising, it
still faces considerable hurdles. The law of the Russian Federation "On Cooperatives" (40) is tailored to production cooperatives
rather than "secondary" cooperatives (such as credit,
marketing, or service cooperatives). The paperwork is complicated and a
cooperative's income may be subject to double taxation (as income
to the cooperative enterprise and to the individual members). In a
period where taxes are not always collected, the threat of
double-taxation may not be a significant detriment to the individual
cooperative, but it will most certainly discourage the proliferation of
such organizations in the future. In an attempt to address some of these
gaps, a federal law on credit cooperatives that defines its legal
status, goals, specific features and basic principles of operation was
finally approved by the Russian government in January 2001.
Marketing
Farmers in the Russian Far East market their products through a
variety of channels, including foreign importers, domestic processors,
stalls at central or local markets, and roadside trucks. Sale of
agricultural production directly to consumers is a prime means of cash
for farmers. Many farmers reported, however, that they could not afford
the time or transport costs of selling at consumer markets. Some farmers
sold their goods at the roadside or to an established round of
customers.
The middleman sector in the RFE has grown over the past decade. By
purchasing goods in bulk from farmers at less than retail price
middlemen are able to be profitable after deducting transport and
marketing costs. Despite additional marketing choices presented by an
evolving middleman sector, many farmers view middlemen as corrupt,
usurious, or monopolistic. Middlemen often gain access to premium stalls
in local markets that are inaccessible to farmers, and some farmers
suspect collusion between market operators and middlemen. Some middlemen
also import goods at lower rates from other areas, thereby creating
competition for local farmers and benefiting consumers. In the spring,
middlemen representing big processing firms are able to make deals with
cash-hungry farmers who have few other means of access to processing
equipment.
The market for soy products has seen the strongest development
because of strong foreign demand. Seventy percent of soy oil exports
from the region go to China. Soy meal is exported to Japan, Holland and
Israel. A Danish-designed soymilk facility is under construction in
Khabarovsk, which will have a strong price advantage over expensive
imported baby food products.
The domestic market for other food products has been volatile, even
after the fall in the value of the ruble in August 1998. Competition
from U.S. chicken drumsticks had virtually wiped out local poultry
producers until the fall of the ruble in August 1998. For a brief period
after August 1998, Russians could not afford the U.S. chicken, and
Russian poultry factories began to work in full swing again. Later,
drumstick prices from the European Union dropped dramatically to compete
with local prices. It remains to be seen whether inefficient domestic
producers will remain competitive in the face of rising domestic
inflation and potential reductions in domestic tariffs on food imports.
Taxation
Farmers cite agricultural taxes, which they claim absorb from 68 to
90 percent of gross receipts, as a major burden. Land share owners who
were considering withdrawing their land to start a PFE feared taxes, as
much for their complexity as for their actual financial burden. Support
for a uniform tax appeared widespread. While former collective farms
have been able to maintain accountants, smaller PFEs often negotiate the
maze of financial obligations alone.
The Russian agricultural tax structure, which includes profit
taxes, value-added taxes, road fund taxes, income taxes, property taxes,
and land taxes, remains complex and discretionary. (41) The most
significant payments required of agricultural enterprises are the
compulsory deductions for extra-budgetary funds such as the pension,
social security, medical insurance, and public employment funds,
amounting to a total of 31.1 percent of gross revenues.
As a final note, tax enforcement appears inconsistent. While most
farmers deemed the tax burden onerous, we interviewed several peasant
farmers and managers on former collectives who had paid no taxes for
several years.
Labor
Low labor productivity also impedes agricultural production in the
new market system in the Russian Far East. Several enterprising farmers
complained that they had difficulty finding workers willing to labor
more than eight hours per day. Some PFEs in the Russian Far East hire
Chinese laborers to supplement their work force. These seasonal workers
usually work in exchange for a percentage of the crop, which they then
take with them to sell in China upon their return. The Chinese workers,
according to officials and farmers, are hardworking and willing to work
for lower wages than Russians. They often bring with them useful
techniques to maximize production. Particularly in soy and melon production, Chinese and Korean laborers have particular expertise. The
official numbers of such immigrants are relatively few, however. In
Khabarovsk, for example, officials reported that only 200-300 Chinese
agricultural workers participated in farming in 1998. There are severe
administrative restrictions on the use of foreign agricultural labor in
the local economy.
Immigrant laborers do not have the benefits of land tenure security
available to Russian farmers through ownership or long-term leases.
