Internal Liberalization as a Barrier To Export-led Recovery in Central European Countries Preparing For EU Accession.
Frensch, Richard
I. Introduction
The EU's Agenda 2000 allows for the Union's eastern
enlargement, for which ten Central and East European countries have
applied so far: the seven current CEFTA members (Bulgaria, the Czech
Republic, Hungary, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, and Slovenia) and the
three Baltic states (Estonia, Latvia, and
Lithuania). For prospective new EU members the Agenda 2000 requires
(a) an established democratic system, (b) a workable market economy, (c)
the ability of the respective economies to withstand competitive
pressures from the EU once goods and factor markets are actually opened,
and (d) the acceptance of the EU's legal and regulatory framework.
As the applicants' current GDP levels average roughly one third of
the EU's in purchasing power parity terms, fast pre-accession
growth would tremendously ease the enlargement process.
With 1997 GDP shares of exports and imports of goods and services combined ranging from 56% (Poland) to 121% (Czech Republic), these
economies are textbook examples of small, open economies. But in spite
of an hitherto unprecedented liberalization of prices and foreign trade
regimes, export sector contributions to their GDP growth have generally
not exceeded the experience of OECD countries to a significant extent in
recent years.
This essay tries to answer this puzzle by combining two
transition-specific trends. First, accompanying the decline of formerly
oversized industrial sectors, the share of services in both employment
and GDP has been gradually increasing since the early nineties. This
economy-wide structural change represents a reallocation of resources out of former excess supply sectors into former excess demand sectors,
i.e., out of agriculture and industry into services following internal
liberalization (price liberalization and ease of market entry). This in
turn is largely a reallocation out of the tradables into the
non-tradables sector and thus diametrically differs from resource flows
envisaged in standard trade liberalization and structural adjustment
programs elsewhere in the world, which aim at redirecting resource flows
into the opposite direction [see, e.g., Sachs and Larrain (1993, pp.
667ff]. This transition-specific reallocation has helped to generate and
keep in motion a second transition-specific trend: a continuous
appreciation of the real exchange rate, which is independent of the
measure and varies with the chosen exchange rate regime only as a matter
of degree. This real trend appreciation has so far acted as a
significant barrier to a strong export-led recovery from the transition
recession, which should have been expected as a consequence of the
unprecedented price and foreign trade liberalization in these countries.
The general idea is thus very simple: (1) The higher the extent of
transition-specific reallocation of employment in the economy following
internal liberalization, the higher the real appreciation. (2) The
higher the real appreciation, the lower the export sector real growth
contribution. Combining (1) and (2) yields: An extensive
transition-specific reallocation of resources acts as a barrier to
export-led recovery from the transition recession. The following
sections try to disentangle this rough picture: Section II describes the
hitherto unprecedented speed and scale of the external sector
liberalization in selected transition countries, while section III
outlines their surprisingly unspectacular recent export sector
contributions to growth. Section IV links export sector growth
contributions to real appreciation, and sections V and VI close the
argument by relating real appreciation to economy-wide
transition-specific reallocation. Section VII concludes. While the
argument in sections II - V is supported mainly by graphical evidence,
section VI contains a regression analysis of the dynamics of real
exchange rates during transition, establishing a cet. par. positive link
between real exchange rates and transition-specific reallocation. This
procedure together with data availability dictates the selection of
country experiences presented in the various sections: While the
illustrative medium term presentation in sections II-V is confined to
the CEFTA-6 group (i.e., the current CEFTA members without Bulgaria),
estimations in section VI employ panel data available between 1991 and
1998 from all ten EU applicant countries mentioned above to provide
evidence on the short run impact of reallocation on real appreciation.
