State-Owned versus Township and Village Enterprises in China(*).
Perotti, Enrico C. ; Sun, Laixiang ; Zou, Liang 等
Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: L20, P32,
P42.
1. Introduction
While China's overall economic reform has resulted in
considerable achievements in the past two decades, some deep structural
problems remain, one of which is the long-lasting inefficiency of the
state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Although there have been disputes over
the total factor productivity of SOEs, it is widely acknowledged that a
growing proportion of SOEs are losing money. According to a recent World
Bank (1997) report, about half of industrial SOEs made a loss in 1996,
up from one-third just two years ago. The SOE share in national total
industrial output has fallen from 77.6 percent in 1980 to 28.5 percent
in 1996 (SSB, 1997, p. 413), and estimated to decline further to 25
percent by the year 2000.
The statistics seem to indicate that despite persistent enterprise
reforms, the situation of SOEs is worsening, or at least has had little
improvement. Is this completely true? Or how bad is the performance of
SOEs and why? This paper will show that official statistics do not
provide a complete picture of the performance of SOEs. Moreover, where
they underperform non-SOEs, their underperformance relative to
commercial measures can be partly explained by their attention to
certain social objectives.
In contrast, township and village enterprises (TVEs), which are
either collectively established by or initially based on and closely
associated with rural communities such as townships and villages, have
developed rapidly and become engines of China's rapid economic
growth.(1) In 1995, the TVE sector produced nearly 30 percent of
China's gross domestic product (GDP). In the same year, industrial
TVEs produced about half of the total industrial value added, profit,
and output.(2) In 1980, there were 1.4 million TVEs with 30 million
employees. By 1996, there were 23.4 million TVEs with 135 million
workers (SSB, 1997, pp. 399-400). Their real total output increased by
an average rate of 21 percent per annum from 1978 to 1995 (SSB, 1996,
pp. 389 and 403), and the growth rate of their real value added remained
over 18 percent in 1996 and 1997 (People's Daily, 28 February
1998). The TVE exports increased from US$8 billion in 1988 to US$84.3
billion in 1997. The TVE shares in the national total export rose from
16.9 percent in 1988 to 46.2 percent in 1997 (see, Table 2).
Table 2: The Growth of TVE Export, 1988-1997
1988 1991 1993 1995
TVE export (billion US dollars) 8.02 14.8 38.1 64.5
TVE share in total export (%) 16.9 20.6 41.5 43.3
Average exchange rate (yuan/$1) 3.718 5.327 5.761 8.369
1997
TVE export (billion US dollars) 84.6
TVE share in total export (%) 46.3
Average exchange rate (yuan/$1) 8.270
Sources: TVE Yearbook (1990, p. 20; 1996, pp. 102-103), SSB (1993,
p. 633; 1997, p. 587), and People's Daily (5 Feb and 22 March
1998).
Note: TVE export includes direct and indirect (e.g. in the form of
subcontracting with SOEs and foreign companies) exports, and charges on
processing for foreign firms (TVE Yearbook, 1996, pp. 122-123).
The TVE miracle brings about a series of interesting questions.
Typically, the core TVEs are collectively owned by the citizens in rural
communities such as townships and villages. In this sense, TVEs are also
public enterprises like SOEs. In addition, TVEs are usually
competitively disadvantaged in comparison with SOEs in such areas as
technology, labor quality and skills, accesses to bank credit,
information flows within the government hierarchy, distribution of key
materials through official channels, and other proxies for market
intermediaries. How can TVEs do so much better than SOEs? What are the
real causes for the difference? Is there anything SOEs can learn from
TVEs? Although some of the TVE experiences may be useful for the reform
of small and medium SOEs, a careful examination of the management
conditions has led us to conclude that TVEs actually have disadvantages
in some crucial aspects as well. In other words, the ownership and
governance structures of both TVEs and SOEs need to be reformed. Such
reforms have already been taking place since the mid-1990s (Sun, 1999),
and we expect to see more innovative structural changes in both sectors.
This paper attempts to present a comprehensive survey of the
SOE-TVE comparative literature, incorporating our first-hand data and
some original analyses. We shall argue that the SOE performance may not
have been as bad as statistics indicate, despite the fact that they
have, in general, underperformed. Our viewpoint is based upon both
external and internal perspectives, where the external factors refer to
those beyond, and the internal factors those closely associated with,
the notions of property rights, governance structure, and labor
relations.
The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we summarize the
external causes for SOE underperformance, which include their heavy
social burdens, unfavorable position in taxation and pricing, and rapid
de-capitalization in recent years. The failure of China's state
investment system and defective statistics have indeed contributed to
the SOEs' underperformance. Section 3 explains why TVEs have been
so successful, with focus on the factors extrinsic to ownership. In
sections 4 and 5, we focus on the internal factors that lead to the
different performances of SOEs and TVEs. Section 4 highlights the
differences of the governance structure between SOEs and TVEs. Section 5
examines the personnel systems and labor relations in TVEs and SOEs,
comparing the incentive and supervision mechanism of managerial and
labor behavior. The last section contains some concluding remarks.
2. External Causes for SOEs' Underperformance
Undoubtedly, the development pace of the SOE sector has lagged
behind that of the non-state sector. However, as we shall show, the
SOEs' performance may actually not be as bad as statistics or the
coverage by the Western media have indicated. While arguing that SOE
underperformance may be partly justified by their considerable
contribution to the overall social security, we have no intention of
joining the debate over the measurement of efficiency or productivity of
SOEs. We agree that SOE performance has not been, at least, as good as
that of TVEs during the reform period. Many external factors have
contributed to the reported poor performance of SOEs, among which we
identify four of them that we consider most important.
2.1. Social Responsibilities beyond Profit-Seeking
The heavy social burden may be one of the predominant factors
undermining the economic efficiency of SOEs. An SOE has never been a
pure economic actor. It has historically had many other functions beyond
profit-seeking. These include political support to the government,
expansion of employment, and provision of various social services and
securities, such as housing, education, health insurance, and pensions.
What distinguishes the Chinese SOEs from their counterparts in Eastern
Europe is that in China each SOE, particularly large and medium sized,
forms a resident community or small society in which all kinds of social
services and facilities are provided by the enterprise. The manager of
the SOE is more like a mayor or tribal chief. Traditional Chinese family
values and employment pressure may have strengthened such welfare
obligations, making them difficult to change. The increasing burden for
providing a large set of public goods to its community members has
severely hindered the development of SOEs.
Taking pension provision as an example, as the urban population
ages, SOE pension payments have been mounting rapidly in terms of both
absolute amount and relative share in the total wage payment. In 1980,
the SOE sector had about 6.3 million retired employees and the ratio of
the retired over the in-post was 1/13. By 1996, the retired in the SOE
sector had reached 25.2 million and the ratio of the retired over the
in-post rose to 1/6. Accordingly, the proportion of pension expenditure
in the total wage payment increased from 6.9 percent in 1980 to 22.6
percent in 1996 (SSB, 1997, pp. 121, 749-750). While the newly
established SOEs have been relatively free of the pension burden, older
SOEs have become weighed down by the increasingly heavy pension
provision.
To what extent is the SOEs' efficiency directly affected by
their provision of the large set of public goods to the urban
population? It has been estimated that about 40 percent of the
difference in profitability between SOEs and TVEs can be attributed to
social welfare provision of this kind (Xiao, 1991). In addition to the
direct contribution, while functioning as a small society, an SOE has de
facto provided unemployment insurance payment to its redundant employees
(on-the-job unemployment). It is estimated that about 20 percent of
employees in the SOE sector are in fact redundant (Bell, 1993).
The above facts indicate that these heavy social burdens may
justify a large part of SOE losses in a society where a functional
social security system is absent. Without SOEs many of these social
costs would go to the governments at different levels.
2.2. Unfavorable Position in Taxation and Pricing
Along with the marketization reform, the traditional advantages
that SOEs have enjoyed, such as easy access to key materials, credit,
and captive markets, have gradually diminished. However, many
disadvantages have persisted and two of them are critical.
The first one is the SOE's unfavorable taxation position.
