It pays to improve school quality: states that boost student achievement could reap large economic gains.
Hanushek, Eric A. ; Ruhose, Jens ; Woessmann, Ludger 等
LAST YEAR, Congress passed the Every Student Succeeds Act,
supplanting No Child Left Behind and placing responsibility for public
school improvement squarely upon each of the 50 states. With the federal
government's role in school accountability sharply diminished, it
now falls to state and local governments to take decisive action.
Large economic benefits should accrue to states that take advantage
of this new flexibility. When students learn more in school, they remain
in the educational system longer and become more-skilled and -effective
participants in the state's workforce. While some graduates will
migrate to other parts of the country, a majority will join the labor
market in their own states, thus contributing directly to their economic
strength. Over the long run, each state stands to receive an
extraordinary rate of return on successful efforts to improve school
quality.
Even though most education policy debates have focused on school
quality and student achievement, most research on the economic impact of
schooling has focused narrowly on the number of years students remain in
the educational system. This metric is not an adequate measure of
student achievement and thus not a reliable indicator of economic
impacts: it hardly matters how long one sits at a school desk if one
learns little while occupying that seat. Recently, mounting evidence has
suggested that measures of individual cognitive skills that incorporate
dimensions of test-score performance provide much better indicators of
economic outcomes--while also aligning the research with the policy
deliberations. The importance of including direct measures of
achievement is especially apparent when looking at differences in
economic growth across states.
In this essay, we document the long-term economic impact of a
state's student-achievement levels, which in turn permits us to
calculate the economic returns from school improvement. First, we show
that in the 40 years between 1970 and 2010, the spread among the states
in their per-capita gross domestic product (GDP) widened considerably.
Next, we show that the level of student achievement is a strong
predictor of the state's growth rate in GDP per capita over that
time period, even after accounting for both the standard measure of
school attainment and other economic factors. Finally, we project for
each state the large positive impact that improvements in student
achievement would have on a state's GDP (See Figure 1).
Any state political leader of vision would do well to make school
quality a high priority.
The Wealth of States
States vary sharply in the size of their per-capita GDP, that is,
the total value of goods and services produced within a given year
divided by the number of residents. In 2010, the wealthiest state,
Delaware, enjoyed a per-capita GDP that was twice that of the poorest
state, Mississippi (see Figure 2). Geographical and historical factors
account for some of this variation among the states, but the
discrepancies have grown over time. Importantly, the rate at which state
GDPs have increased differs widely: for example, the per-capita GDP of
North Dakota, the most rapidly growing state between 1970 and 2010,
increased annually at a rate of 3.0 percent, while Nevada's rate of
increase was just 1.2 percent, the least of any state during this time
period.
The spread among the states has remained wide and grown in absolute
terms over the past several decades. In 1970 the spread between the 10th
and the 40th state in the distribution was about $5,000 per capita in
2005 dollars, but by 2010 it had increased to nearly $12,000 per capita.
Knowledge Capital vs. School Attainment
Economists have long used the term human capital to refer to the
skills individuals possess that have economic value and that pay off in
the labor market. But their nearubiquitous reliance on school attainment
to measure individual skill differences has made years of schooling
virtually synonymous with human capital. That measure of human capital,
however, implicitly assumes that each additional year of schooling
translates into a comparable increment in the stock of relevant skills,
totally ignoring any variations in the quality of the student's
home, community, school, teachers, and other factors.
Here, we combine the quantity of schooling with a measure of
cognitive skills in order to develop a more complete understanding of
differences in individuals' labor-market skills. In the aggregate,
we call this broader measure the knowledge capital of states in order to
distinguish it sharply from school attainment, or conventionally
measured human capital. We rely upon math test scores from the National
Assessment of Educational Progress (NAEP) and various international
tests to provide data on the cognitive skills of each state's adult
workers.
Using these estimates, we then consider the impact of knowledge
capital on the growth in a state's GDP. In that way, we can
estimate the impact of knowledge capital on a state's wealth and
can explain, at least in part, the divergent growth rates in GDP per
capita among the states between 1970 and 2010.
Developing state-by-state measures of knowledge capital requires
some effort. If we are to obtain an unbiased estimate of the achievement
levels of a state's adult workers, we cannot simply calculate the
test scores of students currently attending the state's schools.