II. External liberalization
Tables 1A and B describe the process of foreign trade
liberalization in CEFTA-6 economies. Although the speed of
liberalization has not been the same everywhere--the rather gradual
development in Romania contrasts with the shock approach taken in former
Czechoslovakia--, speed and extent of this process have been
unprecedented so far: Starting out with a centrally planned external
sector in the late eighties, all CEFTA-6 countries have an essentially
liberal foreign trade regime by now.(1)
Table 1A: External sector liberalization indices for CEFTA-6
economies, 1989-94, according to de Melo et al. (1996)
1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994
Czech Republic, CR 0.0 0.0 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9
Slovakia, SR 0.0 0.0 0.8 0.9 0.8 0.8
Poland, PL 0.2 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9
Hungary, HU 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9
Romania, RO 0.0 0.1 0.3 0.6 0.7 0.8
Slovenia, SLO 0.5 0.7 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9
Table 1B: External sector liberalization indices for CEFTA-6
economies, 1994-97, according to EBRD (1994-1997)
1994 1995 1996 1997
Czech Republic, CR 4 4* 4* 4+
Slovakia, SR 4 4* 4* 4
Poland, PL 4 4* 4* 4+
Hungary, HU 4 4* 4* 4+
Romania, RO 4 4* 3 4
Slovenia, SLO 4 4* 4* 4+
Notes:
(1.) The EBRD definition of external sector liberalization has
changed slightly over the years, but has remained comparable over time;
1 marks the minimum, 4+ the maximum value. In de Melo et al. (1996) 0
denotes the lowest, 1 the highest possible value.
(2.) Both classification systems are mutually comparable, the
classification in de Melo et al. (1996) is partly based on the EBRD
classification system [cf. the discussion in de Melo et al. (1996,
Appendix)].
Sources: de Melo et al. (1996) and EBRD (1994-97).
The effects of this unprecedented foreign trade liberalization
visible so far have not been restricted to the immediate impact upon
domestic relative prices, which changed into the direction of
international relative prices. Foreign trade liberalization swiftly
resulted in a geographic reorientation of trade: Taken as a whole,
CEFTA-6 countries now experience a trade intensity with the EU that
almost matches intra-EU trade [see, e.g., UNECE (1998, No. 1, p. 134)].
This geographic reorientation is increasingly--albeit slower in
pace and to a different degree among countries--accompanied by a change
in the commodity structure of trade [for the following, cf. Eichengreen
and Kohl (1998)]: While the Czech Republic and Hungary have already been
rather successful at exporting technologically more sophisticated
products, Slovakia has so far retained its specialization in less
sophisticated products. Poland, Romania, and Slovenia represent
intermediate cases, with structural improvements varying strongly across
industrial export branches.
Summing up, it is by now the prevalent opinion that external sector
liberalization in transition countries has been unprecedented in scale
and speed with tangible effects on geographic orientation and commodity
composition of foreign trade. As a result, external liberalization has
so far cet. par. proved significantly growth enhancing for transition
economies [as demonstrated, e.g., by Fischer et al. (1998)] with a
growth effect in the same order of magnitude as that of privatization and institutional reforms (i.e., price liberalization and
competition).(2)
III. Export sector growth contributions
In the light of the liberalization recorded in the previous
section, one might expect strong positive impulses from the external
sector for CEFTA-6 countries recovering from their early transitional
recession that should significantly exceed the experience of
"normal" economies when recovering from "normal"
business cycle troughs. To render such a comparison, we examine the
"cumulative contributions of exports of goods and services to real
GDP growth" for two distinct groups of countries, i.e. OECD versus
CEFTA-6 countries, over a recovery period of three years following
either the most recent cyclical trough (for OECD countries) or the last
year of the transitional recession (for CEFTA-6 countries). We define
cumulative growth contributions of exports as total real GDP growth in
percentage points over these three years holding all other GDP
components constant over the same three years.(3) Figure 1 shows three
years cumulative real growth contributions of exports of goods and
services for OECD and CEFTA-6 countries against their degree of
international openness (measured by the GDP share of exports plus
imports).
[Figure 1 ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
As Figure 1 illustrates, export sector real growth contributions
increase with the degree of international openness for OECD countries.
For CEFTA-6 countries--with a sample of only six observations--this
relationship cannot be confirmed. Even more importantly, Figure 1 shows
that deviations of export sector real growth contributions (normalized
by the degree of openness) from the OECD average (as measured by the
indicated regression line) differ considerably across CEFTA-6 countries:
Significant large scale positive deviations may be detectable for
Romania but certainly not for the country group as a whole. One might
thus seriously question the a priori expectation that all CEFTA-6
countries' thorough external sector liberalization necessarily
resulted in extraordinary, positive export sector real growth
contributions. Obviously, the undisputed cet. par. growth effects from
external sector liberalization, stated in the previous section, have--to
a different extent among CEFTA-6 countries--been "eaten up" by
some other adverse effect on export growth contributions; the most
likely candidate, of course, is an appreciation of the real exchange
rate.