Although many tax reforms conducted in the past two decades were
intended, with different degrees, to reduce the SOE heavy tax burden,
taxes collected from the SOE sector have accounted for more than 70
percent of the total government revenue (SSB, 1997, p. 238). By 1995,
the SOE sector produced about 44 percent of GDP, but contributed 71
percent of national fiscal revenue.(3) Before the 1994 tax reform, the
nominal tax rate of corporate income for large and medium-sized SOEs was
55 percent, 35 percent for private enterprises, 33 percent for
foreign-invested enterprises, and progressive tax rates ranging from 7
percent to 50 percent levied on small SOEs and collective enterprises,
including TVEs. The reform unified the corporate tax rate to 33 percent
for all kinds of domestic enterprises (Beijing Review, 14-20 March 1994,
p. 11). However, except for these shifts in the nominal tax rate, the
SOE's contributing share to the government revenue remained
unchanged (see Table 1).
Table 1: The Contribution Shares to Government Revenue by
Ownership, 1988-1995 (percent)
1988 1990 1993 1994 1995
State-owned firms 71.6 71.3 71.6 71.4 71.1
Collective firms 19.7 18.6 17.3 17.3 17.2
(including TVEs)
Households 5.8 4.7 5.5 5.6 6.1
Other ownership 2.9 5.4 5.6 5.7 5.6
Source: SSB (1997, p. 238).
Note: Revenue from both domestic and foreign debts is excluded.
The large difference between nominal and actual tax rates can be
explained by three factors. First, there has been room for negotiating
tax reduction between firms and local tax authorities (Guo, 1992).
Second, tax evasion is much less difficult for those enterprises outside
the state sector. According to a statistical analysis conducted by
Chinese statistical officials, the accumulated sum of verified evasions
of industrial and commercial taxes from 1985 to 1992 amounted to 98.27
billion yuan, being equal to about 4 percent of total taxation income in
each of these years (China Economic News, 23 Aug. 1993, p. 1). The
evasion of enterprise income tax is much more difficult to verify and
therefore, may be used more effectively by numerous small firms in the
nonstate sector. The easier access to tax evasion enjoyed by the
non-state firms puts SOEs at a relatively unfair position. And third,
unlike for TVEs, wage expenditure is not counted as a business cost for
SOEs and must be deducted from their net profit (after sales tax). It
substantially expands the income-tax base of the SOEs (Guo, 1992).
The second disadvantage is associated with the so-called policy
losses induced by the remaining price control of the state. According to
Zhou (1993, p.70), of the 51 billion yuan of subsidies to loss-making
SOEs in 1991, one-quarter was used to subsidize the energy producers who
had to bear the very low controlled prices of their products. And
another quarter was used in exchange for supplying other necessities at
low state prices. In fact, many SOEs in the red are engaged in energy
production (mainly coal mining), grain storage and processing, and the
weapons sector.
2.3. New Losses from New Investment Projects
Many newly established projects in the SOE sector often become new
sources of loss. These projects are typically established by local
governments or industrial ministries and bureaus. The failures of these
projects are the failure of China's state investment system, which
has been characterized by bureaucratic co-ordination and has not yet
been reformed successfully (Sun, 1997a, 1998).
As pointed out in Sun (1998), the process of investment
decisionmaking in the state sector is a distribution process of rights
to possess and use certain scarce state assets, including budget funds,
bank loans, land, quotas of power, oil, and other key materials. The
very first intention of local governments, ministries, and SOEs is to
obtain and occupy as much investment and property from the distributive negotiation process as possible, so that they can reap future benefits
and justify their power base. For example, if an SOE was initially
assigned premises in a commercial part of a city (be it by negotiation
or only by chance), then its employees can get more bonuses simply by
renting out the building. Often the consequence is that when trying to
establish new investment projects, the decision-makers do not care much
about whether or not the project will be profitable in the future. It is
good if the project is profitable, but if it is not the loss will be
born by the state anyway. Such an investment expansion drive, combined
with the persistent soft-budget constraint, inevitably induces
investment hunger and leads to inefficient investment projects (Zou and
Sun, 1996).
Before the reform, the inefficiency of the state investment system
was manifested in subjective decisions of the central leaders, poor
preparation and monitoring, and widespread waste of scarce resources. In
the reform era, following the increase of local autonomy, the
inefficiency of the state investment system has been characterized by
lasting and large-scale duplication of construction at the national
level, and the initiation of too many new projects at the expense of
technical updating of existing assets. In the end, many projects have
little value once their products face weak market demand and strong
competition. There are numerous examples of this in almost all
industrial sectors. For example, by the end of 1990 China had built up
167 production lines for color television sets with an annual production
capacity of 20 million sets. The annual real output was only 10 million,
thus half of the production capacity was idle. In 1993, China had 126
automobile factories and 5,000 re-equipping automobile factories with a
theoretical capability of producing 1 million automobiles per year.
However, most of these factories had no economy of scale by any standard
and the average utilization ratio of capacity was less than 50 percent
(Sun, 1997a, p. 214).
The lasting and severe investment inefficiency has caused
continuous worsening of SOE capital productivity, which can be clearly
revealed by the change in the incremental capital-profit ratio. During
1985-1992, the net value of fixed assets of industrial SOEs with
independent accounting systems increased from 398 billion yuan to 1,098
billion yuan, an increase of 700 billion yuan. While their realized
pre-tax profits increased by only 61 billion yuan, from 133 billion yuan
to 194 billion yuan. The incremental ratio of fixed assets to pre-tax
profit is 11.5, indicating that every 11.5 yuan increase in fixed assets
(net of depreciation)resulted in only one yuan increase in pre-tax
profits. The fact that the ratio of pre-tax profits to total capital
decreased from 23.8 to 9.7 percent during this period (SSB, 1993, pp.
430, 437) can be, to a large extent, attributed to the failures of the
state investment system.
2.4. Capital Diversion and Statistics Bias
Whether the official Chinese statistics are capable of providing a
reliable account of SOE performance is an open question. One of the
basic requirements for official statistics in any economy is to provide
standardized and relatively stable data. These requirements may not
allow the official statistics to capture tactical activities used by
firms in a rapidly changing economy. Among these tactical activities,
several have significantly contributed to the under-reporting of SOE
performance. These include implicit diversion of assets and profits from
SOEs, the SOE-foreign joint venture, and the SOE's incentives to
under report their profit potential owing to the so-called ratchet
effect.
The implicit diversion of assets and profits from the SOE sector to
the collective sector is induced by SOE social responsibilities. In
order to create jobs for the children of their employees, most SOEs have
to set up some new branches, making use of technologies and equipment of
the parent SOEs, often free of charge. These branches are officially
independent identities, which are usually registered as collective
firms. In fact, these firms typically depend on the parent SOEs for
survival and development. Once discovering such diversion as a
convenient channel to avoid tax and to increase the incomes of the
managers and employees, many SOEs also transfer part of their profits to
these daughter firms in the name of subsidies and employment creation
(Qian, 1995).
A survey (conducted in 1992) on 760 collective enterprises set up
by SOEs in Shandong province showed that 54 percent of them were using
6.07 million yuan of parent SOE assets freely. Some SOEs tend to
transfer profitable products and technologies to their daughter
subsidiaries (Guo, 1992, p. 49). Often such subsidiary companies make
profits by simply selling the low-price planned goods from the parent
SOEs at going market prices.
Thanks to many preferential policies for Sino-foreign joint venture
and their own expansion drive, SOEs have had strong incentives to set up
joint ventures with foreign firms. Such ventures are not counted as a
part of the SOE sector in official statistics, although the SOE in such
a joint venture is often the de facto majority investor or controller.
In addition, many of the (more successful) SOEs have been transformed,
partly or fully, into joint stock companies, which is classified into
the category of "other ownership firms" despite the state
holding the majority share. In 1994, for instance, the output value of
these state share-holding companies was equal to 17.6 percent of that of
the SOE sector (SSB, 1995, p. 375). Therefore, it is likely that the
official statistics suffer selection bias in reporting the poor
performance of the SOEs.
SOE management has been monitored by responsibility contract during
the reform era. This monitoring system seems to have transferred the
ratchet effect from output target to profit target. A higher profit
achievement of any year means that a higher target will be set up for
the next year, which has been vividly likened as "lashing the
faster oxen". As a consequence, SOEs have a tendency of
under-reporting their profitability to a certain degree, often reporting
that they are just breaking-even allowing for a better negotiating
position in setting future profit targets (Zhou, 1993, p.71).
