Econometrics of Income Distribution: Toward More Comprehensive Specification of Institutional Correlates.
Durham, J. Benson
Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: B40, C50,
D33
1. Introduction
Many social scientists argue that certain economic and political
"institutions" affect economic outcomes. Perhaps following
North and Thomas (1973), the most developed literature in this genre
focuses on the effect of institutions on growth and investment as an
extension of or an alternative to the neoclassical model. For example,
econometric and qualitative studies evaluate the relative economic
efficiencies of dictatorships and democracies (Barro, 1996; Przeworski
and Limongi, 1993; Durham, 1998 and 1999), labor market centralization (Garrett and Lange, 1985 and 1986; Alvarez, Garret and Lange, 1991;
Hicks, 1994; and Headey, 1970) and fiscal federalism (Weingast, 1993).
Unfortunately, fewer theoretical and empirical studies address the
relationship between these institutional variables and income
distribution. While the literature and econometrics on regime-type and
income equality is comparatively extensive (Sirowy and Inkeles, 1990),
there is a dearth of evidence regarding other institutions that quite
conceivably affect income distribution, particularly labor market
organization and fiscal federalism. Put differently, previous studies
suffer from specification bias with respect to institutions. Such error,
as Bollen and Jackman suggest in a previous institutional inquiry,
"not only misrepresents the relationship directly involved but also
biases the remaining coefficients that are being estimated (1985, p.
441)." In short, given Deininger and Squire's (1996) recent
advances in data collection, this paper endeavors toward a more
comprehensive specification using both cross-sectional/time-series
(panel) and time-series econometric designs.
Section 2 outlines the arguments regarding regime-type, and Section
3 discusses labor market organization and fiscal federalism. Section 4
reviews common economic determinants, and Section 5 comments on the data
and empirical design. Section 6 presents the econometric results from
the panel design as well as time-series equations for Taiwan, the United
Kingdom and the United States. Section 7 concludes.
2. Regime-Type
Economists and political scientists alike debate the relative
economic efficiencies of regime-types. The most noted inquiry addresses
whether democracies or dictatorships better promote growth and
investment. Very briefly, the primary causal concept in this literature
concerns the relative utility of executive discretion or freedom of
action. According to the authoritarian view, dictatorships better govern
economies because they are not susceptible to the "political
business cycle"--democracies must spend scarce resources to win
elections. The democratic view contrarily argues that democracies solve
the veritable "credible commitment problem." Democratic
procedures check arbitrary (and kleptocratic) sovereigns and thereby
secure property rights.(1)
2.1. Theory and Evidence on Regime-Type and Income Distribution
With respect to income distribution, while there are some
dissenters, a majority of scholars argue that democracies are more
sensitive to pressures among the polity to redress unequal distribution
of resources. Similar to the debate on capital allocation and
accumulation, the causal mechanism similarly addresses discretion or
freedom of action, which is notably a continuous and not a dichotomous variable. Democracies are vulnerable because they must win votes to
lengthen tenure, and therefore vote maximizers redistribute scarce
resources to the majority. This rationale closely relates to the
reformist objective to extend the democratic franchise beyond property
owners--conservatives oppose extending political rights to protect
privileged economic: groups. Due to their (comparative) inclination toward majoritarianism and solicitation of the mean voter, democracies
more likely represent lower income groups than dictatorships.
Moreover, authoritarian regimes, presumably and particularly those
buttressed by the wealthy, are more insulated from popular egalitarian demands and thus less apt to redistribute income. In fact, rather than
focus on the majoritarian nature of democracy, which is quite
objectionable given the routine occurrence of coalition governments
(Bollen and Jackman, 1985, p. 440), another key facet of the democratic
view is that particular dictatorships exacerbate material inequalities.
Perhaps Marx's The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte and
classical Marxists interpretations of "fascism" are seminal exemplars. Autocrats possess the potential to pursue policies that
suppress a majority in favor of a select minority, because no political
mechanism holds them accountable. Scholars associated with
"dependency theory," for example, suggest that dictators
collaborate with multi-national corporations to develop industrial
enclaves bereft of satisfactory backward linkages (Evans, 1979). Bollen
and Jackman cite Brazil in the 1960s, Chile under Pinochet, Iran under
the Shah, as well as more traditional monarchies that purportedly fit
such a pattern, including Nepal and Saudi Arabia (1985, p. 439).
The dissenting view argues that authoritarian regimes more ably
redistribute wealth because material inequalities worsen political
inequalities in democracies. As Beitz (1982) argues, democratic
institutions do not adequately represent the poor, and therefore the
system does not effectively redistribute resources. Less affluent
citizens cannot take advantage of electoral mechanisms, he reasons, as
economic inequalities reproduce and exacerbate political inequalities.
Poorer groups lack either class consciousness or effective
organizational representation. Close to an agnostic perspective, while
they do not necessarily endorse authoritarian regimes, some Marxist
versions argue that the political system is irrelevant because it simply
reflects the interests of the capitalist class. Thus, democracies per se
scarcely address inequalities. As Jackman and Bollen (1985) note, a more
benign view of capitalist development argues that technology shapes the
distribution of material and political resources simultaneously, which
suggests that any empirical regularity between regime-type and income
distribution is spurious.
Turning to empirical evidence, Perotti (1996) finds some data to
support the prevailing democratic view. Democracies in general have more
equal distributions of income, which implies that polyarchies redress
income inequality via the "political mechanism." But another
finding besets this conclusion--the "income effect." That is,
more developed countries also have more equal distributions of income,
at least according to the imposed functional form of the level of
development. The most advanced countries, as widely noted, are
democracies, and therefore Perotti (1996), Sirowy and Inkeles (1990, pp.
134-36) and others cannot distinguish the democracy and income effects
on income distribution. For example, Perotti finds that "if one
splits the sample of countries into rich and poor, the results mimic
those obtained when splitting the sample into democracies and
non-democracies (p. 20)." This largely conforms to the
"technological perspective" and the "skeptical
model" that Sirowy and Inkeles characterize, as "any
association between democracy and socioeconomic equality is spurious
since both are determined by the level of a nation's economic
development (1990, p. 136)."
But these entangled effects are perhaps due to economists' and
other social scientists' near ubiquitous treatment of regime-type
as a dummy variable. Simply, the dichotomous treatment of regimes is too
narrow, as subtypes of democracy and dictatorship quite conceivably
better redistribute resources, as the previous discussion of particular
authoritarian forms suggests. In addition, the critical underlying
concept of discretion--or insulation from pressures for more equitable
income distribution in this case--is a continuous and not a dichotomous
variable. Sovereigns do not simply lack or possess freedom of action.
Rather, there is a continuum across space and time.
2.2 Regime-Type Measures
The following econometric analysis alternatively considers two
types of regime-type proxies. The first refers to commonly used ex post
outcome proxies that endeavor to capture myriad political and social
aspects of "democracy," a concept with several meanings. The
second regards ex ante institutional measures that isolate subtypes of
dictatorships and democracies that facilitate or inhibit income
equality. Rather than endorse any particular proxy, the primary aim of
this paper is; to include different outcome and institutional measures
to enhance the sensitivity analysis.
2.2.1. Ex Post Measures: The Freedom House and Gastil Indicators
Among outcome proxies, the Polity III measures employ nine
indicators of "institutionalized authority characteristics."
These indicators, in turn, endeavor to capture three concepts: "the
influence dimensions of authority," "the recruitment of chief
executives" and "government structure (Jaggers and Gurr, p.
470)." Another measure in this genre, perhaps most popular, is
Gastil's dual indices of "political" and
"civil" rights from Freedom House. Political rights refer to
the "capacity of individuals to participate freely and effectively
in the selection of policy-makers and binding decision rules affecting
the national, regional and local community." Civil rights "are
defined by the freedom of individuals to develop views, institutions and
personal autonomy apart from the state (Jaggers and Gurr, p. 474)."
Again, while economists routinely construct dummy transformations
to capture the effect of regime-types, commentary on the ordinal forms
of these indices is instructive(2). Regressions that include ordinal
expressions capture the degrees of executive discretion, but scholars
should interpret unit changes in both variables carefully. As Clague et
al. note, the indices capture outcomes of processes rather than
"defining features or requisites ora democratic political system
(1996, p. 251)." Few comparative economists or political scientists
have an intuitive understanding of ordinal differences across cases
according: to either scale. More importantly, policy entrepreneurs
cannot replicate such outcomes, but they can purport to craft procedural
institutions that distribute resources more effectively.