IV. Real exchange rate appreciation and export sector growth
contributions
External sector developments are closely related to real exchange
rate developments. This relationship may also be illustrated in the
framework of cumulative export sector growth contributions outlined
above. To that purpose Figure 2 contrasts cumulative export sector real
growth contributions (normalized by the degree of openness) over the
first three years of recovery from the transitional recession against
real appreciation over the same period. The real exchange rate is
proxied by two popular measures, i.e. (1) the nominal exchange rate against the DM deflated on the basis of consumer prices, and (2) local
wages expressed in US-$ (dollar wages). Independent of the real exchange
rate measure, cumulative export sector growth contributions appear to
decrease with the extent of real appreciation in this country group.
[Figure 2 ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
V. Links between internal liberalization, reallocation and real
appreciation
Two transition-specific trends dominate recent macroeconomic developments in Central European economies preparing for EU accession.
First, accompanying the decline of formerly oversized industrial
sectors, total employment in services has been gradually increasing
since the early nineties. Figure 3 illustrates this trend singling out
the two CEFTA-6 economies for which it has been most pronounced, i.e.
the Czech Republic and Slovakia.
[Figure 3 ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
This economy-wide transition-specific structural change represents
a reallocation of resources from former (i.e., under central planning)
excess supply into former excess demand sectors, especially from
agriculture and industry into services.(4) Figure 4 exemplifies the
(factor-) price sensitivity of this process for the Czech Republic and
Slovakia, the two CEFTA-6 economies that appear to have experienced this
structural change most prominently: The reallocation of labor between
sectors is accompanied by corresponding changes in relative wages.
[Figure 4 ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The second major trend these economies have experienced in recent
years is a continuous real exchange rate appreciation. Figure 5, again
singling out the Czech Republic and Slovakia, reveals this second trend
using the same real exchange rate proxies as Figure 2.
[Figure 5 ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Abstracting from unemployment (cf. footnote 4), one might relate
these two transition-specific trends, following an argument similar to
Grafe and Wyplosz (1997). Internal liberalization in a transition
economy, i.e., price liberalization and ease of market entry, encourages
the emergence and growth of the formerly under-supplied services sector.
As the services sector is at the same time a former excess demand sector
as well as the largest part of the economy's non-tradables sector,
this process is accompanied by a rise in the price of non-tradables
relative to tradables, i.e. a real appreciation. As shown in the
Appendix, our real exchange rate measures (nominal exchange rates
deflated by consumer prices and wages in foreign currencies) are closely
linked to the ratio of non-tradables to tradables prices in transition
countries if one assumes that the ratio of sectoral prices is
proportional to the ratio of sectoral unit labor costs.
The ratio of unit labor costs in the non-tradables sector relative
to those in the tradables sector is closely connected to the sectoral
reallocation of labor and increases during transition mainly for two
reasons: Starting from a disequilibrium, the reallocation of labor aider
internal liberalization is accompanied by a contemporaneous increase in
the relative wage in the non-tradables sector (as, e.g., illustrated in
Figure 4);(5) also [as argued e.g. in Grafe and Wyplosz (1997)], the
sectoral reallocation of labor induces a lagged restructuring response
of firms in the tradables sector implying decreasing unit labor costs in
the tradables sector relative to the non-tradables sector. This induced
productivity growth in the tradables sector should be differentiated
from exogenous sectoral productivity differentials in the
Balassa-Samuelson approach. The resulting trend real appreciation during
transition effectively curbs any export-led transformational recovery.
It should of course not go unnoticed that the internal
liberalization only revealed the disequilibrium in the sectoral
allocation of labor: This implies that real exchange rates of centrally
planned economies have been systematically undervalued prior to
transition. Accordingly, the reallocation effect on exchange rates
described above is a fundamental, equilibrium source of real exchange
rate developments.
VI. The short-term impact of sectoral reallocation on real
appreciation during transition
Naturally, any relationship between real appreciation and its
fundamental sources should be expected to become effective in the medium
and long term rather than in the short term, when nominal shocks
typically dominate real exchange rate movements. However, the
estimations presented in this section confirm that transition-specific
employment reallocation exerts a significant influence on short-term,
i.e. year-to-year, changes of the real exchange rate.