In comparison, TVEs have few such concerns and, in fact, the
contrary seems more likely. Local government officials tend to encourage
their subordinates to exaggerate profits of TVEs, which can be used as
achievements to speed up the promotion of their own administrative
career and to compete for more bank loans. Though it is impossible to
have an accurate picture, one recent news report may be informative: the
director of the statistics bureau of Changzhou city in Jiangsu province,
one of the areas with the highest level of TVE development, was arrested
because he invented high figures for local TVEs to reach projected
profit targets (The Chinese Times, June 15, 1995). Clearly, he might
have been encouraged, even pressured by some higher level officials.
To sum up, considering all these factors as discussed above, we
come to a conclusion that the actual performance or efficiency of SOEs
may not have been as bad as indicated by the statistics. An additional
observation is that it was SOEs, not TVEs, that typically operated at
the frontier of new product development (Jefferson, 1993, p.3).
3. Conditions Contributing to the TVE Miracle
The TVE phenomenon is unique in the sense that the emergence of
rural entrepreneurs and enterprises has not been experienced in any
other country on such a large scale and at such a rapid rate. Its roots
can be traced back to the late 1950s, but its development was not truly
noticeable until the late 1970s when China began to carry out reforms
and to open up to the outside world. The TVE development so far is not
an outcome of any carefully designed policy or plan. The government
policy changed from tolerance to encouragement during the 1980s, only
after recognizing that the TVE was a vehicle to increase rural income,
and more importantly, to absorb a large amount of rural labor surplus
without much need for state investment--a serious problem which had been
confronting the Chinese governments at all levels (see Jin and Qian 1998
for more details).
Generally speaking, there has been an overall favorable environment
for TVE growth during the reform period, providing both incentives and
disciplines for township and village governments and TVE managers in the
process of TVE development.
3.1. Hard Budget Constraints Confronted by Township and Village
Communities
In China, the central, provincial, municipal, prefecture, and
county governments all have sufficient authority to regulate markets
through administrative methods and to be involved in credit decisions
through both vertical and regional accountability (dual coordination).
Ex ante, governments at the level of the county or above are directly
involved in the formulation of credit plans and can direct specialized banks to make loans. Ex post, governments have the authority to decide
whether or not SOEs should pay back the loans.
Township and village governments (TVGs) have no such authority. A
TVG cannot protect its TVEs by erecting trade barriers to keep out
competition simply because the market within a community is both too
small and limited. TVGs have no access to the state banking system,
because all townships and villages are historically institutionalized as
part of the traditional rural sector whereas the banking system is a
part of the modern urban sector. Likewise, all staff members of state
banks are registered in the urban residency registration system and have
no links with the rural sector except through business dealings.
As a consequence, state banks have typically followed the
commercial principles in making loans to TVEs. Often, they ask TVGs to
act as guarantors of investment loans. If a township or village has a
poor credit repayment record, state banks can refuse the loan
application and, additionally, they can withhold interest payments and
some of the principal from the bank accounts of the community or its
TVEs. Each TVG well understands that a community may be able to delay
debt repayments over the short term, but that it cannot delay them
indefinitely. Meanwhile, a poor credit record implies that the community
must depend on self-financing for future development and debt servicing.
This is not possible even in agricultural communities, for which bank
credits are needed seasonally for the purchase such inputs as seeds,
chemical fertilizers and pesticides, etc.
The above facts force township and village communities to confront
the pressure of market competition and a hard budget constraint. Though
subsidizing across TVEs within a community is possible, the extent of
such subsidies is very limited. Thus, in reaction to the economic
austerity in 1989 and 1990, several million TVEs were closed down or
taken over by other TVEs (Zou and Sun, 1998, Table 1). In contrast, the
losses among SOEs soared, although only a handful actually went
bankrupt. A 120 billion yuan credit relief operation was initiated in
the fourth quarter of 1989 to write off non-performing inter-enterprise
credits, mainly inter-SOE credits (Portyakov 1991).
3.2. Initiatives and Supports of Community Government
Core TVEs are typically initiated or directly established by TVGs.
Motivated by revenue generation, employment creation, and the strong
desire of the community for improving living standards and increasing
wealth, TVGs have been strongly enthusiastic developing TVEs. This
enthusiasm has been further strengthened by an increasing responsibility
for improvement of local education, infrastructure, and social welfare,
which have been gradually shifted from upper levels of government to
TVGs.
Three critical contributions of TVGs to TVEs have been outlined by
Chang and Wang (1994, pp. 443-44). First, because TVGs are part of a
large governmental system with broad powers, and because of the long
tradition of authoritarian government in China, the full support of TVG
can provide community members and other TVE stakeholders with a sense of
security which is needed to achieve long-term development. Second, TVGs
can offer managerial inputs to TVEs in several ways. Because the market
is in its infancy and ordinary citizens who have suitable
market-oriented talents are a scare resource, TVGs are essential in the
organization of major economic and political activities within their
jurisdiction. Without a market or other social mechanisms, TVGs are
often the only available local institutions with the authority to settle
disputes which arise in the process creating TVEs. Third, TVGs can play
an essential role in gaining access to outside resources, particularly
bank loans. In addition to these three contributions, TVGs are not only
the guarantors of TVE loans, but also the executors of the collective
financing and debt repayment system. This collective financing and debt
repayment system represents another support for TVE growth. All the
funds required for the start-up of a new TVE can be borrowed from
existing TVEs with the help of the TVG (Wong et al., 1995). This system
also offers TVGs the power to initiate and co-ordinate internal
reorganizations or takeovers so that communities can avoid the social
and economic costs of bankruptcy and of takeovers by outsiders (Sun,
1997b; Zou and Sun 1998).
3.3. Integration into World Economy
Geographically, TVEs are most developed in the coastal provinces of
Guangdong, Fujian, Zhejiang, and Jiangsu. These provinces, both
historically and today, have close links with the overseas Chinese in
Hong Kong, Taiwan and Southeast Asia. TVE development in these provinces
has well fitted in the requirement of international division of labor
and in the considerable comparative advantages of rural China.
For overseas Chinese investors, the attractions of TVEs in the
coastal areas manifest themselves in (a) a large number of cheap and
well-disciplined Chinese rural laborers released from the successful
agricultural reform and development in the early 1980s; (b) various
preferential treatments in tax exemption, currency conversion and
remission of profit granted by the opendoor policy; (c) flexible and
relatively convenient approval procedures for their investment projects
in the rural society; (d) proximity to their bases; and (e) cultural
convenience and traditional family or kinship network. It is also
conceivable that (a), (b) and (c) are attractive to other foreign
investors.
Foreign investments have played an important role in TVE
development. Foreign investors have brought in scarce foreign capital
and relatively advanced technology and management skills, and their
marketing networks abroad provide easy access to international markets.
Compared with domestic buyers, there are less problems of the (widely
spread) inter-enterprise debts, because exports also guarantee payment,
as it is due mostly upon delivery.
Thanks to the compatible incentives and comparative advantages, TVE
achievement in exports has been most impressive. Table 2 presents TVE
export growth in terms of both total scale and relative share. It can be
seen that during the ten year period of 1988-97, the TVE's shares
in the total national export increased from 16.9 to 46.3 percent. The
TVE's total export value increased from US$8.02 to 84.6 billion.
This is equivalent to an annual growth rate of 26.5 percent in terms of
US dollars, despite the devaluation of yuan from 3.7 to 8.3 yuan per US
dollar. It is worth mentioning also that the TVE's export growth
has been largely contributed by the TVEs with dominant community
ownership (People's Daily, 6 Feb. 1998).
3.4. Unique Market Opportunities
To a large extent, TVE success also depends on the unique
opportunities created by China's market liberalization especially
relaxation of state monopoly over industry. The protected industrial
sector was effectively opened to new entrants beginning in 1979. A large
number of TVEs started up and rushed to take advantage of sharing the
monopoly profits in the industrial sector. For these early entrants, the
average rate of net profit on capital was 32 percent and the total rate
of profit and tax per unit of capital was 40 percent (SSB, 1993, pp.