Russian law does not provide for foreign ownership of land. Furthermore,
at least some of the foreign laborers lack valid immigration documents,
increasing their vulnerability to low wages and reducing their security
in crop-sharing arrangements. A policy of leasing out land-fund land to
foreigner cultivators would be one way to increase the local food supply
and local government revenue.
Property Rights and Economic Development
While only six percent of the RFE population labors in the formal
agricultural sector, much of the variety in the local diet is provided
by households, which supplement low money income with small-scale
subsistence food production. The emergence of more efficient private
farming awaits national legislation on ownership of land and major
changes in the discretionary regulatory, management, and tax practices
of local government agencies.
Even without national legislation, policymakers in the RFE have the
power to make key changes in the way in which laws are implemented. Such
changes include:
* privatizing and/or leasing the large fund of land currently held
by the raion land funds, most of which is not in production;
* providing information and enforcement supporting the exercise of
land shares owned by farm households and used by large agricultural
enterprises. Such exercise may take the form of leasing, sale, or
small-scale production, but enforcement of rights is a crucial element
in this strategy;
* adopting policies to encourage foreign farmers with access to
capital to lease unused, nonprivatized land from the raion land funds.
Long-run improvement in agricultural productivity will require a
strengthening in property rights in land at the federal level. Federal
laws must:
* provide clear property rights in agricultural land, ensuring that
purchase and sale, lease, and inheritance of agricultural land are
clear, widely understood, and enforced at reasonable cost;
* amend the Law on Mortgage to allow the use of agricultural land
as collateral.
In the Amur River Valley, national boundaries place severe
constraints on use of fertile agricultural land. At the moment, there
seems to be no way to bring together the abundant land of Russia with
Chinese and Korean labor and capital. As an alternative to increased
international migration, a program of homesteading combined with modest
rural credits would allow households to relocate from the Russian Far
North and the former Soviet Republics to Russia's borderlands with
China.
Can Russia find a way to develop the fertile Amur River Valley and
border regions of Pacific Russia without placing political control of
the region at risk? Regional policymakers view with alarm both the
steady outflow of Russians from Pacific Russia and a prospective inflow of Chinese and Korean farmers and workers. Agriculture is one of many
sectors where the gap between actual and potential resource use creates
enormous incentives for institutional change, and yet the barriers to
needed change are enormous.
Prospects for Policy Change
In 2001, the Putin administration is drafting a new federal
Development Strategy for Pacific Russia (reminiscent of the era of Five
Year Plans.) Although the strategy is still in draft, its outlines for
agriculture draw on a federal document, Strategy for the Development of
the State to the Year 2010, prepared under the leadership of V.I.
Ishayev, Governor of Khabarovsk in November 2000. (42)
The Ishayev report gives the state primary responsibility in three
areas--the military-industrial complex, infrastructure, and agriculture.
It recommends, "Taking into account that one-third of the
population of Russia lives in rural areas, the state ought to provide
this population with direct financial assistance, with respect to
natural gas supplies, electrification, road construction, education and
health care." It should also address the monopoly practices of
agricultural processors and create a "civilized land market"
(not further defined. Thus, barriers remain to building a strong land
market through clear and enforceable property rights and increased
access to credit and capital. Without any changes, agriculture will
remain an Achilles heel in the Russian Far Eastern economy.
Table 1:
Total Sown Acreage in Southern RFE
Province 1985 1990 1995 1998
Total (Thous hectares)
Primore 433 389 358 345
Khabarovsk 163 61 61 71
Jewish Autonomous Republic n/a 94 90 70
Amur 1269 1096 728 575
Total 1865 1640 1237 1061
Soy (Thous hectares)
Primore 144 113 107 90
Khabarovsk 65 19 13 10
Jewish Autonomous Republic n/a 38 33 19
Amur 478 425 292 221
Total 687 595 445 340
Soy (%)
Primore 33.3 29 29.9 26.1
Khabarovsk 40 31.1 21.3 14.1
Jewish Autonomous Republic n/a 40.4 36.7 27.1
Amur 37.7 38.8 40.1 38.4
Total 36.8 36.3 36 32
Alexander Sheingauz, et. al. "The Competitive Position of the
RFE in NE Asia," in Thornton and Ziegler, ed. Region at Risk;
Security Implications of Political and Economic Developments
in the Russian Far East.