2.2.2. Toward an Ex Ante Measure: The Effective Party/
Constitutional Framework Proxy
The Gastil and Polity III indicators are subjective outcome proxies
that serve a variety of research objectives. As an alternative rather
than a substitute, a continuous, objectively measurable index should
substantively distinguish democratic and authoritarian regime subtypes.
The focus of such an alternative is on institutions; rather than
outcomes, which thereby addresses the implicit serviceable concern
regarding whether constitutional framers can craft regimes more disposed
to income equality. In other words, the quantitative inputs to the proxy
more directly refer to constitutional choices.
Briefly(3), the institutional measure incorporates both the number
of "effective" political(4) parties and the constitutional
framework, which refers to the relative position of the executive
vis-a-vis legislative branches of government(5). The fewer parties in
government, the more discretion the regime has in policy-making.
Importantly, the measure focuses on institutions and constitutional
crafting because electoral laws, from the very stipulation of the
existence of elections to combinations of
"first-past-the-post" and proportional representation systems,
have a direct effect on the number of parties(6). Moreover, framers
directly stipulate the constitutional framework, a real choice among
"parliamentary," "presidential,"
"authoritarian," and combinations thereof.
In addition to the effective party/constitutional frameworks
measure, dummy variables that follow Linz and Stepan and Skach (1993)
also explore that possibility of empirical regularities between income
distribution and certain subtypes of democracy. While these dummy
variables do not capture a continuum of discretion, this alternative
nevertheless addresses the purported "perils" of presidential
democracy (Mainwaring, 1993).
To briefly summarize the focus of these institutional proxies, the
effective party/constitutional framework measure distinguishes both
authoritarian and democratic subtypes and purports to capture the
"political mechanism" through which governments process
popular demands for income distribution. Among dictatorships, given that
ideal parties "mobilize" or "channel" political
sentiment from the polity(7), then the more embedded party would be more
responsive to popular demands for redistribution(8). Thus, exclusively
considering dictatorships, policy-makers in one-party regimes enjoy less
discretion than their counterparts in party-less regimes. This
measurement addresses Barro's (1996) recent observation that there
is no econometric distinction among dictatorships. Moreover, the party
distinction isolates dictatorships most disposed to perpetuating
inequalities. Among democracies, the effective party/constitutional
framework measure and dummy variables for parliamentary and
non-parliamentary systems measure distinguish pluralistic regimes where
the Polity III and Gastil measures do not. Therefore, given potential
collinearity between the level of development and democracy, the measure
enables tests of whether certain subtypes of pluralistic regimes more
effectively promote equality.
A possible shortcoming of the ex ante proxy might concern internal
party discipline with respect to dictatorships. Importantly, by
definition parties do not constrain policy-makers from without in
single-party systems. However, the single party might more likely
contain heterogeneous sects or factions, thereby making within party
discretion less acute compared to multiparty systems in which equally
disparate factions might simply form an additional party. In short, this
qualification might imply a "blip" in the interval between one
and additional parties in the continuous proxy. On the other hand,
democratic polities perhaps influence participating parties to adopt
more pluralistic self-governance. Consider the opposition's common
accusation in contemporary British politics, for example, that Blair
runs (New) Labour like Lenin or even Stalin governed the Communist
Party. After all, a literally, bloody "night of the long
knives" seems far more likely to occur in a dictatorship compared
to a democracy, which would ultimately suggest considerable within party
discretion in authoritarian regimes. Unfortunately, either way, the
continuous effective party/constitutional framework measure does not
capture this possibly problematic distinction. But again, inclusion of
the ex ante proxy in addition to the outcome measures does not
necessarily imply an endorsement of the former but a more thorough
sensitivity analysis of the (purported) effect of political regimes.
2.2.3. Alternative Functional Forms
Whatever the particular merits of each proxy, the continuous nature
of policy-maker discretion suggests three hypotheses using each measure.
First, the relation between regime-type and income distribution might be
linear, which perhaps becomes less intuitive after certain values in the
independent variable. One might question whether there is a constant
slope effect after some critical number. Thus, failure to accommodate
diminishing marginal returns recommends a linear-log form that tests
whether the beneficial effect on income distribution becomes less
pronounced, or "tails off" after some general threshold.
Finally, the quadratic or U-shaped form tests whether there is an
optimal ordinal value.
3. Additional "Institutions": Labor Markets and Fiscal
Federalism
In addition to a more comprehensive assessment of regime-type
proxies, another problem with previous studies is the omission of other
related factors. "Regime" ultimately refers to the methods of
access to the state, which in turn quite conceivably relates to other
institutions that affect income equality. Unfortunately, the literature
does not test for these institutional variables, which broadly describe
the organization of the economy, and is therefore susceptible to
specification bias.
3.1. Labor and Partisan Ideology: The Social Democratic Corporatist Model
For example, the organization of labor unions in a given country
quite conceivably influences income distribution. After all, more
equitable distribution of scarce resources is the raison d'etre of
trade unions. Also, commentators commonly associate "left
government partisanship," which describes the ideological
composition of the state, with more equitable distribution of income
among the working classes.
Quantitative literature on labor relations and the partisan
characteristics of developed democracies, "the social democratic
corporatist model (SDC) of national economic performance (Hicks, 1994,
p. 190)," is abundant (Garrett and Lange, 1985 and 1986; Alvarez,
Garret and Lange, 1991; Hicks, 1994; and Headey, 1970). Briefly, rather
than income distribution, this perspective largely addresses growth and
investment--strong labor organization and centralization leads to higher
capital accumulation and growth, provided such labor structures attend
"Left" partisan government tenure.
The SDC perspective focuses on two concepts. The first is how to
characterize the labor market. Garrett and Lange argue that
"centralized and dense unions ... appear conducive to the
development of concertation between unions, employers' associations
and government." Regulation of union behavior in the market both
"promotes and is promoted by" a "virtuous circle" of
economic policy (1985, p. 793). In this cycle, labor must realize the
potential gains from wage restraint and not disrupt the flow of
investment.
Partisan composition of government is the second consideration, as
the interaction between union organization and government policy affects
macroeconomic performance. In contrast to, say, a scenario with strong
labor organization and Left control of government, countries with
relatively weak labor movements combined with governments of the
"Right" can still "pursue their partisan preferred
macroeconomic strategies and achieve similarly beneficial macroeconomic
outcomes (Alvarez et al., 1991, p. 539)." Crafts similarly suggests
that "it must also be recognized that the effects of industrial
relations structures are contingent on political circumstances (1992, p.
25)." In less compatible scenarios, trade unions less willingly
show wage restrain and are more apt to behave militantly given a
confrontational partisan government. An interaction term captures this
dynamic, as the expression, momentarily ignoring other regressors, is
(1) Y = [[Beta].sub.0] + [[Beta].sub.c]C + [[Beta].sub.p]P +
[[Beta].sub.c,p](C x P) + [Mu]
where Y is some macroeconomic performance variable, C is the union
centralization index, P is the "Left" partisanship measure,
and [b.sub.c,p] captures the interaction. Alternatively, Garrett (1995)
adds C and P to capture "left labor power," with no
interaction term, as in
(2) Y = [[Beta].sub.0] + [[Beta]c+p](C + P)+ [Mu].
Whether in (1) or (2), dense labor organization and Left
partisanship should translate into more equitable income distribution,
regardless of the regime-type mechanism, because unions help transfer
wealth from owners to workers, and Left governments typically purport to
represent lower income groups(9). The interaction term, however, more
likely has a less pronounced impact, as conventional wisdom would
suggest that governments of the Right and weak labor organizations
should lead to greater inequality, regardless of the purported
benevolent effect on growth and investment(10).
3.2. Fiscal Federalism
A third institutional consideration besides regime-type and labor
organization regards "fiscal federalism," which ultimately
refers to the abstract concept of multiple "sovereignty" among
central and local governments. Qualitative research on this variable
largely concerns economic expansion, but the organization of local and
central governments quite conceivably affects income distribution. A
very brief review of the economic performace argument is instructive.