396-397). Of course, continued TVE entry gradually created and
intensified competition, inducing monopoly profits to decrease and
finally to vanish. However, the windfall profits enjoyed by early
entrants in the late 1970s and early 1980s greatly contributed to the
TVE takeoff.
In the early years of TVE development, there were many empty niches
in the consumer goods market (processed foods, clothes, etc.) and
primarily processed products markets, mainly owing to lasting shortages
induced by the inefficient command economy. Not surprisingly, TVEs
jumped to meet demands of these markets. Moreover, the rapid economic
development in both urban and rural areas has created a whole series of
new markets -- a good example is building construction and building
materials production in both urban and rural areas, where TVEs have
dominated these industries since the mid-1980s (Naughton, 1996, pp.
150-151).
Meanwhile, the two-track system of market and planning has also
eased constraints, providing TVEs with access to raw materials and
market shares outside the state plan. They can afford higher input
prices by setting up higher prices for outputs, or by simply using low
quality input to produce cheap and poor quality goods to meet the
corresponding demands.
3.5. Flexibility due to Size and Accounting System
Most TVEs are small in size and engage in labor intensive industries with low asset specificity. By 1996, the average size of
township enterprises was 73 employees per firm and that of village
enterprises was 26 employees per firm. In the earlier years, the average
TVE size certainly was smaller (SSB, 1997, pp. 399-400). This makes them
very flexible to react to market changes, to switch products, and to
catch new market opportunities.
The accounting system in TVEs has been much less standard and
strict than in SOEs. Only the TVE owners are accountable for
bookkeeping, and not all of the income and expenditure need to go
through banks. Thus, they can use such flexible financial and
bookkeeping systems to develop their business. TVEs typically pay the
highest salaries to their marketing staff, which can be more than ten
times an average worker's income. TVEs have enjoyed the flexibility
to pay higher commission, send gifts, or even offer bribes to government
or SOE officials so as to get low-price inputs or materials in shortage
and to expand market shares of their products.
In contrast, these conveniences have rarely been possible for SOEs.
The accounting systems of SOEs have been much more standardized, and is
controlled by a nationally uniform accounting inspection system -- with
careful supervision of such items as wages and travel expenses.
3.6. Support from SOEs
The growth of TVEs in peri-urban areas has been facilitated by
direct co-operation between urban SOEs and rural TVEs, mainly in the
form of subcontracting. In the suburban areas of Beijing, Tianjin and
Shanghai, an estimated 60-80 percent of TVE output was produced by firms
subcontracting with large urban SOEs in the early 1980s (Industrial
Almanac, 1949-1984, p. 50). In Jiangsu and Zhejiang provinces, where
TVEs have dominated the local economies since the mid-1980s, the
proportions were only slightly lower in the mid-1980s. Linkages with
Shanghai SOEs in these two provinces have played a decisive role in
their TVE development (Tao, 1988, p. 100).
Why are urban SOEs motivated to cooperate closely with TVEs?
Naughton (1996, pp. 155-156) gives three plausible reasons, namely
diversified supply, cheap labor and land use, and the flexibility to
escape some rigid controls of the state sector.
4. Ownership and Governance Structures of SOEs and TVEs
It has become popular to view ownership as a bundle of rights and
the firm as a nexus of contracts among various owners of different
production factors (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972). Ownership structure
involves many dimensions, among which the most important are the
allocations of residual control rights and rights to residual benefits.
An ownership structure that is consistent with the objective of
firm-value maximization may require that the residual claimants, who
contract for the residual benefits, bear the residual risks, the
"risk of the difference between stochastic inflows of resources and
promised payments to agents" (Fama and Jensen, 1983, p.302).
The governance structure of a firm refers to "the ways in
which suppliers of finance to [the firm] assure themselves of getting a
return on their investment." (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997). The
governance structure of the SOEs is weak because the state, in the role
of financing SOEs, has no assurance to get adequate returns on the
investments. The governance structure of the TVEs is better defined and
appears to be much more effective. The main suppliers of finance to the
TVEs are the township or village households and outside creditors.
Acting on their self-interests, these finance suppliers have all the
incentives to make sure that their investments will not be appropriated.
Alternatively, without an adequate governance structure, a TVE would
find it very hard to get any project financed by outside creditors.
Separation of ownership and control, or, in more intuitive
terminology, of finance and management, is likely to lead to agency
problems. This refers to self-interested managerial behavior that
imposes agency costs on the firm or on the absentee owners'
welfare. Optimal incentive contracting may ameliorate some of these
costs, but owing to informational asymmetries, monitoring costs, or
other market imperfections, agency problems are in most cases inherent
in the separation of ownership and management.
As with China's SOEs, the agency problems are further
aggravated by the conflicting roles assigned to the managers and to the
supervising bodies, and by the fact that SOEs' assets are akin to
public goods that suffer from free-riding problems (Jefferson, 1998). On
the other hand, TVEs are much less affected by these problems. The TVG
usually has close relationships with the managers of the TVEs.
Monitoring costs are lower, and thanks to their close relationships,
information could be shared by the member firms within the community.
Furthermore, incentives can be aligned more easily because of member
firms' common interests and the fact the TVEs share financial risks
under the umbrella of the TVG (Zou and Sun, 1998). However, along with
the expansion of the TVEs as they become more successful, the
traditional close ties among the community member firms may be loosened.
Powerful TVEs may eventually free themselves from the control of the
TVG, and new conflicts among the TVEs or between TVEs and the TVG could
emerge. These would likely result in more serious agency problems as
well.
4.1. Problems Inherent in SOE Ownership and Governance Structures
and Choices for SOE Reform
An SOE is, by legal definition, owned by the Chinese people. Being
owned by 1.2 billion people inevitably means nobody directly owns the
firm. As analyzed in Jefferson (1998), this widely dispersed and
ambiguous ownership structure induces the excludability problem. In
different periods and following the policy shifts, SOEs have been
subject to opportunistic behaviors and appropriations by those who have
direct control of or influence on the firms' assets. These
appropriations may include, e.g., asset stripping by managers and other
insiders; shirking by workers; predatory taxes, fees and bribes levied
by government officials; and non-pecuniary benefits for employees and
their relatives in the forms of housing and social services.
While the 1.2 billion people have no way to exercise direct control
over SOEs, the real control rights are delegated by the central
government to ministries, local governments at different levels and
their industrial bureaus. In order to limit the opportunistic behaviors
of managers and officials at lower levels, the governments at higher
levels have sufficient reasons to keep tight control over SOE operation.
Thus government interventions become inevitable. On the other hand, the
state has to bear the losses made by SOEs in return, assuming an
unlimited liability for SOEs. The asymmetry between lower jurisdictions
that are interested in extracting value from the SOE pool and higher
jurisdictions that replenish value, through either direct subsidies or
the state bank system, creates a serious moral-hazard problem for
opportunist local officials. It has induced an accumulation of bad loans
and non-performance debt within the SOE sector that renders the
financial system vulnerable to external shocks and crises (Jefferson,
1998).
How should China reform the ownership and governance structures of
SOEs? Diversified alternatives have been proposed by scholars and
experimented with in China, which include selling, leasing, and
management and employee buyout (MEBO) of small and some medium SOEs, SOE
equitization through equity joint venture with foreigners, and
restructuring SOEs into shareholding companies. It is widely
acknowledged that China's enterprise reform is a progressive
process of reassigning property rights, reducing transaction costs, and
exchanging these rights among officials, managers within the firm, and
outside entrepreneurs and firms in search of sales, mergers, and
acquisitions (Sun, 1997b, pp. 16-23; Gu, 1997; Jefferson et al., 1998).
Though SOE property rights are not well-defined, the entering of SOEs
into an economy where market-mediated exchanges of property rights are
possible does define the opportunity cost of state ownership (Jefferson,
1998). The increasing opportunity costs of SOEs have motivated and will
further stimulate the SOE reform in China.
