The Political Economy of Gunnar Myrdal: An Institutional Basis for the Transformation Problem.
Sawyer, Malcolm
James Angresano. 1997. The Political Economy of Gunnar Myrdal: An
Institutional Basis for the Transformation Problem. Cheltenham, UK and
Lyme, USA, Edward Elgar, pp. xiii + 197.
This book has two rather distinct elements, which are only loosely
linked. The first chapter and the final one are on transformation issues
(in the former CEE countries), whereas the three middle chapters provide
an intellectual biography of Gunnar Myrdal (and there is also an
appendix with the transcripts of two interviews with Myrdal). Each of
these two elements could be read and understood with little reference to
the other element, though in the chapters on the transformation issues
there are sections which seek to draw out on a Myrdalian perspective.
In this review, I will first discuss the three chapters on Myrdal
before turning to those on the transformation issues. The author
identifies three `Gunnar Myrdals', each identified with a
particular period, moving from the orthodox economist through to the
political and social economist in the 1930s, and emerging as an
institutional economist for the half century ending with his death in
1987.
Myrdal was born in 1898, and his study of economics began in 1915.
The first chapter on Mydral's life covers the period from 1915 to
1933, using the title of Shackle's famous book, The Years of `High
Theory'. These were Myrdal's years as an orthodox economist,
working in the neoclassical tradition, fascinated by abstract
mathematical models and much influenced by Wicksell and others. There
appears little in this period to suggest the latter radical social
scientist, though Angresano remarks on the `rebellious, inquisitive, and
brilliant mind' of Myrdal and the encouragement of criticism and
open discussion by his mentors.
The next chapter covers the years from 1929 to 1938, and
Myrdal's transition from the orthodox economist to the political
and social economist. This transition starts in 1929 with the award of
Rockefeller Fellowships for Myrdal and his wife Alva to study in the
United States. In the USA, Myrdal confronted what Angresano describes as
`the rising tide of institutional economics in America', and
witnesses racial tension and slums for the first time and the effects of
the stock market crash. These experiences transform both Myrdal and his
wife: and it appears to have been transformation involving both
political radicalization and a paradigmatic shift in their approach to
social science.
The Stockholm School, of which Myrdal was a member, is famed for
its development of the Keynesian multiplier process and the theoretical
basis of macroeconomic stabilization policy. Myrdal is reported here as
believing that `all substantive aspects of [Keynes's] The General
Theory were familiar to the Stockholm School members' (p.50).
However, Myrdal argued for the `soundness of public finances' which
meant that there should be deficit spending in the recession compensated
by surpluses during the boom.
Myrdal's political involvement was with the Social Democrats,
who emerge as a dominant political force in Sweden in the early 1930s,
and first formed a coalition government in 1932. Wigforss as the
Minister of Finance was strongly influenced by the Stockholm School and
deficit spending was implemented. Besides acting as a specialist advisor
(cf. p.48), Myrdal was an elected member of the Swedish senate for three
years.
Angresano argues that Myrdal was a social economist in terms of
five propositions. The first three of these are that Myrdal strove to
convert economics into political economy, emphasized an inductive
approach, adopted an interdisciplinary analysis. He also argues that
Myrdal sought to establish social goals for Sweden and to develop policy
recommendation for efficiency and stabilization problems and also for
societal transformation.
In the discussion of what the author terms Gunnar Myrdal II,
covering the period 1929 to 1938, I found the omission of any
substantive discussion of The Political Element in the Development of
Economic Theory, first published in 1930, rather surprising. In that
book, Myrdal clearly brought out the normative content of economic
theories which often purport to the positive, and can be viewed as a
major critique of the practice of the prevailing orthodoxy.
The third chapter on Myrdal seeks to describe his emergence as an
institutional economist, and covers the last half-century of
Myrdal's life from 1938 to 1987. It foregoes any detailed
discussion of his major contributions (which include An American
Dilemma, the study of race relations in the United States with the
dilemma referring to the contradiction between egalitarian principles
and prejudicial practices, and An Asian Drama). For much of this period,
Myrdal was also heavily involved in administration and political
activity, notably as a Minister in the Swedish government and Chair of
the Swedish Post-War Economic Planning Commission, and Executive
Secretary for the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (1947-57).
A common thread which can be seen to run through most of
Myrdal's theorizing is the notion of the forces of cumulative
causation, starting with his work in the first period of his academic
career on the Wickellsian cumulative process arising from differences
between the `natural' rate of interest and the money rate. This
thread continued in a rather different context and precise form in The
American Dilemma, where he argued that `the principle of causation ...
has a much wider application in studying social change'. It found
further expression in his work on regional and international economics
such as Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions. This thread is
underplayed in this book, and given rather little attention, which I
found puzzling. I would regard this notion of cumulative causation as
one of Myrdal's major contributions to economic analysis, and an
idea of considerable importance when considering transformation, and the
roles of the market and of the State.
The major intention of the author appears to be to establish the
credentials of Myrdal as a social economist and an institutional
economist (p.83). The author then turns (p.87 et seq) to what he views
as Myrdal's unique and heterodox method of analysis. The first
element of that method is, quoting from Myrdal, `research is always and
by logical necessity based on moral and political valuations, and that
the researcher should be obliged to account for them explicitly.'
The second is the acceptance of the need for an interdisciplinary
approach. The third is a theory of social change, and one which builds
in the principle of circular and cumulative causation. Finally,
Myrdal's `theory of social change was shaped by his conception of
the socio-economic reality, human behavior, and history. From his point
of view the socio-economic order consists of a wide set of social
relations' (p.91).
The discussion of the issues of transformation begins in Chapter I
with `searching for a useful perspective'. A central aspect of this
chapter is the formulation of performance criteria as they might be
viewed by Myrdal and as they have been viewed from an IMF perspective.
Angresano argues that Myrdal would have focused on criteria such as
social and economic equalization, productivity, standard of living,
improved institutions, social discipline and national independence and
consolidation in a framework of political democracy. In contrast, the
IMF criteria have focused on economic variables such as budget deficit
and exchange rates.
The final chapter considers `Myrdalian contributions to
transformation issues': the title of the chapter is suggestive of a
number of different strands being examined which is indeed the case. The
chapter ranges over matters such as `a more objective approach to social
science research' through the nature of Myrdal's vision for
the future of different societies to a relatively brief examination of
three countries, Bulgaria, Hungary and Russia. The general perspective
is described as containing `a holistic conception of societal
development which is rooted in the history, philosophical currents, and
con temporary socio-economic conditions of the particular country under
study' (p.97).
This is a relatively short book with just over 60 pages devoted to
the intellectual biography of Myrdal and around 80 pages on
transformation issues (and a further 20 pages of interview transcript).
This has left many interesting issues unexplored -- some I have
mentioned above: another is the influences on Myrdal which caused an
almost Pauline conversion from the enemy of the institutional economists
to one of their key figures. It also means that an opportunity has been
foregone to provide an in-depth analysis of the transformation problems
facing the former CEE countries from the broader Myrdalian perspective.
Malcolm Sawyer
University of Leeds, U.K.