Weingast claims that "market preserving" federalist organization of the state promotes economic growth. Departing from the
"credible commitment problem," Weingast's
"fundamental political dilemma of an economic system" is that
"a government strong enough to protect property rights is also
strong enough to confiscate the wealth of its citizens (1993, p.
287)." Democratic government is not enough to assuage sovereign
temptation to renege on property rights. Federalism more thoroughly
induces such constraint. The "decentralization of political
power" alleviates the credible commitment problem because "no
government or jurisdiction has a monopoly over regulation of the market,
(which) induces political competition among jurisdictions, competition
that limits the ability of any one state to impose debilitating regulation." In his empirical investigation, Weingast argues that
federalism enhanced the economic development of(quite curiously)
Britain(11) and the United States, and more recent work with Qian
applies the concept to contemporary China vis-a-vis former communist
Eastern Europe (1997, p. 86).
Returning to this research question, which Weingast does not
address, the effect of federalism on income distribution primarily
addresses territorial inequalities. In many cases, regional income
disparities exist within countries. For example, the southern regions of
Italy and Spain are considerably less affluent than northern areas. With
respect to theory, dependency theorists argue that "enclaves"
of capitalist development naturally emerge in less developed nations.
Also, the widely observed discrepancy between urban and rural areas in
less developed areas, germane to Kuznet's trajectory hypothesis as
discussed in the following section, necessarily implies regional
considerations. Simply, a higher degree of fiscal federalism implies
that these lesser developed regions by definition have less resources
with which to redress, inequalities given the (poor) local tax base.
Less centralization suggests that national governments transfer fewer
resources across regions. Under these assumptions, federalism has a
negative effect on income distribution.
The following equations employ two proxies that measure two
different aspects of fiscal federalism. With respect to the first
measure, as Lijphart (1984, p. 177-78), Oates (1972, p. 18), Casella and
Frey (1992, p. 643), and Kee (1977, p. 80) suggest, the most valid
approximations of fiscal federalism include the fractions of total
revenues collected and total expenditures allocated by' the
national government. Given these hypotheses, the revenue federalism
measure should have a negative impact on income distribution, as
decentralized national governments do not have the resources to address
regional inequalities by transferring wealth from affluent to poorer
areas.
The second measure of fiscal federalism regards the mismatch between spending and taxation levels. In some cases, spending is
decentralized while taxation remains a responsibility' of central
government. According to Garrett, such gaps between spending and revenue
encourage fiscal irresponsibility and therefore poor macroeconomic
performance. But this phenomenon should have a positive impact on income
distribution. A large gap between local spending and revenue suggests
that local governments spend fewer indigenous resources, which increases
the possibilities for significant resources transfers across regions.
The proxy is local spending minus; local revenues, divided by total
government revenues(12), as in
(3) [G.sub.federal] = [E.sub.l] - [R.sub.l]/[R.sub.l] + [R.sub.c]
where [E.sub.l] is local expenditure, [R.sub.l] is local revenue,
[R.sub.c] is central revenue, and [G.sub.federal] is thus the federal
spending gap(13).
4. Economic Determinants
To summarize the discussion of institutional variables, the dual
effects of income and democracy on income distribution bedevil
economists who only employ dichotomous regime variables. Furthermore,
inclusion of other variables that describe the organization of the
economy explores how the broader institutional framework might affect
income distribution. These tests more effectively specify the mechanisms
through which institutions affect income distribution and advance a more
comprehensive model relevant to normative economists.
But institutional variables are not the only determinants of income
distribution. Similar to econometric studies of economic growth (Levine
and Renelt, 1992), there is no universal consensus or "true
model" of empirical correlates of income distribution. This
specification includes regional dummies, a quadratic functional form of
the initial per capita level of GDP the government spending ratio,
population growth, and openness to international trade(14). Each factor
should be described briefly in turn.
The regional variables refer to the observation that Latin American
and African countries, which have also grown more slowly, have less
equal distributions of income than other areas. Similar to Barro's
(1996) inclusion of regional variables in growth regressions, such
specification suggests that these dummy variables have some effect
irrespective of the other determinants, but the precise causal process
is ambiguous.
The quadratic form of the initial level of national income is a
proxy for Kuznets' argument about the effect of urbanization.
According to Kuznets, urbanization purportedly effects income
distribution because urban areas are "characterized by more
inequality relative to rural areas, but also by higher percapita
income." Perotti explains that the combination of these effects
implies that "urbanization increases inequality in lower levels of
development, but inequality decreases as countries continue to grow
(1996, p. 14)." While "urbanization" is a particular
component of "modernization," to clearly distinguish the
concept from the general level of economic development is difficult, and
both Kuznets' and Perotti's diction in fact seems to confound the two concepts. Therefore, along with the poor temporal coverage of
the World Bank figures for urbanization, which is suitable for
Perotti's (1996) pure crosssectional design, the quadratic
expression of initial level of GDP is a reasonable proxy given the
unclear distinction. Again, the quadratic form, which Bollen and Jackman
(1985, p. 441) employ, suggests a negative effect on equality as income
increases from comparatively lower levels and a positive effect as
income increases from higher levels.
Another control variable is the share of government spending to
total national income. This factor purports to capture the extent to
which government supply responds to subject population demand. The
hypothesis is that a government more involved in the economy generally
is more likely to specifically pursue income distribution through fiscal
policy. An alternative approach is to include population demographics,
such as the share of the population over 65 years of age. Inequality and
income, the argument reasons, are lower among retirees, and the demand
for social security increases as the population ages (Perotti, 1996).
But to include such demographic figures assumes that governments in fact
respond to such demands for redistribution. Insensitive to that
assumption, the government ratio considers the actual supply of
government involvement.
The specification in this paper also includes population growth,
but not in the context of popular demand for government policy. Briefly,
increased birth rates increase inequality because different income
groups grow at different rates, as poorer segments of the population
increase more quickly, thereby increasing the proportion of lower income
groups. As Bollen and Jackman summarize, another facet of this
consideration is that high population growth generally by definition
accompanies higher fertility and lower mortality, which produces a
younger population age structure among low-income groups (1985, p. 443).
This second aspect complements Perotti's suggestion that income
distribution is more even among older populations, but again, the
emphasis is not on the demand side.
Finally, this specification of income distribution includes
openness to international trade. Most commonly, the factor addresses the
notion that free trade puts downward pressure on wages for lower skilled
workers. But, this variable is also germane to the debate in comparative
political economy about international influences and policy-making. As
Gourevitch (1978) suggests, international politics affects domestic
political structures, and the system has unit-level consequences--world
politics affects internal policy choices. Briefly, in addition to the
standard argument about wages, countries that are more open to trade and
the international economy enjoy less policy discretion ceteris paribus.
Such limits on policy choice might inhibit redistributive policies, as
the French Socialists "right-turn" in the early 1980s under
Mitterand illustrates. Moreover, the proxy is also germane to dependency
theorists who argue that exposure to the world economy leads to the
development of enclaves and indigenous under-classes. In short, given
each of these varying rationales, the hypothesis suggests that openness
worsens income inequality.
5. Data Disabilities
Before presentation of the results, detailed commentary on the data
set is imperative. As scholars ubiquitously state in any empirical
investigation of income distribution, to measure inequality is difficult
because much of the evidence depends on the accuracy of public surveys,
which are considerably less reliable in poorer countries. Furthermore,
there are distinctions between income and wealth, pre- and post- tax
income, wage and non-wage earnings and individuals and households that
complicate both temporal and spatial measurement. The regressions in
this paper use Deininger and Squire's (1096) data set.
Deininger and Squire cite three methodological issues that
distinguish income distribution studies, for which this study controls.
The first regards the difference between surveys based on household or
individual data, and the authors find that "using the distribution
of income across; households rather than persons as the basis for the
Gini index results in a slightly lower value." But given the
magnitude of the difference, approximately 1.69 without controls,
Deininger and Squire conclude that "there is no reason to expect a
large systematic bias in empirical work as a result of using both
household-based an individual-based Gini coefficients (1996, p.