4.2. Relative Advantages of TVE Ownership and Governance Structure
TVEs are under the direct jurisdiction of their TVGs. The
government-enterprise relationship is much simpler and more direct than
that of SOEs. In terms of the owner-management relationship, community
members as owners do have incentives to monitor the TVG officials and
TVE management, though the real effectiveness varies across different
communities. Because community members, as owners, possess the right to
derive both short-run and long-run residual benefits from the TVE's
operation, when necessary they are willing to give up short-run
benefits, such as dividends, in exchange for long-run more profitable
benefits. Here, the term "benefits" can be broadly defined as
including job opportunities and security, pension funds, and communal
welfare programs in housing, health care, irrigation, road construction,
and other infrastructure (Chang and Wang, 1994; Sun, 1997b).
Although the residual control rights exercised by TVG may imply a
certain risk of bureaucratization, the control by the government over
implementation and coordination of internal reorganization, or over the
takeover process, does sidestep the social and economic costs of
bankruptcy through court action or of takeover by outsiders. This
control is quite similar to that exercised by the main bank in a
Japanese Keiretsu.
Because the residual control rights of TVEs within a community is
held by TVGs, the community becomes a de facto corporation or "mini
conglomerate", facing a hard budget constraint (Section 3.1). Under
the pressure of intense competition, this arrangement can facilitate a
consensus among community members, TVG officials and TVE managers and
workers to maximize profits even by sacrificing all or part of wage
income. Moreover, because a community is diversified in an economic
sense, it can diversify the business risk. A township or village can
rather easily create several small-scale TVEs in manufacturing,
agriculture, commerce, construction, and transportation and then expand
the size of these TVEs (Zou and Sun, 1998).
A community can be seen as a small society, in which the citizens/
owners can vote by a show of hands in semi-competitive elections for
community officials. In wealthier villages and villages that enjoy a
large TVE economy, this is particularly true (O'Brien, 1994, pp. 47
and 51; The Economist, 2 Nov. 1996, pp. 81-83; Howell, 1998). The
villagers may also directly participate in discussions with community
leaders. These avenues contribute to the resolution of the agency
problems and help reduce costs of organization.
A community can also be seen as a corporation, governed by, e.g., a
system of responsibility contracts or subcontracts. Such a system can be
arranged between the community representative assemblies and the
community government, between the government and the TVEs, and within
the TVEs. These contracts and subcontracts have facilitated the solution
of monitoring problems within the community and within the TVEs (Lin,
1995; Wong et al., 1995).
For the large-scale TVEs requiring access to domestic and
international capital markets, a further clarification of property
rights is necessary. However, this does not mean that the only
alternative is the distribution of shares among individuals. The
community as a collective equity holder and the TVG as the executive
equity holder may still possess comparative advantages. Even if each
citizen becomes a shareholder, it may still be more efficient if the TVG
can act as the representative of local shareholders in the exercise of
their residual control rights over the TVEs (Vermeer 1996). In this
connection, the democratization recently exercised in China's
villages is of decisive importance for future TVE development.
4.3. Disadvantages Inherent in TVE Property Rights Arrangement
The so called "mechanism degeneration" of TVEs has been
widely reported since the early 1990s (see, e.g. Ministry of
Agriculture, 1997). Many aspects of mechanism degeneration can be linked
to the problems inherent in TVE ownership and governance structures.
Among them, two are often pointed out.
First, TVGs are not purely economic actors. As TVEs mature, the
objectives of TVG officials are coming increasingly into conflict with
those of TVE managers, although initially these two sets of objectives
were quite similar (Ren et al., 1990; Wang 1990; Shi and You, 1997).
TVGs have assigned priority to raising employment, local prosperity and
financial revenue. This could hinder the stable, long-term development
of TVEs. The powerful control rights of TVGs could thus lead to
unfavourable interference into TVE management. TVGs also seem to be
shifting the responsibility for the overall development of rural
communities onto TVEs. As a result, many TVEs are now also experiencing
redundant employment and increasingly heavy social burdens. In this,
they are becoming quite similar to SOEs in many ways (Byrd and Lin 1990,
pp. 125, 304 and 351, Shi and You, 1997; Xu and Zhang, 1997).
Second, bureaucratization and corruption among TVG officials and
TVE managers are growing. In those townships and villages where the
development of grassroots democratization has lagged behind, the problem
of who monitors the monitors becomes increasingly serious. This is
because there is a lack of effective checking and restraint devices to
curb corruption behavior of those increasingly powerful TVG officials.
For example, many TVEs are becoming "purses" of their TVGs,
required to pay all sort of expenses for TVG officials. And many TVE
managers are stripping TVE assets for their own interests (Shi and You,
1997).
Although there have been supervisions from county governments as
highlighted in Che and Qian (1998), this kind of monitoring may be
limited due to the problem of information asymmetry. The restraints from
county governments are mainly based on disciplines of the Communist
Party. This may not make sense for most officials at grassroots level,
because the probability for them to get promotion into a formal
bureaucrat is tenuous. Indeed, compared with the economic and social
rents they enjoy from the TVEs, the career of being a low-rank
bureaucrat is not that attractive. In addition, this monitoring is bound
to be weak because of the communication difficulty in rural areas and
there being usually a large number of TVEs and TVGs in a county.
The existence of these problems calls for further reforms of TVE
ownership and governance structures and for grassroots democratization
(Sun, 1999).
5. Differences in Personnel Systems and Labor Relations
Another important reason for the different performance of SOEs and
TVEs lies in the different personnel and employment systems, which
assigns the roles of managers and shapes the basic labor-management
relations in SOEs and TVEs. Generally speaking, unlike in the TVE
sector, there is no significant labor market for both SOE managers and
workers. An SOE manager is not just an entrepreneur but also a
bureaucrat and the chief of the SOE community. He/she has to cope with
and co-ordinate conflicting interests among different stakeholders,
inside and outside the SOE, and within the community. SOE employees, as
the inside stakeholders of their SOE, have enjoyed a special set of
social privileges, are more influential in certain areas, and are more
difficult to manage than their counterparts in TVEs.
5.1 Urban versus Rural Social Status
China has practiced a very strict personnel control system. People
are divided into different social statuses, among which the most
significant differentiation is between urban and rural ones. Each
Chinese citizen is registered either as urban or rural resident under a
household residence registration system. The registration status depends
on one's mother's status at birth. This status can only be
changed due to a promotion to certain level in military service,
university enrollment, or marriage plus a repeated change-of-status
application and waiting for many years. As urban citizens, their food
supply is subsidized and employment is guaranteed by the state.
Furthermore, whether a citizen is employed in a SOE or in an urban
collectively owned enterprise (COE) will further determine the different
levels of his or her employee benefits. Only are urban citizens entitled to work in SOEs and to the associated welfare benefits, such as
subsidized low-rent houses, life-time employment, health care,
retirement pension, children's schooling and employment, and so on.
This systematic arrangement is why Chinese peasants often say that the
socialism has been realized only in urban China and in the state sector.
This arrangement establishes a specific incentive structure for urban
Chinese and SOE employees, allowing them to enjoy benefits and costs
packages that are different from those for the rural Chinese.
A positive externality of this arrangement, though, is that by
restricting the employment opportunity of rural citizens in cities, this
system helps create a more competitive rural labor market for TVEs.
5.2. Personnel/Employment System in the SOE Sector
For both SOE managers and workers there has been no pressure or
threat from the labor market until significant layoffs took place in
1996.(4) The long-lasting reform over the lifetime employment system has
had a limited effect. The system of contract employment was adopted in
1986, but is only applicable to the newly recruited workers. Before
1989, almost 90 percent of the employees in the state sector had
permanent job tenure. Until 1994, only 26 percent of SOE employees were
on employment contracts (SSB, 1997, p. 113). It is also widely reported
that there has been little real difference between permanent employees
and those contracted prior to 1996. One may argue that the lifetime
employment may not necessarily result in lower efficiency with reference
to the evidence from Japan, but the difference is that Japanese firms
are constantly facing pressure from market competition and the threat of
takeover and bankruptcy whereas Chinese SOEs can depend on the ultimate
protector, the state, for solving their troubles.
Managerial appointments in the SOE sector have been tightly
controlled by the Party committees at different levels. Although an
increasing number of technicians have been appointed as SOE managers in
recent years, political consideration is still an important factor in
promotion, and the dominant feature of heads of Party committees is that
they have either an administrative or military background (Qian, 1995,
pp. 228-230).