Estimations below are based on the common hypothesis that long-run
real exchange rates follow real labor productivity developments relative
to abroad [see, e.g. Halpern and Wyplosz (1997)], while in the short nm
the impact of nominal shocks dominate. While such a hypothesis might
usually call for an error-correction model that combines long-run
equilibrium relationships with short-run deviations, such a model
nevertheless does not seem appropriate in the situation under
consideration: First, 6 years of available data are rather short for
testing long-run relationships; second, the transition-specific
relationship between intersectoral reallocation and real appreciation
hypothesized above implicitly rules out that real exchange rates
"on average" realize their equilibrium level during
transition. Consequently, only a short-term estimation approach is taken
under the hypothesis that even in the short run real exchange rate
movements during transition react to productivity changes and employment
reallocation as well as, of course, to nominal shocks. As derived in the
Appendix, estimation equations for different measures of the real
exchange rate can therefore be reduced to:
(1) [rer.sub.i](j,t)= [c.sub.o] + [c.sub.1] [multiplied by]
cpi(j,t-1) + [c.sub.2] [multiplied by] a (j,t) + [c.sub.3] [multiplied
by] ls(j,t) + [c.sub.4] [multiplied by] ls (j,t-1) + [c.sub.5]
[multiplied by] ERR (j,t) + e(j,t),
for country j in year t, where:
[rer.sub.i], = 1,..,4: Real exchange rate; the four real exchange
rates measures used are the nominal exchange rates against the DM and
US-$ deflated on the basis of consumer prices and dollar and DM wages,
cpi: Consumer price index,
a: Aggregate labor productivity, i.e., GDP per total employment
(including self-employed),
ls: Share of service sector employment in total employment
(including self-employed),
[rer.sub.i], cpi, and a are yearly rates of change measured in
percent; ls measures the change of shares in percentage points.
ERR: Exchange rate regime dummy; ERR = 1, for periods and countries
with a fixed exchange rate or controlled floating, ERR = 0, otherwise
(i.e., for free floating or crawling pegs).
e: error term.
Estimations of equation (1) employ panel data from all ten EU
applicant countries named in the introduction, i.e., the seven CEFTA
countries plus the Baltic countries, for the period 1991-98. Episodes of
more than double-digit inflation were excluded from the sample; exchange
rate data for Baltic countries are available only for 1993 onwards (for
Estonia) or 1994 onwards (Latvia and Lithuania). Estimation is done by
OLS enriched with exchange-rate regime specific dummy variables. Due to
the limited number of observations, especially per individual country,
exchange rate regimes are classified into only two groups with
comparable effects upon real exchange rate developments, i.e. fixed
exchange rates and controlled floating versus crawling pegs and free
floating. To deal with remaining panel data specific heteroskedasticity
problems, White's correction for heteroskedasticity is employed.
The results, presented in Table 2, are compatible with the apriori
expectations formulated in the Appendix. Especially, they confirm a
positive and (with one exception) significant short-run influence of
intersectoral employment reallocation upon real exchange rate movements,
a faster impact of reallocation on wage-based real exchange rate
measures than on price-based real exchange rate measures, and a stronger
short-run impact of total productivity changes on wage-based real
exchange rate measures than on price-based real exchange rate measures.
Table 2: Yearly rates of change of four real exchange rate
measures: all ten EU applicant countries, 1991-98
Nominal Nominal DM wages US-$
exchange exchange wages
rate aga- rate against
inst the the US-$
DM (cpi- (cpi-
deflated) deflated)
constant -5.7(*) -13.80(***) -12.49(**) -20.29(***)
(-1.70) (-3.94) (-2.05) (-3.44)
cpi(-1) 0.25(***) 0.41(***) 0.27(**) 0.42(***)
(2.81) (6.57) (2.40) (4.46)
a 0.24 0.18 1.78(**) 1.78(**)
(0.64) (0.47) (2.66) (2.59)
ls 2.46(*) 3.53(***)
(1.87) (3.12)
ls(-1) 0.88 1.91(**)
(1.04) (2.63)
ERR 8.06(***) 9.35(***) 13.20(***) 15.01(***)
(3.00) (3.44) (3.37) (3.97)
# of obser-
vations 53 53 52 52
[R.sup.2] 0.34 0.56 0.36 0.49
[R.sup.2]
adj. 0.28 0.53 0.31 0.45
DW 1.83 2.23 1.71 1.78
Notes: 1. OLS with heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors
and covariances; 2. t-values in parentheses. 3.(*) ((**), (***)) denote significance at 10 (5, and 1) per cent levels, respectively.