580)." The second distinction between surveys based on before- and
after-tax data also potentially biases the estimates. Assuming that
taxation redistributes resources from rich to poor, coefficients from
after-tax surveys should be lower ceteris paribus(15). Deininger and
Squire note, however, that the quantitative importance of the difference
depends on both the progressive nature and effectiveness of the given
tax system. They suggest that the effect is less pronounced in poorer
countries because "the role of redistributive taxation is smaller
in these countries (1996, p. 580)." The most important distinction
according to Deininger and Squire is between income- and
expenditure-based coefficients. Given that expenditure is based on net
income after taxes and other expenses, coefficients should be lower than
those based on gross figures, and their data render a 6.6 difference
between expenditure and income-based coefficients.
Therefore, in addition to the economic variables, the controls also
include dummy variables for the three distinctions based on household,
tax and income data sources, which ensures that the remaining
coefficients in the specification hold irrespective of the different
survey procedures(16). This precaution roughly resembles Bollen and
Jackman's design that includes a dummy variable for the
household/individual distinction (1985, p. 442).
6. Econometric Results
6.1. Panel Regressions
FGLS random-effects(17) pooled regressions, which include
continental and time-specific dummy variables(18) to control for
temporal effects, test spatially dominant panel designs, and the
following empirical section on time series results addresses the
unbalanced nature of the panels.
Turning to the panel results, Regression 1 is the base equation
without institutional determinants, and some findings notably contradict persistent hypotheses. For example, the coefficients for the quadratic
form of the level of income clearly contradict Kuznet's thesis, as
the model produces a global minimum of approximately $15,433 in per
capita income. This result suggests that the Gini coefficient decreases
(income distribution improves) as income approaches the critical point,
to the right of which the measure increases (income distribution
worsens). This contradicts the view that inequality increases in the
initial stages of development, but then improves during later phases.
Also surprising, population growth correlates with more equitable income
distribution, which is significant at the 10 percent level.
Some findings are consistent with enduring hypotheses. For example,
openness to international trade seems to worsen income inequality, which
might support the common view of wage pressures, dependency theory or
simply the more general view that increased exposure to the world
economy constrains (redistributive) social policy. Also consistent with
theory, the coefficient for the government ratio enters the equation
with the expected negative sign, as increased involvement in the economy
correlates with decreases in the Gini coefficient(19). Also as expected,
the regional dummies enter with characteristic signs, as Africa, the
Americas and Asia have more uneven income distributions compared to
Europe(20).
Finally, control dummies for the underlying data sources produce
the expected signs and magnitudes, especially regarding expenditure
data, which renders Gini coefficients approximately 6.4 lower on
average, and personal income data, which renders figures about 1.5 lower
on average. These parameters compare with the respective 6.6 and 1.7 raw
means in the data set that Deininger and Squire report, and the dummy
for pre- and post-tax is insignificant.
Turning to single-institutional equations, the Polity III dummy
variable for "democracy" supports the prevailing regime-type
perspective(21). According to Regression 2, democracies have Gini
coefficients on average approximately 1.1 lower than dictatorships,
ceterisparibus and notably including the income effect, which is
significant at the 10 percent level. Ordinal forms of the Policy III
scale do not produce more accurate estimates, as the linear, linear-log
and quadratic expressions are all statistically insignificant according
to Regressions 3 through 5. To address data source sensitivity, the
Gastil dummy in Regression 6 also suggests that democracies have more
egalitarian income distributions, but the figure is less robust and
notably insignificant. The three functional forms of the ordinal Gastil
measure also produce insignificant results according to Regressions 7
through 9.
The effective party/constitutional framework measure strongly
suggests that there is no relationship between regime-type and income
distribution. For example, no functional form of the number of effective
parties is significant according to Regressions 10 through 12. Also,
contrary to theory, single-party dictatorships do not affect more even
distributions of income as the insignificant coefficient in Regression
13 is positive. Also, dummy variables for constitutional frameworks in
Regressions 14 and 15 suggest that there is no difference among
parliamentary and presidential democracies and the: residual
authoritarian category. In general, these results imply that policy
entrepreneurs and constitutional framers cannot craft methods of state
access that compel more equitable income distribution.
But besides regime-type, again, other institutions are also
important, and the regressions produce some unexpected results. For
example, while the coefficients for SDC variables largely have the
expected signs in Regressions 16 and 17, with the notable exception of
the interaction term, none is statistically significant. This casts
doubt on the intuitive perspective that strong labor movements and
"Left" governments effectively achieve their stated
egalitarian objectives.
Also, the revenue based federalism measure significantly correlates
with income distribution but with the unexpected sign. As Regression 18
indicates, a 10 percent increase in the local revenue proportion
corresponds with an approximate 0.6 lower Gini coefficient, which is
safely significant. This contradicts the expectation that centralization
leads to effective redistribution across disparate regions. The
insignificant but unexpectedly positive coefficient for the federal
spending gap in Regression 19 similarly vitiates the hypothesis.
Besides data quality, which unfortunately besets any econometric
study of income distribution, the previous equations likely suffer from
institutional specification bias. Therefore, the final panel equation
exercise regresses Gini coefficients on every linear combination of
institutional variables: each functional form of the number of effective
parties, SDC expressions (1) and (2), and the two fiscal federalism
considerations. Regression 20 is the model that explains the most
variance in income distribution in the limited sample, and the results
confirm the empirical relationship between the federal revenue ratio and
income distribution. The more "complete" specification
suggests that a 10 percent increase in the ratio corresponds with
approximately 0.9 lower Gini coefficients. Also, the more comprehensive
equation confirms the univariate single-institution models that
regime-type, labor organization and government partisanship do not
correlate with income inequality.
6.2. Individual Time-Series Equations: Taiwan, the United Kingdom
and the United States
As previously noted, the panel regressions are unbalanced. The
primary difficulty in the design, although Deininger and Squire hardly
preclude such evaluation, regards the inconsistent temporal coverage.
Nonetheless, a pooled design is still arguably the best strategy for
general, sweeping inferences because, after all, variation in the
exogenous variables through time across space should summarily affect
income distribution. But to address these shortcomings with an
alternative approach, this section presents individual time-series
estimations for three countries with an adequate number of consecutive
observations(22). In addition to a broadening the sensitivity, analysis,
such a strategy might also address uneasiness associated with spatially
defining and comparing certain "institutions," such as
"political party," "federalism" or "centralized
labor organization," across such a vast array of countries. Most
important, however, these regressions might usefully suggest future
qualitative research that thoroughly describes idiosyncrasies of
economic and political institutions that affect equality in particular
countries.
The equation for Taiwan that explains the most variance, Regression
21, does not clearly support common institutional or economic hypothesis
regarding income distribution. Although the sign is positive, the
KMT's fluctuating dominance, which ranged from approximately 1.16
to 1.24 effective parties during 1972 to 1992 did not have a
demonstrative quantitative effect on income distribution. Curiously, the
only statistically significant regressor is population growth, which,
contrary to the hypothesis, correlated negatively with the Gini
coefficient at the 10 percent level of significance.
Data for the United Kingdom generally support the SDC perspective
Regression 22 suggests that decreased labor organization and Right-wing
partisanship worsened income distribution from 1966 to 1990. This
reflects common characterizations of the Thatcher years, 1979 to 1990,
which witnessed steadily increasing inequality and partisanship. In
fact, the lowest Gini coefficient is for 1977 under Labour, and the
figure steadily increased to the greatest value in 1990 under 11 years
of Tory rule. A problem with this summation is that the statistically
significant interaction term suggests that cohesion between Right-wing
government and weaker labor movements, perhaps pigeonholing "Thatcherism" for some commentators, also improved income
inequality. In addition, the British case confirms the correlation from
the panel regressions regarding the federal revenue ratio, which
increased in the early 1970s and decreased in the late 1980s in Britain.
Finally, the significant quadratic form of the number of effective
parties curiously suggests that income distribution worsened until
approximately 2.1 parties and improved with greater values, as the
figure fluctuated from about 2.02 during 1966 through 1969 to 2.17
during 1987 through 1990. Also, openness to international trade, which
peaked in 1974, correlated negatively with the Gini coefficient, in
contrast to the base panel regression finding and the common notion
regarding wage pressures.