Table 2:
Amur Agricultural Output
(Thous Tons) 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
Grain 710 473 433 259 315 318.5 304.8
Potatoes 358 205 360 338 316.7 358.8 397.8
Vegetables 62 54 58 98 83.1 79.6 102.3
Soy 170.4 156.3 169.5 161.5
Meat (slaughter 62 51 42 31 26.5 26.4 21.8
weight)
Milk 355 330 264 232 236.3 217.2 203.3
Eggs (mil) 222 226 210 164 153.9 138.2 125.3
Goskomstat Rossii. Regiony Rossii 1999.
Table 3:
Primore Agricultural Output
(thous tons) 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
Crops 403 359 164 163 187 187 180.1
Potatoes 368 384 329 466 475.4 370 536.9
Vegetables 82 115 82 123 124.2 90.2 126
Meat (slaughter 52 46 39 28 26.9 21 18.7
weight)
Milk 278 270 228 182 164.9 149.8 146.1
Eggs (mil units) 471 405 383 361 349.9 295.3 260.4
Goskomstat Rossii. Regiony Rossii 1999.
Notes
(1.) Collectivization saw the forced relocation of rural peasants
from dispersed villages to a small number of state-controlled kolkhozes
(collective farms), logging camps, mines, and construction sites. (Bruce
Grant, In the Soviet House of Culture. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton
University Press, 1995, 92.) Stalin's fears of Japanese expansion,
lead to expulsion or forced relocation of East Asians from the region,
such as the removal of 135,343 Koreans on sixty trains from Vladivostok
in 1937-38. (John J. Stephan; The Russian Far East; a History. Stanford,
Ca: Stanford University Press, 1994, 191, 213.)
(2.) In 1990, the RFE had 761 sovkhozes, 84 kolkhozes, 1289
subsidiaries of industrial factories, plus 1.3 million individual farm
plots and 700,000 garden-farm associations. (Pavel Minakir, ed. The
Russian Far East; An Economic Handbook. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1994,
61.
(3.) Pavel Minakir, ed. The Russian Far East; An Economic Survey.
Khabarovsk: RIOTIP, 1996, 438-439.
(4.) Bradley J. Rorem and Renee Giovarelli, Agrarian Reform in the
Russian Far East. RDI Report 95 (October 1997), processed.
(5.) Goskomstat Rossii. Regiony Rossii 1999, Vol 2, 80.
(6.) Bulletin: Development of Economic Reforms in Primorskii Krai
from January to June 1997 (Primorskii Krai Committee on Statistics), 20;
Amur Region: Guidebook for Businessmen (Vostokincenter, 1994); The
Russian Far East: A Business Reference Guide, (3rd Ed., 1997-98)
156-157; As cited in Rorem & Giovarelli, op. cit.
(7.) Discussions with officials in Khabarovsk Krai and Amur Oblast
Land Committees (October 1999).
(8.) By the mid-1960s the Soviet government had expressed it
intention for a "massive" extension of agriculture in the RFE.
In 1967, it publicized a plan to reclaim 1.2 million hectares of swamp
land to create 75 state farms, manned by new immigrants. Despite initial
claims of success, this plan was never fully realized. It did, however,
result in substantial increases in area planted in grain and soy. E.
Stuart Kirby, The Soviet Far East 65-67 (1971). From 1986-1990, Soviet
policy again dictated an expansion of Far East agriculture through land
reclamation, resulting in an increase of 824,000 hectares, or 12 percent
of all agricultural land. Pavel A. Minakir, The Russian Far East: An
Economic Survey (1996).
By the 1980's state and collective farms in the former Soviet
Union cultivated an average of 5,400 hectares of land, which is enormous
by world standards. Collectives in the Far East were even larger,
frequently upward of 10,000 hectares. In comparison, Canada's farms
averaged about 242 hectares in size, while Finland's farms averaged
about 13 hectares, and in both countries nearly every farm was operated
by a single household. Rorem & Giovarelli, op. cit.
(9.) From 1986-1990, for example, the Soviet government spent 3.5
billion rubles (equivalent to $3.5 billion at the official exchange
rate) on the development of the agro-industrial complex of the Far East.