Data sources: Cf. Figures 2 and 3.
VII. Conclusion: Intersectoral employment reallocation as a barrier
to export-led recovery in transition
The paper links two trends observable in transition economies,
i.e., continuous resource reallocation and trend real exchange rate
appreciation: An extensive transition-specific reallocation of resources
from former excess supply sectors, such as industry and agriculture
(i.e., mostly tradables production), to former excess demand sectors,
specifically market services (i.e., mostly non-tradables production),
acts as a barrier to export-led recovery from the early transitional
recession in Central and Eastern European countries preparing for EU
accession. As it was the internal liberalization that put
transition-specific reallocation of employment into motion, it is
consequently internal liberalization that cet. par. limits the growth
stimulus from external liberalization. Of course, as internal
liberalization only revealed the previous disequilibrium in the sectoral
allocation of labor, one might soften this view by holding the (extent
of the) previous disequilibrium responsible rather than liberalization.
To some extent, observers have concentrated on the microsphere when
looking for reasons behind real exchange rate appreciation during
transition and potentially resulting currency overvaluation. Especially
in the case of the Czech currency crisis of May 1997 the most popular
suspect is an allegedly misspecified privatization strategy: the Czech
voucher privatization scheme of the early nineties which failed to
result in effective corporate control in privatized industry, thus
allowing an ever widening gap between wages and productivity to open up,
is held responsible for real exchange rate appreciation.
While this paper argues that transition-specific intersectoral
resource reallocation may significantly be responsible for at least some
portion of real exchange rate trend appreciation in transition
economies, in the sense of Blanchard's (1997) definition of
transition as reallocation and restructuring this is no contradiction to
the quoted micro-based view; transition firms' micro problems with
equalizing wage pressures and productivity changes (differing in extent
across countries and industries) may rather be attributable to a
transition-specific employment reallocation that is not equally strong
across transition countries.
Finally, it has repeatedly been stated that macroeconomic policy
measures (including price and trade liberalization) are not sufficient
for a successful transition. With its special emphasis on foreign sector
growth contributions, this view is strongly supported in this paper:
Again resorting to Blanchard (1997), one might conclude that the first
transition phase, i.e., resource reallocation out of former excess
supply into excess demand sectors, works as an inevitable barrier
against a post-transition export-led recovery, given the initial
disequilibrium allocation of labor. Permanent growth impulses from
foreign trade should thus be expected only from the second, presumably longer transition phase of firm-level restructuring.
Notes
(1.) For an interesting attempt at relating this fast
liberalization to a transition-specific political perspective, see
Wunner (1998).
(2.) In Fischer et al. (1998) external liberalization,
privatization, and other institutional reforms are measured by three
respective liberalization indices provided in de Melo et al. (1996),
where the external liberalization index is the one shown in Table 1A of
this paper. Alternative regressions of each of these (highly correlated
indices) plus other explanatory variables on yearly GDP growth rates of
25 transition economies between 1992 and 1995 yield estimated
coefficients for the three indices that are of the same order of
magnitude.
(3.) The formula for calculating three years cumulative real growth
contributions of real exports E is thus CGC(E) = (E(j+3) -E(j))/GDP(j),
with j denoting the year of the most recent cyclical trough (for OECD
countries) or the last year of the transitional recession (for CEFTA
countries).
(4.) We abstract from unemployment during transition. Rather, we
stress direct reallocation between (tradable and non-tradable) sectors,
where we broadly identify these sectors with state-owned or privatized
agriculture and industry versus a newly emerging private services
sector. So far, most transition models [most prominently Blanchard
(1997)] have assumed that the major source of the emerging private
sector employment is unemployment from industry restructuring. But, as
noted e.g. in Brixiova (1997), this would either imply a quickly
emerging private sector together with short-lived unemployment or a
slowly emerging private sector together with persistent unemployment;
contrary to this, transition economies have experienced quickly emerging
private sectors combined with persistent unemployment, which is
compatible with the explanation that private sector firms hire directly
from industry, i.e. that the most significant labor flows are directly
from industry into services.