Although inequality similarly increased steadily from 1966 to 1990,
the American case does not corroborate the institutional findings with
respect to Britain. Regression 23, which best fits the variance in
income distribution in the United States, suggests that the federal
spending gap, which peaked in 1982, correlated positively with the Gini
coefficient, in contrast to the hypothesis. Also, two findings suggest
that the United States does not conform to the base income distribution
panel equation, Regression 1. First, increased government involvement in
the economy curiously correlated with greater inequality, and, second,
increased openness to international trade correlated with more equality,
similar to the equation for the United Kingdom.
7. Conclusions
Again, the specifications do not posit a single "true"
model of income distribution but more closely resemble an informal
sensitively analysis of the effect of regime-type and other key
institutions. The most robust conclusion among the institutional
considerations regards fiscal federalism, as the results suggest that
more decentralized countries correlate with greater equality, all things
being equal. This finding, however, contradicts the view that greater
centralization corresponds with more equitable income distribution due
to resource transfers across disparate regions or to centralized
redistributive policy aims. Also, among the more conspicuous ambiguous
findings, regime-type does not seem to affect income distribution, and,
surprisingly, most data produce no correlation between SDC variables and
equality.
To speculate on further research, the general dearth of robust
relationships in econometric models could reflect the assumption of
homogenous expectations. In short, similar to studies of regime-type and
growth, statistical designs do not sufficiently consider the ideology or
beliefs of the very policymakers who operate vis-a-vis institutions(23).
In short, assuming some "correct" measure of the complete
ensemble of relevant institutions, policy--makers with varying ideas can
pursue varying economic objectives that lead to different and unintended
results. Two single-party dictators, for example, can purse equitable
income distribution or contrarily protect economic elites. Likewise,
democracies produce a wide variety of governing parties with myriad
objectives. Thus, econometric models of income distribution assume
homogenous expectations among economic policy-makers. While the SDC
partisanship scale does cover the most advanced countries, most
regressions, do not satisfactorily capture these differences.
Econometrically incorporating "ideas" is difficult, but
some interaction term with institutions might better represent the
"true" form. That is, income distribution depends on the joint
coincidence of some optimal configuration of discretion and the
sovereigns' objective to redistribute resources. As suggested
elsewhere (Durham, 1998), the equation, momentarily ignoring other
economic factors, might resemble
(4) Y = [[Beta].sub.0] + [[Beta].sub.ib](I x B) + [Mu]
where the effect of the given set of institutions, I, largely
depends on prevailing beliefs, represented by B. Conversely, the impact
of I depends on the magnitude of B. The coefficient, then, [b.sub.ib],
captures the coincidence of institutional and ideology.
Besides the difficulty associated with classifying economic
ideology, this approach might treacherously approach endogenous selection. Identifying those governments that "truly" intend
to redistribute income but fail to do so would be difficult. However,
the prevailing assumption of homogenous expectations in these models
might help explain the dearth of compellingly robust findings for
institutional variables. Also, as the discussion of time-series
equations suggests, perhaps case studies that include such "thick
description" of the interaction between ideas and economic as well
as political institutions would be instructive.
[TABULAR DATA 1-2 NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Table 3
The Effective/Party Constitutional Framework Measure FGLS
Random-Effects Models 1960-1992
Regression 13:
[Beta] p value
Squared Effective Parties
Log Effective Political
Parties
Effective Political Parties -0.112 0.617
(Critical Point)
Initial GDP Squared 2.99E-08(**) 0.011
Initial GDP -0.001(**) 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 17079
Government Ratio -0.116(**) 0.028
Population Growth -0.532(*) 0.068
Openness to Trade 0.013 0.212
Dummy for Africa 13.070(**) 0.000
Dummy for Central 8.008(**) 0.000
and North America
Dummy for South 11.681(**) 0.000
America
Dummy for Europe -6.803(**) 0.001
Dummy for Oceania 0.370 0.932
Dummy for Expenditure -8.238(**) 0.000
Dummy for Personal -1.798(**) 0.001
Income
Dummy for Tax 0.601 0.370
Intercept 49.190(**) 0.000
Observations 548
Cases 80
Average Time Periods 6.850
[R.sup.2] Within 0.210
[R.sup.2] Between 0.571
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.519
[Chi square] 245.630
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 43.440
Prob. Hausman [Chi square] >0 0.368
Regression 14:
[Beta] p value
Squared Effective Parties
Log Effective Political -0.075 0.320
Parties
Effective Political Parties
(Critical Point)
Initial GDP Squared 2.95E-08(**) 0.012
Initial GDP -0.001(**) 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 17127
Government Ratio -0.115(**) 0.029
Population Growth -0.534(*) 0.066
Openness to Trade 0.013 0.208
Dummy for Africa 13.111(**) 0.000
Dummy for Central 8.145(**) 0.000
and North America
Dummy for South 11.721(**) 0.000
America
Dummy for Europe -6.838(**) 0.001
Dummy for Oceania -0.305 0.944
Dummy for Expenditure -8.313(**) 0.000
Dummy for Personal -1.770(**) 0.001
Income
Dummy for Tax 0.688 0.307
Intercept 48.852(**) 0.000
Observations 548
Cases 080
Average Time Periods 6.850
[R.sup.2] Within 0.213
[R.sup.2] Between 0.568
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.519
[Chi square] 245.150
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 32.180
Prob. Hausman [Chi square] >0 0.836
Regression 15:
[Beta] p value
Squared Effective Parties -0.021 0.801
Log Effective Political
Parties
Effective Political Parties -0.007 0.988
(Critical Point) -0.170
Initial GDP Squared 2.99E-08(**) 0.011
Initial GDP -0.001(**) 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 17147
Government Ratio -0.117(**) 0.027
Population Growth -0.513(*) 0.080
Openness to Trade 0.013 0.205
Dummy for Africa 13.028(**) 0.000
Dummy for Central 7.992(**) 0.000
and North America
Dummy for South 11.668(**) 0.000
America
Dummy for Europe -6.742(**) 0.001
Dummy for Oceania -0.366 0.932
Dummy for Expenditure -8.181(**) 0.000
Dummy for Personal -1.818(**) 0.001
Income
Dummy for Tax 0.580 0.391
Intercept 49.096(**) 0.000
Observations 548
Cases 080
Average Time Periods 6.850
[R.sup.2] Within 0.209
[R.sup.2] Between 0.573
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.521
[Chi square] 248.630
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 22.420
Prob. Hausman [Chi square] >0 0.994
Notes: (*) 10 percent confidence interval
(**) 5 percent confidence interval
Table 4
Single-Party and Party-less Dictatorships and Constitutional
Frameworks Dummy Variables FGLS Random-Effects Models
Regression 13:
1962-1992
[Beta] p value
Dummy for Dictatorship
Dummy for Parliamentary
Dummy for Presidential
Dummy for Mixed
Dummy for Semi-Presidential
Single-Party 0.186 0.920
Dictatorship
Initial GDP Squared
Initial GDP 0.001(**) 0.009
(Income Critical Point)
Government Ratio -0.026 0.739
Population Growth 1.860(**) 0.041
Openness to Trade 0.000 0.996
Dummy for Africa 10.655(**) 0.000
Dummy for Central and 15.329(**) 0.000
North America
Dummy for South America 22.539(**) 0.000
Dummy for Europe -8.202(**) 0.001
Dummy for Oceania
Dummy for Expenditure -1.354 0.508
Dummy for Personal Income -1.543 0.349
Dummy for Tax -0.829 0.565
Intercept 35.074(**) 0.000
Observations 123
Cases 40
Average Time Periods 3.075
[R.sup.2] Within 0.112