Although an evolving managerial labor market seems to emerge in the
SOE sector (Groves, et al., 1995), its significance should not be
overestimated because of the following two reasons. First, the entry to
the market is far from free. According to an official survey conducted
in 1995, about 80 percent of SOE managers, especially those of large and
medium SOEs, are appointed through political and administrative channels
(Window, March 10, 1995, p. 10). The social status of SOE managers has
been continuously defined by their ranks within the hierarchy of Party
and government. For instance, some managers of large SOEs enjoy the rank
of vice-minister. Second, dismissals rarely happen. It is a well-known
practice in China for government officials or SOE managers usually to
only be promoted and not demoted unless they commit important economic
crimes or political mistakes. Usually, those managers who suffer certain
difficulties in their SOEs will be transferred to work in other SOEs
with a similar position as before. Only an early retirement results in
an effective exit. Such a turnover cannot form real pressure or be a
threat to most managers. Quite ironically, the competence of an SOE
manager may be judged in an adverse way according to the turnover
numbers: the more firms he has managed, the less professionally
competent he may be. The selection of managers through bidding is only
used in some small SOEs. These facts indicate that there are still both
severe entry and exit barriers to the SOE managerial labor market.
5.3. Employment System in the TVE sector
For TVE employees, there is no guarantee of lifetime employment,
the so-called "iron rice bowl". There have been an increasing
number of rural surplus laborers who are released by agricultural
development and pushed by regional development imbalance. Therefore, the
rural labor market for TVEs has been highly competitive. TVEs can employ
workers from both local communities and other places outside their
communities. Thanks to the competition, there are no generous welfare
benefits, housing in particular, for TVE employees. The unemployment and
retirement insurance typically lies on their contracted land in their
home villages. As a consequence, TVEs have enjoyed low labor cost and a
clear management objective. In the meantime, a competitive labor market
plus a land contracting system induces high labor mobility, the
opportunity cost of unemployment for TVE workers being much lower than
for SOE workers. If unemployed, the worst thing for them is to return to
fanning. This mobility combined with the bottom-line insurance may help
reduce the problem of labor-management conflicts.
5.4. Triple Role of SOE Managers
An SOE manager not only has to be an entrepreneur but also a
government official and the chief of the SOE community. The manager is a
government official because he/she is assigned by the government bodies
to be an agent of the state to manage the business of the SOE and to
protect the interest of the owner, the state. As government officials,
managers are likely to be motivated by administrative promotions,
respected social statuses, and the associated fringe benefits. Although
the cash salary for an SOE manager is typically fixed to be no more than
three times the average salary of regular workers, he/she can be
compensated by many non-pecuniary benefits such as an elevated social
status, large house, and other luxurious on-the-job consumption. The
levels of these non-pecuniary benefits are mainly determined by his/her
official rank in the bureaucratic hierarchy. This incentive structure
serves the purpose of inducing SOE managers to identify themselves with
the government and the state, and to protect the interest of the state
in their SOEs.
The role of bureaucrat is bound to conflict with the role of
entrepreneur in any economy, because politicians or bureaucrats have to,
in most cases, give priority to political control, job generation, and
complaints of their constituencies rather than to profit maximization of
SOEs under their control (Boycko et al., 1996).
As we analyzed in Section 2.1, each SOE, in particular large or
medium sized, lives as a resident community or small society, and the
manager naturally assumes the role of the mayor or chief of the
community. Within a community, the power balance appears to have been
well established. The Party Committee has played a key role in the
appointment of upper level personnel, particularly the assistant
directors and mid-level cadres. The Employees' Congress has played
a dominant role in dismissal decision of workers and in distribution of
social welfare. Employees also have a large influence over the decision
concerning wage and bonus differentials (Jefferson et al., 1998). For
the community members, the top concern is their employment security and
welfare maximization, which is in conflict with profit maximization.
By way of a compromise between the roles of bureaucrat and
entrepreneur, SOE managers prefer to develop smooth relationships with
their superiors. These managers tolerate many kinds of predatory demands
from their superiors, and pay various bills and unauthorized charges
imposed by these above, thereby adding to the losses of SOEs. Table 3
presents a comparison of initial distribution patterns of 769 surveyed
SOEs in 1981 and 1989. We see in the table that there is a category of
"other expenses", the share of which almost doubles from 1981
to 1989. Among the other expenses, the unauthorized fee imposed by
superior bodies is a major component (Tang, 1992, p.9).
Table 3: Initial Distribution of Net Revenue in 769 Surveyed SOEs
in Sichuan Province (percent)
1981 1989
Profit (after sale tax) 46.23 33.03
Sales tax 24.34 24.69
Interest payment 2.13 9.24
Wages 20.28 24.70
Other expenses 4.50 8.50
Total net revenue 100.00 100.00
Source: Tang (1992).
Note: This survey is conducted by Economic Institute of China
Academy of Social Sciences. The sum of shares is not equal to 100
because of rounding and compiling errors in the raw data.
Driven by the interest of the SOE community and thanks to the
increasing autonomy along with the reform, SOE managers now have more
discretion to increase wages, bonuses, and other community welfare at
the expense of earnings. It is reported that during 1986-90, the
realized pre-tax profit of those SOEs within the state budget (key large
and medium SOEs) increased by only 3.2 percent while the total wages and
bonuses of their employees went up by 91 percent (Survey Report, 1992,
p.4). It is also frequently reported that some loss-making SOEs
continuously pay bonuses to their workers by using bank loans.
The unbalanced increase of employees' benefits have failed to
result in better performances, because of the effective "lower
level bargaining between managers and workers at the factory
level," both of whom seek to maximize profit retention while
distributing it as equally as possible within the firm (Walder, 1987,
p.41).
5.5. Simple Role of TVE managers
By contrast, the role of TVE manager is simple. A bureaucratic
career has very limited possibility, and thus is hardly attractive,
especially for those in rich regions. The tasks and objectives of a TVE
manager or management team are typically well specified in a contract
between them and their TVG. They only need to report to the TVG. This
simple principal-agent contract also makes their work considerably
easier and more efficient.
The major compensation for TVE managers includes direct pecuniary benefits in various forms such as higher wages, year-end bonuses and
contract fulfillment bonuses. These bonuses are closely linked with the
TVE performance and thus can be considered as a kind of sharing scheme
of residual benefits. Typically, the bonuses of TVE managers are not
only related to their own TVE performance but also decided through
comparison with the performance levels of other TVEs in the same
township or village. This horizontal comparison has generated
competition pressure among managers of different TVEs (Wu et al., 1990,
p. 332).
TVE managers also face competition and threat from the managerial
labor market. They are not guaranteed lifetime status, and their terms
are fixed for a limited period. As a result, over time, entrepreneurship
has developed in the TVE sector. TVE managers are becoming more
experienced and professionally competent, and more capable to deal with
market competition.
The evaluation practices are also different in the SOE sector and
TVE sector. TVE managers are evaluated mainly by fulfillment of profit
targets. But in the SOE sector, under the current institutional
arrangement and market conditions, it is hard for the superiors to
figure out which losses are caused by external factors, which are
inherited problems of the SOE, and which are resultant from the
incapable mangers. For an SOE manager, it is easy to list a number of
objective reasons that can serve as excuses for poor performance.
5.6. Labor-Management Relations in SOEs and TVEs
For SOE workers, there has been a lack of incentives and pressure
to work hard because of the lasting egalitarian practice of income
distribution, the lifetime employment system, and the public goods
property of SOE assets.
In comparison with TVE workers, SOE workers are less disciplined
and may be more difficult to manage. The labor-management conflict can
turn into a personal one. For instance, if the manager decides to
penalize an undisciplined worker, the worker may take it personally and
make trouble or brandish threats to the manager and even the
manager's family. The worker believes that any loss of the
enterprises caused by his undisciplined performance will be borne by the
state while any personal punishment against him will have to be borne by
him individually. This adds to Jefferson's (1998) list an
additional manifestation of nondiminishability property of the SOE
public goods, which indicates that one person's overconsumption
need not seriously constrain the ability of others to extract value from
the SOE. Because of this nondiminishability, the undisciplined worker
has a rational reason to think that if the manager decides to punish him
then it must be out of the manager's personal intention. There is
nearly a consensus among workers and managers about this. Moreover,
because of such obvious nondiminishability, the punished worker can
often get sympathy from other workers. There have even been examples
where managers were injured or even killed, by workers during reforms in
some places. Meanwhile, managers have no incentive to place the workers
under strict disciplines at all. As a consequence, pervasive shirking
and free riding become inevitable and widespread in the SOE sector.