(Minakir, (1996) 97
(10.) Even when agriculture was more heavily subsidized by the
Soviet Union, it did not achieve yields at levels experienced by
non-collectivized agriculture in countries with agro-climatic conditions
similar to Russia. Between 1985 and 1989, state and collective farms of
the Russian Soviet Federated Socialist Republic (RSFSR) produced grain
yields averaging 1.7 tons per hectare. Grain yields in the RFE during
this period were 1.2 tons per hectare. Minakir, (1996) 438. During the
same period, Canada's farms produced an average of 2.2 tons per
hectare, and Finland averaged 2.7 tons per hectare. Id. (internal cites
omitted). Rorem & Giovarelli, op. cit.
(11.) Pavel Minakir. Dal'niy vostok rossii; ekonomicheskiy
potentsial. Vladivostok: Dal'nauka, 1999, 541.
(12.) See, e.g., the law of Russian Soviet Federated Socialist
Republic, "On the Peasant (Farm) Enterprise" (as amended
January 5, 1991) (giving collective farms, state farms and subsidiary
agricultural operations the right to divide up farmland among their
permanent members, and giving members and workers the right to leave
agricultural enterprises with their share of the land and property to
start peasant farms); Presidential Decree No. 323, "On Urgent
Measures for Implementation of Land Reform in the RSFSR" (December
27, 1991), art. 6 (requiring collective and state farms, and other
agricultural enterprises, to distribute land held in permanent use into
"private, collective-share, or other form of ownership in
accordance with the Land Code of the RSFSR"); Government Resolution
No. 86, "On the Procedure for Reorganization of Collective and
State Farms" (December 29, 1991) (clarifying the rights of
collective farm members, state farm workers, and pensioners to receive
land and property shares, and providing the size of the property share
would be based upon work contribution). Prosterman et al,
"Prospects for Family Farming in Russia," Europe-Asia Studies,
Vol. 49, Number 8 (December 1997) 1384-385.
(13.) Each land share on a particular enterprise is of equal size
and represents its holder's ownership, in common with the other
land share owners, of the land being used by the enterprise. Each
recipient of a land share was entitled to receive a land share up to the
`raion norm' for free distribution of land established by the raion
administration. (Raion norms were calculated by dividing the amount of
agricultural land in the raion by the entire rural population, rather
than using the smaller denominator of agricultural workers and
pensioners in the raion.)
(14.) Of particular relevance for the remainder of this paragraph
are articles 13-17 of the regulations, "On Reorganization of
Collective and State Farms and Privatization of State Agricultural
Enterprises" (approved by Resolution of the Government of the
Russian Federation No. 708 of September 4, 1992).
(15.) Farms also had the option of extending the categories of
people entitled to receive property shares to social sphere workers and
former employees.
(16.) Official from the Khabarovsk Krai Ministry of Agriculture
(for Khabarovsk); International Market_Insight Reports, interview with
Anatoly Bonetskii, head of State Committee on Land Resources and Land
Tenure for Amur (October 1999).
(17.) The Economic Research Service of the USDA estimated in 1997
that 75 percent of former state and collective farms in Russia were
unprofitable in 1995, even if all subsidies were included in revenue.
"International Agriculture and Trade: Newly Independent States and
the Baltics" (USDA: Economic Research Service, May 1997) (as cited
in Rorem & Giovarelli, op. cit., 32.
(18.) Presidential Decree No. 1212, "On Measures to Improve
the Collection of Taxes and other Mandatory Payments and Streamlining
Cash and Noncash Money Turnover" (August 18, 1996).
(19.) In 1997, for example, 62 enterprises in Khabarovsk Oblast
controlled 78,300 hectares of arable land, while 207 enterprises in Amur
Oblast controlled over one million hectares of arable land.
(20.) For legislative authority, see Presidential Decree No. 1767,
"On the Regulation of Land Relations and Development of Agrarian
Reform in Russia" (27 October 1993); Presidential Decree No. 337,
"On Realization of Citizens' Constitutional Rights to
Land" (March 7, 1996).
(21.) Russian Federation State Land Committee, 1996.
(22.) Data from Primorskii Krai (the second largest agricultural
region in the RFE) gathered in 1997 shows that nearly 45 percent of all
shares in this region (37,765 out of a total of 86,021 shares) are used
without consideration by agricultural enterprises. Of even greater
notice, as of 1997 Primorskii Krai had issued only approximately 45
percent of shares to entitled owners in the region. Rorem &
Giovarelli, op. cit., 16 (Table 5).
(23.) In areas of the RFE where livestock constitute the primary
agricultural production, requiring less land mass, the average size may
be smaller. In Khabarovsk Krai, for example, the average size of a PFE
was only 20 hectares in 1999.