[R.sup.2] Between 0.856
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.860
[Chi square] 497.210
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 11.530
Prob. Hausman [Chi square] >0 1.000
Regression 14:
1960-1992
[Beta] p value
Dummy for Dictatorship 0.320
Dummy for Parliamentary -0.320 0.687
Dummy for Presidential -1.247 0.168
Dummy for Mixed -1.125 0.847
Dummy for Semi-Presidential -5.117(*) 0.006
Single-Party
Dictatorship
Initial GDP Squared 2.74E-08(**) 0.018
Initial GDP -0.001(**) 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 17770
Government Ratio -0.113(**) 0.032
Population Growth -0.608(**) 0.038
Openness to Trade 0.012 0.229
Dummy for Africa 13.401(**) 0.000
Dummy for Central and 8.179(**) 0.000
North America
Dummy for South America 12.351(**) 0.000
Dummy for Europe -6.878(**) 0.001
Dummy for Oceania -0.596 0.893
Dummy for Expenditure -8.957(**) 0.000
Dummy for Personal Income -1.816(**) 0.001
Dummy for Tax 0.790 0.232
Intercept 49.351(**) 0.000
Observations 549
Cases 80
Average Time Periods 6.863
[R.sup.2] Within 0.237
[R.sup.2] Between 0.553
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.504
[Chi square] 251.910
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 46.110
Prob. Hausman [Chi square] >0 0.345
Regression 15:
1960-1992
[Beta] p value
Dummy for Dictatorship 0.687
Dummy for Parliamentary
Dummy for Presidential -0.927 0.427
Dummy for Mixed -0.804 0.890
Dummy for Semi-Presidential -4.796(**) 0.015
Single-Party
Dictatorship
Initial GDP Squared 2.74E-08(**) 0.018
Initial GDP -0.001(**) 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 17770
Government Ratio -0.1113(**) 0.032
Population Growth -0.608(**) 0.038
Openness to Trade 0.012 0.229
Dummy for Africa 13.401(**) 0.000
Dummy for Central and 8.179(**) 0.000
North America
Dummy for South America 12.351(**) 0.000
Dummy for Europe -6.878(**) 0.001
Dummy for Oceania -0.596 0.893
Dummy for Expenditure -8.957(**) 0.000
Dummy for Personal Income -1.816(**) 0.001
Dummy for Tax 0.790 0.232
Intercept 49.030(**) 0.000
Observations 549
Cases 80
Average Time Periods 6.863
[R.sup.2] Within 0.237
[R.sup.2] Between 0.553
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.504
[Chi square] 251.910
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 42.130
Prob. Hausman [Chi square] >0 0.509
Notes:
(*) 10 percent confidence interval
(**) 5 percent confidence interval
Table 5
SDC Variables and Fiscal Federalism FGLS Random-Effects Models
Regression 16: Regression 17
1966-1990 1966-1990
[Beta] p value [Beta]
Federal Spending Gap
Federal Revenue Ratio
SDC Labor Organization -0.156 0.750
SDC Partisan Index -0.409
SDC Interaction Term 0.380
SDC Left-Labor Power -0.422
Initial GDP Squared 4.21E-08 0.135 3.30E-08
Initial GDP -0.001(*) 0.094 -0.001
(Income Critical Point) 14078 14471
Government Ratio -1.313 0.115 -1.283
Population Growth -0.023 0.832 -0.082
Openness to Trade -0.088(**) 0.000 -0.084(**)
Dummy for Africa
Dummy for Central and
North America
Dummy for South
America
Dummy for Europe
Dummy for Oceania
Dummy for Expenditure
Dummy for Personal -8.557(**) 0.000 -7.917(**)
Income
Dummy f or Tax 1.722(*) 0.056 1.588(*)
Intercept 46.523(**) 0.000 45.457(**)
Observations 159 159
Cases 13 13
Average Time Periods 12.231 12.231
[R.sup.2] Within 0.088 0.115
[R.sup.2] Between 0.796 0.779
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.692 0.695
[Chi square] 283.260 282.970
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 160.910 154.700
Prob. Hausman [Chi
square]> 0 0.000 0.000
Regression 18:
1960-1992
p value [Beta] p value
Federal Spending Gap
Federal Revenue Ratio -5.608(**)
SDC Labor Organization
SDC Partisan Index 0.343
SDC Interaction Term 0.323
SDC Left-Labor Power 0.146
Initial GDP Squared 0.265 4.64E-08(**) 0.014
Initial GDP 0.196 -0.002(**) 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 19922
Government Ratio 0.129 1.360(*) 0.069
Population Growth 0.490 0.063 0.316
Openness to Trade 0.000 -0.036(**) 0.005
Dummy for Africa -7.333(**) 0.000
Dummy for Central and -5.385(**) 0.000
North America
Dummy for South -3.651(**) 0.000
America
Dummy for Europe 14.627(**) 0.000
Dummy for Oceania 4.633(**) 0.000
Dummy for Expenditure 9.786(**) 0.000
Dummy for Personal 0.000 3952(**) 0.(i)02
Income
Dummy f or Tax 0.086 3.60(*) 0.051
Intercept 0.000 48.792(**) 0.000
Observations 264
Cases 39
Average Time Periods 6.769
[R.sup.2] Within 0.084
[R.sup.2] Between 0.824
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.747
[Chi square] 641.400
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 117.000
Prob. Hausman [Chi
square]> 0 0.000
Regression 19:
1960-1992
[Beta] p value
Federal Spending Gap
Federal Revenue Ratio
SDC Labor Organization
SDC Partisan Index
SDC Interaction Term
SDC Left-Labor Power
Initial GDP Squared 5.01E-08(**) 0.008
Initial GDP -0.002(**) 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 20298
Government Ratio 1.014 0.181
Population Growth 0.112(*) 0.084
Openness to Trade -0.032(**) 0.011
Dummy for Africa -9.184(**) 0.000
Dummy for Central and -5.535(**) 0.000
North America
Dummy for South -3.278(**) 0.001
America
Dummy for Europe 17.150(**) 0.000
Dummy for Oceania 4.040(**) 0.001
Dummy for Expenditure 10.003(**) 0.000
Dummy for Personal 3.171(**) 0.035
Income
Dummy f or Tax 4.595(**) 0.010
Intercept 47.323(**) 0.000
Observations 262
Cases 38
Average Time Periods 6.895
[R.sup.2] Within 0.066
[R.sup.2] Between 0.841
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.740
[Chi square] 610.240
Prob. [Chi square] > 0 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 100.920
Prob. Hausman [Chi
square]> 0 0.000
Notes:
(*) 10 percent confidence interval
(**) 5 percent confidence interval
Table 6
Complete "Institutional" Specification and Individual
Time-Series Equations: Taiwan, the United Kingdom, and the United States
Regression 20: Regression 21:
Taiwan
1966-1990 1972-1992
[Beta] p value [Beta]
Squared Effective Political
Parties
Log Effective Political - -1.983 0.246
Parties
Effective Political Parties 16.732
(Critical Point)
Federal Spending Gap
Federal Revenue Ratio -8.769(**) 0.004
SDC Labor Organization 0.173 0.735
SDC Partisan Index -0.465 0.290
SDC Interaction Term 0.431 0.257
SDC Left-Labor Power -0.353
Initial GDP Squared 2.99E-08 0.307
Initial GDP -0.001 0.185 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 15983
Government Ratio -0.080 0.503 0.749
Population Growth -1.268 0.125 -3.925(*)
Openness to Trade -0.071(**) 0.000 0.002
Dummy for Expenditure
Dummy for Personal -9.811(**) 0.000
Income
Dummy for Tax 0.631 0.545
Intercept 52.326(**) 0.000 5.619
Observations 157 19
Cases 13
Average 12.077
Time Periods
[R.sup.2] Within 0.128
[R.sup.2] Between 0.823
[R.sup.2] Overall 0.719
[R.sup.2] 0.439
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.223
[Chi square] 307.720
Prob. [Chi square] > 0.000
Hausman [Chi square] 300.600
Prob. 0.000
Hausman [Chi square]> 0
F Statistic 2.040
Prob. F Statistic > 0 0.140
Durbin Watson 2.546
Transformed Durbin 1.928
Watson
PraisWinston rho 0.055
Regression 22:
United Kingdom
1996-1990
p value [Beta] p value
Squared Effective Political 516.215(**) 0.010
Parties
Log Effective Political -
Parties
Effective Political Parties 0.142 -2172.507(**) 0.010
(Critical Point) 2.104
Federal Spending Gap
Federal Revenue Ratio -27.978(**) 0.018
SDC Labor Organization -6.230(**) 0.012
SDC Partisan Index -7.693(**) 0.003
SDC Interaction Term -6.406(**) 0.003
SDC Left-Labor Power
Initial GDP Squared
Initial GDP 0.439 0.000 0.162
(Income Critical Point)
Government Ratio 0.148 -0.291 0.281
Population Growth 0.066 -0.198 0.901
Openness to Trade 0.966 -0.135(**) 0.003
Dummy for Expenditure
Dummy for Personal
Income
Dummy for Tax
Intercept 0.753 -23.296(*) 0.070
Observations 25
Cases
Average
Time Periods
[R.sup.2] Within
[R.sup.2] Between
[R.sup.2] Overall
[R.sup.2] 0.979 0.988
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.960 0.982
[Chi square]
Prob. [Chi square] > 0.000
Hausman [Chi square]
Prob.