(5.) For a sample of fourteen OECD countries, Strauss (1997) is
able to show that for periods of less than five years wage differentials between the non-tradables and the tradables sector can raise
intersectoral price differentials and therefore cause real appreciation,
thus invalidating the assumption of intersectoral wage equalization featuring prominently in the Balassa-Samuelson approach to real exchange
rate movements. For countries in transition, one might therefore expect
intersectoral wage differentials to cause a continuous real appreciation
at least as much as for OECD countries.
(6.) Cf., e.g., Halpern and Wyplosz (1997, p. 441) or Strauss
(1997, p. 392).
(7.) Again, see Halpern and Wyplosz (1997, pp. 438ff.)
References
Blanchard, Olivier. 1997. The Economics of Post-Communist
Transition, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
BMWi (German Federal Ministry of Economy). 1995-99. Wirtschaftslage
und Reformprozesse in Mittel- und Osteuropa. Sammelbande 1995-99,
BMWi-Dokumentationen, Berlin.
Brixiova, Zuzana. 1997. "On the speed of transition in Central
and Eastern Europe: Does on-the-job search matter?," IMF Working
Paper 97/102, Washington, D.C., August.
De Melo, Martha, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb. 1996. "From
plan to market: Patterns of transition," Policy Research Department
Working Paper No. 1564, The World Bank, Washington, DC.
EBRD. 1994-97. Transition Reports 1994-1997, London.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Richard Kohl. 1998. "The external
sector, the state, and development in Eastern Europe," CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1904, London.
Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos A. Vegh. 1998. "From
transition to market: Evidence and growth prospects," IMF Working
Paper No. 98/52, Washington, DC, April.
Grafe, Clemens, and Charles Wyplosz. 1997. "The real exchange
rate in transition economies," CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1773,
London, December.
Halpern, Laszlo, and Charles Wyplosz. 1997. "Equilibrium
exchange rates in transition economies," IMF Staff Papers, 44, 4,
December, pp. 430-61.
International Financial Statistics on CD-Rom (IFS), IMF,
Washington, DC, various issues.
Prasad, Eswar S., and Jefferey Gable. 1998. "International
evidence on the determinants of trade dynamics," IMF Staff Papers,
45, 3, September, pp. 401-39.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Felipe Larrain B. 1993. Macroeconomics in
the Global Economy, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice Hall.
Strauss, Jack. 1997. "The influence of traded and nontraded
wages on relative prices and real exchange rates," Economics
Letters, 55,3, pp. 391-5.
Wunner, Norbert. 1998. "Trade liberalization and political
support in transition economies," Economics of Transition, 6, 2,
pp. 409-25.
United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE). 1998.
Economic Survey of Europe, No. 1, New York and Geneva.
Appendix
In equation (1) in section VI we regress rates of change of various
exchange rate measures on nominal disturbances (proxied by lagged
inflation), aggregate productivity growth and sectoral reallocation of
labor (proxied by the change of the share of services employment). To
motivate regression equation (1), we define price-based measures of the
real exchange rate as
(A-1) [RER.sub.P] = P [multiplied by] e/P*,
where P (P*) is the home (foreign) price level and e is the nominal
exchange rate (expressed as units of foreign per home currency, i.e., an
increasing e denotes a nominal appreciation of the home currency). In
general, P may be consumer (CPI) or producer prices (PPI). In our
context, foreign countries are the US and Germany.
Wage-based measures of the real exchange rate are simply
(A-2) [RER.sub.W] = W [multiplied by] e,
where W is nominal wages at home. [RER.sub.W] is thus measured as
US-$ or DM wages.
We assume that
(i) Prices (CPI or PPI) may be expressed as a combination of
tradables and non-tradables prices according to(6)
(A-3) ln P = (1-[Alpha]) ln [P.sub.T] + [Alpha] ln [P.sub.NT],
T (NT) denoting tradables (non-tradables).
(ii) All prices are proportional to unit labor costs, i.e.
(A-4) [P.sub.T] = [[Beta].sub.T] [W.sub.T]/[A.sub.T] and [P.sub.NT]
= [[Beta].sub.NT] [W.sub.NT]/[A.sub.NT],
where A is labor productivity.