TVE workers are much easier to disciplined and to manage. They have
sufficient motivation and face strong pressure to work hard. They are
motivated by the close link between their wages and performance.
Piece-rate and team-responsibility-wage systems are common in the TVE
sector. As for pressures, TVE employees are almost without exception
Contract workers, hired for the year or the season with no job security
as there are many others waiting for jobs. They often work longer hours
and much harder than SOE workers do, because if their performance is not
satisfactory, their job contracts may not be renewed or even terminated
in advance (Ho, 1994). Collectively, if business goes wrong, everybody
in the firm will lose their job. Therefore, TVE workers well understand
that their own future is closely tied with that of the firm, with which
they have to share the risk.
The outstanding performance of TVE workers may be further explained
by a kind of group or mutual monitoring at the horizontal level. This
mechanism is induced by the threat of collective unemployment caused by
the failure of their enterprise, in academic words, by a
"cooperative culture" within a small commons (Weitzman and Xu,
1994; Jefferson, 1998).
6. Concluding Remarks
In this paper we have presented a comprehensive account of the
issue of SOE-TVE comparison in China. The account is based on a major
survey on the literature as well as first hand analysis. It is concluded
that though TVEs have been confronted with comparative disadvantages in
the areas of technologies, labor skills and education levels, accesses
to bank loans, official channels of information and key material
distribution, they have enjoyed and established more important
advantages over SOEs. These can be summarized in the following major
points: (a) Hard budget constraints to TVEs in general and to each
township and village community in particular, whereas SOE budget
constraints remain soft. (b) Relatively compatible interests and
incentives within a TVE community, constantly reinforced by competitive
pressures from markets and other communities, whereas SOEs have
continuously shared the properties of public goods and faced conflicts
of interest in many aspects. One example is the conflicting roles of SOE
managers, who have to be simultaneously a government bureaucrat, chief
of the SOE community, and entrepreneur. (c) Flexibility due to small
size, diversified community economy, and far from strict bureaucratic
control, which give TVEs an advantage to capture opportunities emerging
in all markets of products, labor, capital, and the domestic and
international. And (d) simpler principal-agent tier, personnel and
employment system, and labor relations, which are induced by the
historical institutional arrangements in rural China and subject to the
adjustments required by competition. As a consequence, TVEs have
out-performed SOEs and replaced SOE positions in many areas. The TVE
sector has become the number one sector in China's industrial
production and export. In the near future, it will become number one
sector in China's GDP generation.
In contrast, though having enjoyed advantages in technologies,
government financing and supporting, SOEs have suffered from many
problems inherent in SOE institutional arrangements and their ownership
and governance structures. Due to the widely dispersed and ambiguous SOE
ownership structure and the multiple principal-agent tiers, the SOE
sector has suffered most serious agency and asymmetric information problems. There are large numbers of stakeholders around each SOE, all
having sufficient incentive to extract value from the SOE but with much
less incentive to put their efforts into the SOE. This is the essential
reason why the SOE financial situation increasingly becomes worse while
their output expansion continues -- although the real performance of the
SOE sector is better than what is indicated by official statistics if
the SOEs' broad social contributions are taken into account.
However, much of SOE social contributions may have been transferred into
bad loans and non-performing debts in the state banking system, when the
SOE sector has continued to consume about 80 percent of state bank
credit funds but creates less than 45 percent of China's GDP.
Due to the broad institutional arrangements and cultural
environments around and within SOEs are so remarkably different from
those around and within TVEs, there seems to be no partial solution for
SOEs to learn from TVEs. Facing a hard budget constraint, a survival
urge placed by tough market and inter-jurisdiction competitions, and the
self-initiated adaptive innovations induced by the competition and hard
budget constraint may be the basic lessons TVEs can offer. These basic
lessons have been appealing to not only SOEs but also TVEs to reform
their ownership and governance structures, because both SOEs and TVEs
have appeared to face similar problems while the initially favorable
market and environmental conditions enjoyed by TVEs have gradually
dissolved. Following the expansion of TVE scale and market shares, TVE
mechanism degeneration has become increasingly serious in those township
and villages where grassroots democratization has lagged behind. It has
generated serious consequences in TVE performance since the mid-1990s
(Sun 1999, Section 4.3). The central issues here are, once again, the
increased agency costs and the question of who monitor the monitors. In
this connection, SOEs and TVEs face the similar challenge and need to
conduct similar reform on their ownership and governance structures.
Interestingly, collective ownership within a small community which faces
competition and hard budget constraint is more akin to the small commons
such as the small fisheries in Maine, where a self-initiated effective
property-rights arrangement has evolved (Jefferson, 1998). In fact, many
Chinese rural communities initiated "joint stock cooperative"
reform even in the 1980s. Such a self-initiated, innovative property
rights reform appeared well-fitting in local conditions in most cases
and has become widespread in both the SOE and TVE sectors since 1992
(Sun, 1999).
China's ambitious and radical SOE reform plan has been delayed
by the problem of a large number of layoffs and the shock of Asia's
financial crisis. But the scenario is clear. The plural ownership
structures and diversified governance structures have emerged and will
become widespread in the near future, which include pure private
ownership, employee stock ownership, joint stock partnership or
cooperative, leasing, joint ventures, shareholding company and hybrid
forms of shareholding company, and a small proportion of reformed state
ownership in certain industries.
Notes
(1) TVE in this paragraph is interpreted in the broader sense, i.e.
including household- run and jointly owned private enterprises, which
accounted for 33 percent of output and 51 percent of employment in the
broader TVE sector in 1994 and tend to be much smaller in scale (Sun,
1997, p. 28). In the discussion which follows, TVEs are understood in
the narrower sense of those with dominant community ownership only. We
may call TVEs in the narrower sense "core TVEs" when it is
necessary.
(2.) Sources: "Selection from the 1995 National Industrial
Census", published in People's Daily, 19 February 1997; and
Ministry of Agriculture, 1997.
(3.) The GDP share of SOEs in 1995 is estimated as follows. In
1995, the agricultural sector (dominated by peasant households) produced
21 percent of GDP (SSB, 1997, p. 42), the broader TVE sector contributed
30 percent of GDP (Ministry of Agriculture, 1997), and the urban
collective, private, and foreign sectors could have produced 5 percent
of GDP.
(4.) By the end of 1996, there were about 9 million SOE lay-offs in
urban China (SSB, 1997b, p. 31). These workers continued to be
identified as SOE employees rather than unemployed. Their cash salaries
are reduced by a large margin, but other non-pecuniary benefits
basically remain. In addition, governments at different levels have
promised and conducted programs to help them find new jobs. Because they
have maintained and expect to maintain their favorable urban plus SOE
social status in the future, they usually resist joining TVEs or
entering the huge emerging urban labor market that has attracted tens of
million rural laborers since the late 1980s.
References
Alchian, Armen and Harold Demsetz. 1972. "Production,
Information Costs, and Economic Organization," American Economic
Review, 62: 777-795.
Beijing Review (weekly periodical, in English).
Bell, Michael W., Hoe Ee Khor, and Kalpana Kochhar. 1993.
"China at the Threshold of a Market Economy," IMF Occasional
Paper, No. 107, Washington DC: IMF.
Boycko, Maxim, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1996. "A
Theory of Privatization," Economic Journal, 106 (March): 309-319.
Byrd, William and Lin, Qingsong (eds.). 1990. China's Rural
Industry: Structure, Development and Reform, Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Chang, Chun and Yijiang Wang. 1994. "The Nature of the
Township-Village Enterprises," Journal of Comparative Economics,
19, 3: 434-452.
Che, Jiahua and Yingyi Qian. 1998. "Institutional Environment,
Community Government, and Corporate Governance: Understanding
China's Township and Village Enterprises," Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization, 14, 1 (April): 1-23.