Hausman [Chi square]> 0
F Statistic 53.760 163.100
Prob. F Statistic > 0 0.000 0.000
Durbin Watson 1.665 0.960
Transformed Durbin 2.271
Watson
PraisWinston rho 0.374
Regression 23:
United States
1996-1990
[Beta] p value
Squared Effective Political 0.207
Parties
Log Effective Political -
Parties -7.979
Effective Political Parties
(Critical Point) 3.116(**) 0.001
Federal Spending Gap
Federal Revenue Ratio
SDC Labor Organization
SDC Partisan Index
SDC Interaction Term
SDC Left-Labor Power -0.353 0.174
Initial GDP Squared -9.40E-08(**) 0.000
Initial GDP 0.004(**) 0.000
(Income Critical Point) 22127
Government Ratio 0.476(**) 0.001
Population Growth 1.003 0.333
Openness to Trade -0.152(**) 0.038
Dummy for Expenditure
Dummy for Personal
Income
Dummy for Tax
Intercept -7.913(**) 0.000
Observations 25
Cases
Average
Time Periods
[R.sup.2] Within
[R.sup.2] Between
[R.sup.2] Overall
[R.sup.2]
Adjusted [R.sup.2]
[Chi square]
Prob. [Chi square] > 0.000
Hausman [Chi square]
Prob.
Hausman [Chi square]> 0
F Statistic
Prob. F Statistic > 0
Durbin Watson
Transformed Durbin
Watson
PraisWinston rho
Notes:
(*) 10 percent confidence interval
(**) 5 percent confidence interval
Notes
(1.) Recent data suggest that the level rather than the rate of
economic, development affects regime-type (Durham, 1998 and 1999).
Therefore, as the econometric section more thoroughly addresses,
collinearity between national income levels and democracy is a potential
problem in broadly specified income distribution models. The empirical
data presented in this paper directly addresses this concern.
(2.) Both measures are inherently subjective, and temporal
reliability is questionable. Brunetti persuasively argues that the
"dominating" Gastil scale is "rather subjective (1997, p.
166)," and the Freedom House judges readily admit that
"changes in information and judgment since 1973 make many ratings
not strictly comparable from year to year (Gastil, 1987, p. 53)."
(3.) The construction of the proxy is described in more detail in
Durham (1998 and 1999).
(4.) The number of parties follows Laakso and Taagepera (1979). as
the "effective number of parties is the number of hypothetical
equal-size parties that would have the same total effect on
fractionalization of the system as have the actual parties of unequal
size (1979, p. 4)." The effective number N is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [P.sub.l] represents the share of the total number of
parliamentary seats that the lth party holds. Data come from the
Chronicle of Parliamentary Elections and Developments
Inter-Parliamentary Union, vols. 2-27 (1967-1993); The Political
Handbook of the World (various issues); and Machie and Rose (1991).
(5.) In Stepan and Skach's terms, a "pure parliamentary
regime" is a system of "mutual dependence," where
parliamentary majorities must support executive power, and the executive
office "has the capacity to dissolve the legislature and call for
elections." A "pure presidential regime" is a system of
"mutual independence," where both the executive and
legislative powers have "fixed electoral mandates" that are
the sole sources of "legitimacy (Stepan and Skach, 1993, pp. 3-4,
emphasis added)." Similarly, "dictators," according to
common indicators, who permit the existence of a multi-party parliament,
occupy the "executive" branch.
While the raw number of effective parties captures discretion for
parliamentary regimes, the figure adjusts for these non-parliamentary
categories because the executive branch does not derive its legitimacy
from the legislature. Therefore, the overall measure for these cases is
the average number of effective parties across the legislative and
executive branches.
(6.) The effective party component of the measure is also
serviceably relevant to dictatorships, who may or may not choose to
surround themselves with a party.
(7.) Some scholars object to the term "party" in a
non-democratic setting. There are two rejoinders. First, to apply the
term exclusively to democracies necessarily excludes similar analysis of
less developed areas, as if poorer countries are
"underdeveloped" politically (Ranney, 1968). Second, and more
persuasive, as Durverger (1954) notes, the internal organization of
parties in single or multiple party regimes do not differ widely.
(8.) The effective party/constitutional framework measure does not
purport to capture interest group pressures or the impact of (marginal)
political parties that the electoral system excludes from participation.
Perhaps the Gastil and Polity III data sets better capture such
influences. Again, the alternative is not necessarily a superior proxy
for all purposes but perhaps more effectively addresses implicit
serviceable concerns. The focus of this institutional measure is largely
on the "party-in-the-government," as defined in Ranney (1968).
(9.) Data come from Garrett (1995).
(10.) In some cases conventionally perceived "right-wing"
parties, particularly in Europe, entertain strong corporatist
convictions. In other words, a consensus regarding social welfare policy
can characterize a polity across partisan lines, such as in, say,
Austria or Denmark. However, the indices that Garrett employs take
social policy into account, as, but one example, (pre-Thatcher)
Conservative governments in the United Kingdom are considered to the
left of Republican administrations in the United States. In other'
words, the partisan measure is not a relative index within countries but
an absolute scale: across national boundaries. Nonetheless, the
left-labor index in (2) is perhaps the most effective test.
(11.) Bernholtz (1993) criticizes Weingast's characterization
of the British state, which scholars more conventionally consider as
comparatively centralized.
(12.) Federalism data come from various issues of the UN's
Yearbook of National Account Statistics.
(13.) The concept of fiscal federalism recommends brief discussion
of other multiple sovereignties. In addition to local governments,
supranational institutions potentially have a very significant impact
through (primarily) international trade and (at least in the case of the
European Union) social policy. Moreover, transfers between local
governments can have considerable impact on economic outcomes. Some
regressions attempt to capture these effects with dummy variables for
the relevant international organization (EC membership) and
consideration of the relative importance of international trade.
Importantly, however, the notion of fiscal federalism focuses on the
constraints on national government, the primary locus of policy-making.
(14.) These data come from the Penn World Table 5.6. See Summers
and Heston (1991) for a description.
(15.) This view ignores the prevalence of tax evasion of wealthy
individuals, a fundamental problem (especially in developing countries).
(16.) Deininger and Squire suggest three strategies for empirical
investigation of their data. They write that "it would be prudent
to examine whether such results hold for (a) the raw data, (b) data that
have been adjusted for differences between expenditure-based and
income-based coefficient, and (c) data consistently based on a common
definition (1996, p. 582)." The following regressions follow (b).
For an empirical examination that follows each of these alternatives see
Durham (1998). Notably, these alterations do not significant affect the
results.
(17.) To test the appropriateness of a random-effects model, the
regression tables list the Hausman (1978) specification test, which
evaluates the equivalence of parameters from random- and fixed-effects
models. But whatever the formal equivalence of the coefficients, the
strong emphasis on cross-sectional institutional variance in these
hypothesis suggest that inclusion of country-specific dummy variables is
largely counterproductive.
(18.) An alternative temporal consideration is also instructive and
perhaps more theoretically appealing--the effect of election years. But
with respect to all relevant institutional specifications (Regressions 1
-19, except Regression 13, which exclusively considers dictatorships),
the election year dummy is statistically insignificant. Data are
available upon request.
(19.) The government ratio less military spending is perhaps a more
accurate proxy for public social welfare expenditure. Unfortunately, the
distinction limits the data somewhat (from 568 to 384 observations in
Regression 1), but nonetheless, the results are generally consistent
using the two proxies. In fact, of the 19 (univariate) regressions, only
two results differ in terms of significance, albeit in ambiguous
directions. Curiously, the government ratio less military spending is
significant in Regression 17 but insignificant in Regression 18, unlike
the gross proxy.