(iii) Movement of non-tradables prices is unrestricted by
purchasing power parity; for tradables, purchasing power parity is
relaxed due to the existence of a product quality differential,
(A-5) [P.sub.T] = [Kappa] [multiplied by] [P.sub.T] */e,
where k [is less than] 1 describes product quality differences
between goods produced in transition economies versus abroad.(7) We
assume kappa to grow with aggregate labor productivity,
(A-6) [Kappa] = [A.sup.[Gamma], [Gamma]] [is greater than] 0
(iv) Foreign prices are treated as constant. This simplification
reflects the fact that during the period under consideration inflation
rates in transition countries are of a different order of magnitude than
in the US or Germany. As we are interested in rates of change only,
foreign prices are neglected in the following.
Accordingly, from (A-1), assumption (iv) and inserting (A-5),
ln [RER.sub.P] = ln P + ln e = ln P + ln kappa - ln [P.sub.T].
From (A-3) and (A-6),
(A-7) ln [RER.sub.P] = [Gamma] ln A + [Alpha]
ln([P.sub.NT]/[P.sub.T]).
Using (A-4), we similarly derive,
ln [RER.sub.W] = ln W + ln e = ln P + ln A + ln [Kappa] - ln
[P.sub.T] or--again via (A-3) and (A-6),
(A-8) ln [RER.sub.W] = (l+[Gamma]) ln A + [Alpha]
ln([P.sub.NT]/[P.sub.T]).
In general, the [P.sub.NT]/[P.sub.T]-ratio in (A-7) and (A-8)
should respond to (1) exogenous sectoral productivity differentials
(assuming sectoral wage equalisation as in the Balsassa-Samuelson
approach), (2) sectoral reallocation (assuming wage differentials), and
(3) nominal shocks and their different impacts on [P.sub.NT] versus
[P.sub.T] depending upon the chosen exchange rate regime (assuming weak
PPP for tradables, as in assumption (iii)). As argued already in section
V, sectoral reallocation is deemed to have influenced the
[P.sub.NT]/[P.sub.T]-ratio much more pronouncedly than exogenous
sectoral productivity differentials in transition countries so far: By
(A-4), the price ratio [P.sub.NT]/[P.sub.T] is proportional to
([W.sub.NT]/[A.sub.NT])/([W.sub.T]/[A.sub.T]) and is thus closely linked
to the sectoral reallocation of labor during transition: At the
beginning of transition, excess wages in the unrestructured tradables
sector imply ([W.sub.T]/[A.sub.T]) [is greater than]
([W.sub.NT]/[A.sub.NT]), as the non-tradables sector was quickly
privatized wiping out potential excess wages there. The relationship
([W.sub.NT]/[A.sub.NT])/([W.sub.T]/[A.sub.T]), however, increases during
transition mainly for two reasons: We know that--starting from a
disequilibrium--liberalization induced reallocation of labor is
accompanied by a contemporaneous increase in the relative wage in the
non-tradables sector [W.sub.NT]/[W.sub.T] (as, e.g., illustrated in
Figure 4); also [as argued e.g. in Grafe and Wyplosz (1997)], sectoral
reallocation of labor induces a lagged restructuring response of firms
in the tradables sector implying a decrease in [W.sub.T]/[A.sub.T]
relative to [W.sub.NT]/[A.sub.NT]
Proxying nominal short-run disturbances by lagged inflation,
aggregate productivity growth by the rate of change of GDP per total
employment and sectoral reallocation of labor by the change of the share
of services employment, while capturing the exchange rate regime with a
dummy variable, we arrive at the regression equation (1) in section VI.
In general, we should expect a faster impact of labor reallocation
on wages and thus on wage-based real exchange rate measures than on
prices and price-based real exchange rate measures. In addition,
comparing (A-7) and (A-8), we should apriori expect a stronger short-run
impact of total productivity changes on wage-based real exchange rate
measures than on price-based real exchange rate measures. The results in
Table 2 fulfill these expectations.
Richard Frensch
Department of Economics Osteuropa-Institut Munchen
Without implicating, the author is grateful to Andrea Boltho,
Laszlo Halpern, Michael Keren, Holger Wolf, an anonymous referee and the
editor for critical comments on earlier versions of the paper.