The Chinese Times (Huaren Shibao in Chinese), published in Japan,
1995.
Fama, Eugene, and Michael Jensen. 1983. "Separation of
Ownership and Control," Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 2 (June):
301-326.
Groves, Theodore, Yongmiao Hong, John McMillan, and Barry Naughton.
1995. "China's Evolving Managerial Labor Market," Journal
of Political Economy, 103, 4 (Aug.): 873-892.
Gu, Edward X. 1997. "Foreign Direct Investment and the
Restructuring of Chinese State-owned Enterprises (1992-1995),"
China Information, 12, 3 (Winter 1997-1998): 46-71.
Guo, Zhengying. 1992. "On Problems of China's Ownership
Structure," Economic Research (Jinji Yanjiu, in Chinese), No.2.
Ho, Samuel. 1994. Rural China in Transition, Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
Howell, Jude. 1998. "Prospects for Village Self-Governance in
China," Journal of Peasant Studies, 25, 3 (April): 86-111.
Industrial Almanac-Almanac of China's Industry: 1949-1984.
Beijing: China Labor Publishing House, 1986 (in Chinese).
Jefferson, Gary H. 1993. "Are China's Rural Enterprises
Outperforming State-owned Enterprises?" Research Paper Series,
Number CH-RPS#24, Transition and Macro Adjustment Division, Policy
Research Department, Washington, DC: World Bank.
--. 1998. "China's State Enterprises: Public Goods,
Externalities, and Coase," American Economic Review, 88, 2:
428-432.
Jefferson, Gary, John Zhiqiang Zhao, and Mai Lu. 1998.
"Reforming Property Rights in Chinese Industry," in G.
Jefferson and I. Singh (eds.), Reform, Ownership, and Performance in
Chinese Industry, New York: Oxford University Press.
Jin, Hehui and Yingyi Qian. 1998. "Public versus Private
Ownership of Firms: Evidence from Rural China," Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 113, 3 (Aug.): 773-808.
Lin, Nan. 1995. "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in
Action in Rural China," Theory and Society, 24, 3:301-354.
Ministry of Agriculture. 1997. "The Status of China's
TVEs and the Suggestions for TVE Reform and Development in the
Future," in People's Daily, 24 April 1997 (in Chinese).
Naughton, Barry. 1996. Growing out of the Plan: Chinese Economic
Reform 1978-1993. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
O'Brien, Kevin J. 1994. "Implementing Political Reform in
China's Villages," Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, No.
32 (July): 33-59.
People's Daily (Renmin Ribao, in Chinese).
Portyako, Vladimir. 1991. "The Financial Market in
China," Far Eastern Affairs, No 2.
Qian, Yingyi. 1995. "Reforming Corporate Governance and
Finance in China," in Masahiko Aoki and Hyung-Ki Kim (eds.),
Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies: Insider Control and the
Role of Banks, Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Ren, Qi, Ying Du, Jicheng Qiu, and others. 1990. "An Initial
Analysis of TVE Survey in Ten Provinces," Development Research
(Fazhan Yanjiu, in Chinese), March, pp. 265-288. Beijing: Beijing Normal
College.
Shleifer, Andrei and Robert W. Vishny, 1997. "A Survey of
Corporate Governance", Journal of Finance, 52, 2: 737-783.
Shi, Xiongru, and Jinbo You. 1997. "An Analysis of the Heavy
Debt in Rural Enterprises of Southern Jiangsu," China Rural Economy
(Zhongguo Nongcun Jingji, in Chinese), No. 1 (Jan.): 10-16.
SSB (State Statistics Bureaus), China Statistical Yearbook, various
issues, Beijing: China Statistical Publishing House.
--. 1997b. A Statistical Survey of China. Beijing: China
Statistical Publishing House.
Sun, Laixiang. 1997a. Aggregate Behavior of Investment in China: An
Analysis of Investment Hunger and Fluctuations, PhD Dissertation,
Institute of Social Studies, The Hague, London: Macmillan Press
(forthcoming).
--. 1997b. "Emergence of Unorthodox Ownership and Governance
Structures in East Asia: An Alternative Transition Path," Research
for Action Series RFA38, United Nations University, WIDER, Helsinki,
Finland, July. ISBN 952-9520-62-X.
--. 1998. "Estimating Investment Functions Based on
Cointegration: The Case of China," Journal of Comparative
Economics, 26, 1 (March): 175-191.
--. 1999. The Evolutionary Dynamics of China's Small and
Medium-Sized Enterprises in the 1990s. World Development Studies Series
(forthcoming), UNU/WIDER, Helsinki.
Survey Report, by the Research Group of Policy Orientation in
Vitalizing Large and Medium SOE. 1992. Published in China Social
Sciences (Zhongguo Shehui Kexue, in Chinese), No. 3.
Tang, Zongkun. 1992. "Profit Transfer of SOEs and Their
Reproduction Capability," Economic Research (Jinji Yanjiu, in
Chinese), No. 7 (July).
Tao, Youzhi. 1988. The Southern Jiangsu Model and the Road to
Prosperity. Shanghai: Shanghai Academy of Social Sciences (in Chinese).
TVE Yearbook -- Statistical Yearbook of China's Township and
Village Enterprises, various issues, Beijing: China Agriculture Press.
Vermeer, Eduard B. 1996. "Experiments with Rural Industrial
Shareholding Cooperatives: The Case of Zhoucun District, Shandong
Province," China Information, 10, 3/4 (Winter 1995/Spring 1996):
75-107.
Walder, Andrew. 1987. "Wage Reform and the Web of Factory
Interest," China Quarterly, March.
Wang, Xiaolu. 1990. "Capital Formation and Utilization,"
in W. Byrd and Q. Lin (1990)
Weitzman, Martin L. and Chenggang Xu. 1994. "Chinese
Township-Village Enterprises as Vaguely Defined Cooperatives,"
Journal of Comparative Economics, 18, 2:121-145.
Window of Hong Kong (published in Hong Kong), March 10, 1995.
Wong, John, Rong Ma and Mu Yang. 1995. China's Rural
Enterprises: Ten Case Studies. Singapore: Times Academic Press.
World Bank. 1997. China's Management of Enterprise Assets: The
State as Shareholder. Washington DC: World Bank.
Wu, Quhui, Hansheng Wang and Xinxin Xu. 1990. "Non-economic
Determinants of Workers Incomes," in W. Byrd, and Q. Lin (1990)
Xiao, Geng. 1991. "Managerial Autonomy, Fringe Benefits, and
Ownership Structure," Research Paper Series, No 20, Socialist
Economies Reform Unit, Country Economics Department, World Bank
Xu, Zhimin and Jianliang Zhang. 1997. "Rapidly Increased
Capital versus Decreased Capital Efficiency in Township and Village
Enterprises: Survey over TVEs in Suzhou of Jiangsu Province," China
Rural Economy (Zhongguo Nongcun Jingji, in Chinese), No. 3 (March):
51-58.
Zhou, Xiaochuan. 1993. "Privatization versus Minimum Reform
Package," China Economic Review, 4, 1 (Spring): 65-74.
Zou, Liang and Laixiang Sun. 1996. "Interest Rate Policy and
Incentives of State-owned Enterprises in the Transitional China,"
Journal of Comparative Economics, 23, 3 (Dec.): 292-318.
--. 1998. "A Theory of Risk Pooling and Voluntary Liquidation of Firms: With an Application to Township and Village Enterprises in
China," Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, TI 98-123/2,
Amsterdam: Tinbergen Institute. ISSN 0929-0834.
(*) Part of this paper was written and revised while Laixiang Sun
was visiting the World Institute for Development Economics Research
(UNU/WIDER) in Helsinki and Liang Zou was visiting the Hong Kong Baptist
University. They gratefully acknowledge the gracious support of their
hosts. While fully responsible for any remaining errors, all the authors
wish to thank Robert C. Stuart, the editor, and an anonymous referee of
this journal for their comments and advice.
Enrico C. Perotti
University of Amsterdam and CEPR
Laixiang Sun
International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg,
Austria
and
Liang Zou
University of Amsterdam3