(20.) Other dummy variables are perhaps instructive in lieu of controlling for regional effects. For example, a dummy variable for
membership in the European Community complements in analysis of fiscal
federalism by controlling for a influence supranational organization
that facilitates significant international resource transfers, as
discussed previously. Surprisingly, the variable produces rather
ambiguous results, as the coefficient is expectedly negative in
regressions that include the Gastil index but positive in equations that
include the SDC variables. All other regressions produce statistically
insignificant results. Also, dummy variables for Communist regimes,
particularly the Soviet bloc and China, consistently suggest in every
equation that such "Marxist-Leninist" systems have more
equitable income distributions.
(21.) As previously suggested, widely specified income distribution
models may suffer from collinearity among initial GDP per capita,
political regime-type measures and openness to international trade.
Regressions that alternatively exclude trade and the functional form of
GDP should ameliorate the difficulty in interpreting the coefficients
for the regime variables. For example, Regressions 1 through 19 without
openness to trade produce no changes in the significance tests of the
coefficients. Furthermore, omission of the quadratic form of GDP per
capita produces only three changes in the (14) relevant regressions, as
the linear-log forms of the Gastil and Polity III indices (10 percent
confidence) as well as the quadratic form of the Gastil measure (10
percent confidence) are significant.
(22.) While there are a few additional countries with more than 20
observations according to the Data Appendix (Bulgaria, Canada, India,
and Japan), there are missing consecutive observations in each series.
The regressions do not use interpolated data.
(23.) This focus is different from Romer's more general
discussion of the role of "ideas" that encompass an economy.
Previous models of growth include some 'variables with acknowledged
respect to the broader notion of ideas. For example, as Romer discusses,
openness to international trade can affect the benevolent "flow of
ideas" across national boundaries. The following considers
"ideas" with respect to the relevant actors that institutions
restrain. Alesina et al. note the potential importance of governing
ideologies in passing but do not consider any interaction with
institutions (1996, pp. 205-06).
References
Alesina, Alberto et al. (1996). "Political Instability and
Economic Growth," Journal of Economic Growth 1, 2:189-211, June.
Alvarez, R. Michael, Garrett, Geoffrey and Lange, Peter. (1991).
"Government Partisanship, Labor Organization, and Macroeconomic
Performance, American Political Science Review 85, 2: 539-56, June.
Barro, Robert J. (1996). "Democracy and Growth," Journal
of Economic Growth. 1, 1: 1-27, March.
Beitz, Charles R. (1982). "Democracy in Developing
Societies," In Gastil, Ed., Freedom in the World: Political Rights
and Civil Liberties. New York: The Free Press.
Bernholtz, Peter, "Comment," Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 149, 1.
Bollen, Kenneth A. and Jackman, Robert W. (1985). "Political
Democracy and the Size Distribution of Income," American
Sociological Review 50, 438-57.
Casella, Alessandra and Frey, Bruno. (1992). "Federalism and
Clubs: Toward an Economic Theory Of Overlapping Political
Jurisdictions," European Economic Review 36, 313-31.
Chronicle of Parliamentary Elections and Developments,
Inter-Parliamentary Union 2-7, 1967-1993.
Clague, Christopher et al. (1996) "Property and Contract
Rights in Autocracies and Democracies," Journal of Economic Growth.
1, 2: 243-45, June.
Crafts, Nicholas F. R. (1992). "Institutions and Economic
Growth: Recent British Experience in an International Context,"
West European Politics 15, 4:16-38, October
Deininger, Klaus and Lyn Squire. (1996). "A New Data Set
Measuring Income Inequality," The World Bank Economic Review 10, 3:
565-91.
Durham, J. Benson. (1998). Economic and Political Institutions and
Growth: Some Econometrics, Ph.D. diss., Columbia University.
--. (1999). "Economic Growth and Political Regimes,"
Journal of Economic Growth, forthcoming.
Duverger, Maurice. (1954). Political Parties. New York: Wiley.
Evans, Peter. (1979). Dependent Development. The Alliance of
Multinational, State, and Local Capital in Brazil. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Garrett, Geoffrey. (1995). "Capital Mobility, Trade, and the
Domestic Politics of Economic Policy," International Organization
49, 4: 657-87, Autumn.
Garrett, Geoffrey and Lange, Peter. (1986). "Performance in a
Hostile World: Economic Growth in Capitalist Democracies," World
Politics 38, 4:517-35.
--.(1985). "The Politics Of Growth: Strategic Interaction And
Economic Performance In The Advanced Industrial Democracies,
1974-80," Journal of Politics 47, 792-827, August.
Gourevitch, Peter. (1978). "The Second-Image Reversed: The
International Sources of Domestic Politics," International
Organization 32, 881-912.
Hausman, J. A. (1978). "Specification Tests in
Econometrics," Econometrica 46, 1251-71.
Headey, Bruce. (1970). "Trade Unions and National Wage
Policies," Journal of Politics 32, 407-32.
Hicks, Alexander. (1994). "The Social Democratic Corporatist
Model of Economic Performance in The Short- And Medium-Run
Perspective." In Thomas Janoski and Alexander Hicks, Eds., The
Comparative Political Economy of the Welfare State, pp. 189-217,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jaggers, Keith and Gurr, Ted Robert. (1995). "Tracking
Democracy's Third Wave with the Polity III Data," Journal of
Peace Research 32, 4: 469-482.
Kee, Woo Kik. (1977). "Fiscal Decentralization and Economic
Development," Public Finance Quarterly 5, 1: 79-97, January.
Kuznets, Simon. (1955). "Economic Growth and Income
Inequality," American Economic Review 45, 1-28.
Laakso, Markku and Taageper, Rein. (1979). "Effective Number
of Parties: A Measure With Application to West Europe," Comparative
Political Studies 12, 3-27, April.
Levine, Ross and Renelt, David. (1992). "A Sensitivity
Analysis Of Cross-Country Growth Regressions," American Economic
Review 82, 4: 942-63, September.
Lijphart, Arend. (1984). Democracies: Patterns of Majoritarian and
Consensus Government in Twenty-one Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Machie, Thomas and Rose, Richard. (1991). The International Almanac of Electoral History.' Fully Revised Third Edition (Congressional
Quarterly Inc.).
Mainwaring, Scott. (1993). "Presidentialism, Multipartism, and
Democracy," Comparative Political Studies 26, 198-228.
North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry R. (1989).
"Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions
Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England," Journal of
Economic History 49, 4: 803-32, December.
Oates, Wallace. (1972). Fiscal Federalism, Harcout Brace Jovanovich
Inc.
Perotti, Roberto. (1996). "Growth, Income Distribution, and
Democracy: What the Data Say," Journal of Economic Growth 1,
2:149-87, June.
Przeworski, Adam and Limongi, Fernando. (1993). "Political
Regimes and Economic Growth," Journal of Economic Perspectives 7,
3: 51-69, Summer.
Qian, Yingyi and Weingast, Barry R. (1997). "Federalism as a
Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives," Journal of Economic
Perspectives 11, 83-92.
Ranney, Austin. (1968). "The Concept of `Party'." In
O. Garceau, Ed., Political Research and Political Theory, pp. 143-46.
Boston: Harvard University Press.
Romer, Paul. (1993). "Idea Gaps and Object Gaps in Economic
Development," Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 543-73.
Sirowy, Larry and Inkeles, Alex. (1990). "The Effects of
Democracy on Economic Growth and Inequality: A Review," Studies in
Comparative International Development 25, 126-57.
Stepan, Alfred and Skach, Cindy. (1993). "Constitutional
Frameworks and Democratic Consolidation: Parliamentarism Versus
Presidentialism, World Politics 45, 1-22.
Summers, Robert and Heston, Alan. (1991). "The Penn World
Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of Intenational Comparisons,
1950-88," Quarterly Journal of Economics 61,327-68.
Weingast, Barry R. (1993). "Constitutions as Governance
Structures: The Political Foundations of Secure Markets. Journal of
Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149, 1395-1424.
Data Appendix
[TABULAR DATA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
J. Benson Durham, Without implication, the author is grateful to
Richard R. Nelson, Douglas A. Chalmers, Robert Y. Shapiro, Brendan
O'Flaherty, Alessandra Casella, Lauren Paige Kennedy, and an
anonymous referee for helpful comments on this study.
Columbia University3