(24.) Some of the recorded decrease in the number of peasant farms
may be attributed to de-registration of smaller farms to operate as
household plots rather than as PFE's. (Reasons to de-register
include tax advantages and less bureaucracy.) See, e.g., V. Ya. Usun,
Privatization of Land and Farm Restructuring: Ideas, Mechanisms,
Results, Problems 6, August 23, 1999. Rural Development Institute
working paper (processed).
(25.) Pavel Minakir. Dal'niy vostok rossii; ekonomicheskiy
potentsial. Vladivostok: Dal'nauka, 1999, 540-541.
(26.) One example of"superficial" or "cosmetic"
restructuring is a number of collective farms in Amur Oblast now
formally registered as PFE's. These farms, like other former
collectives now registered as joint stock companies, production
cooperations, or limited liability companies, have undergone no
meaningful managerial or structural change at all from the former
collective period. In some instances they re-registered as PFE's in
order to take advantage of certain low-interest credit opportunities
extended to PFE's during the initial reforms.
(27.) These findings are consistent with those reported throughout
Russia. A 1996 study showed that perhaps 95 percent of former collective
farms in Russia have "reorganized," most into shareholding
enterprises. However, these enterprises continue to be managed
internally like collective farms. Experience from the reform period has
shown that the collective nature of reorganized agricultural enterprises
is shed only when they divide into much smaller units. Karen Brooks,
Elmira Krylatykh, Zvi Lerman, Aleksandr Petrikov, and Vasilii Uzun,
Agricultural Reform in Russia: A View from the Farm Level, World Bank
Discussion Paper 327 (June 1996), at 2.
(28.) See especially regulations, "On Reorganization of
Collective and State Agricultural Enterprises," (Approved by
Resolution of the Government of the Russian Federation No. 708 of
September 4, 1992).
(29.) Data from Amurskaia oblast State Committee on Land Resources
and Land Tenure, October 1999.
(30.) In 1997 Khabarovsk had 65,000 hectares and Amur had 779,000
hectares of arable land in their respective land funds. Ibid.
(31.) Rorem and Giovarelli, Agrarian Reform in the Russian Far
East, 22-30.
(32.) In fact, legal authority for some land-monitoring activities
is lacking. Federal legislation includes irrational use, but not nonuse,
as a violation. See Rorem and Giovarelli, Agrarian Reform in the Russian
Far East, 23-30, for a detailed discussion of legislative authority for
land monitoring.
(33.) Evgenia Serova, "The Impact of Privatization and Farm
Restructuring in Russian Agriculture" (September 1999), 21.
(34.) The only sector in which a market in land turnovers is
functioning well in the RFE is the small plots (household auxiliary
plots, dacha plots, garden plots). A law adopted by the Russian
parliament in late 1992, complemented by a regulation on how to actually
carry out such sales issued in May 1993, has given potential buyers and
sellers high confidence in the legality of such transactions. As
mentioned above, the ability to freely transact small plots has probably
contributed to their high productivity.
(35.) Law of the Russian Federation, "On Mortgage" (June
24, 1997).
(36.) Law of the Russian Federation, "On the State
Registration of Rights to Immovables and Real Estate Transactions
"(June 17,1997); Resolution No. 1378 of the Government of the
Russian Federation "On Measures to Realize the Federal Law on State
Registration of Rights to Immovable Property and Transactions With It
"(November 1, 1998).
(37.) See, for example, V.Ia. Usun, "Privatization of Land and
Farm Restructuring," 5.
(38.) Figures from V.A. Uvarov, Agriculture of the Russian Far
East:Choosing the Form of Production, Rosseskogo Dalnego
Vostoka:Khabarovsk (1998), 315.
(39.) FT Asia Intelligence Wire, International Market Insight
Reports, October 21, 1998, 6.
(40.) Law of the Russian Federation "On the Consumer
Cooperative System in the Russian Federation" (July 1992).
(41.) Interview with Sergei Egorov, Chief Specialist on Peasant
(Farm)Enterprises, Khabarovskii krai Agro-Industrial Committee (October
18, 1999).
(42.) Strategy for the Development of the State to the Year 2010,
prepared by Presidium of the State Council of the Russian Federation (published in English by Executive Intelligence Review, Vol. 28, No. 9,
2 March 2001.)
Jennifer Duncan Rural Development Institute, Seattle, Washington
Michelle Ruetschle Rural Development Institute, Seattle, Washington