Many workers have migrated from a different state, and still others have
immigrated to the United States from abroad; both of these groups will
tend to differ in their cognitive skills from those who remain in a
state after finishing their education. The degree to which state
workforces consist of migrants from other parts of the United States is
illustrated in Figure 3a, and the impact of foreign immigration is shown
in Figure 3b. In 2010, less than 60 percent of adults living in the
median state were also born in that state. The range across states
varies from less than 20 percent (Nevada) to almost 80 percent
(Louisiana). The share of adults not born in the United States in 2010
ranges from just 1 percent (West Virginia) to almost 30 percent
(California).
To obtain our estimate of the student achievement component of the
knowledge capital of a state at any point in time, we use census data to
trace workers back to the place in which they were born. With that
information, we can obtain a good estimate of the achievement of
migrants from various states, because, on average, 86 percent of
children age 14 or younger attend school in their state of birth. To
estimate the achievement of workers born in the United States, we use
mathematics test scores on the NAEP for 8th graders by birth state
between 1990 and 2011. For workers born and educated outside of the
United States, we use mathematics scores from the Program for
International Student Assessment (PISA) and the Trends in International
Mathematics and Science Study (TIMSS) conducted between 1995 and 2011.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
We know, however, that both state migration patterns and the skills
of interstate migrants are likely to differ depending on people's
educational background, so we estimate NAEP scores separately for
workers with different levels of educational attainment. For example, we
assume that we can assign to a college-educated individual born in
Massachusetts (but possibly living elsewhere) the average test score of
students with college-educated parents in Massachusetts. The achievement
levels of international immigrants educated abroad are assumed to be the
same as those of students performing at the 90th percentile of the
distribution in their home country. We make this assumption because
studies have shown that a country's emigrants to the United States
tend to be among its most talented people. (In a separate analysis, we
modify this assumption to account for the less-selective nature of
Mexican immigration into the United States; these results differ little
from the ones reported here.)
Knowledge Capital and Economic Growth
To estimate how knowledge capital relates to the growth in a
state's GDP, we correlate the rate of GDP growth from 1970 to 2010
with our measures of the average knowledge capital of the state's
workers (based on the state's workforce in 1970, the beginning of
our growth period). Simultaneously, we adjust for the influence of three
other factors that are usually hypothesized to be related to growth
rates: the initial (1970) values of the level of GDP per capita, of
physical capital per worker, and of the average number of years of
schooling.
Figure 4 reveals a strong relationship between the achievement
component of the knowledge capital of a state's adult workers and
economic growth in that state. The cluster of states in the lower
left-hand corner of the graph--Alabama, Mississippi, Utah, Nevada--have
suffered from both low math achievement levels on the part of their
workforces and disappointing rates of economic growth. Those in the
upper right-hand corner--North Dakota, South Dakota, Minnesota, Texas,
Massachusetts, and Virginia--have enjoyed both significantly higher
levels of math achievement and higher rates of economic growth.
The connection between the two variables--achievement levels and
economic growth--is not perfect, of course. Given the levels of
achievement of workers in Kentucky, Maine, Vermont, and Montana, these
states should have enjoyed higher rates of economic growth. Conversely,
the economies of Connecticut, Maryland, Virginia, and Louisiana have
performed better than expected, given achievement levels. But, overall,
our results suggest that achievement levels that are 1 standard
deviation higher--for example, having the average worker in a state
achieve at the 69th percentile rather than at the 31st percentile of the
overall distribution of cognitive skills--yield an average annual growth
rate that is 1.4 percentage points higher.
Some may question whether this correlation actually reflects a
causal relationship. One could argue that students simply learn more
when their state is performing well economically, perhaps because growth
generates additional resources that can be spent on education or because
students are more motivated to learn when prosperity is close at hand.
We are not persuaded by these arguments, in part because of the very
weak correlation between increased spending on schools and higher levels
of student achievement. Furthermore, the crossstate results are
virtually identical to previous results from international research, and
extensive analysis of the crosscountry evidence has shown that a causal
interpretation of the relationships is credible.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
To test the credibility of our results further, we also undertook a
standard accounting exercise used by economists to determine how much of
the total variation in economic performance among states at any point in
time can be attributed to differences in a specific factor. In
particular, we use existing research about how much a high level of
achievement boosts the earnings of an individual worker, combined with
our new measures of the average achievement levels of workers in each
state, to gauge the contribution of differences in achievement to
differences in income levels across states. And we perform a parallel
analysis to shed light on the role played by differences in average
years of schooling.
The results of this exercise again suggest the importance of
knowledge capital for state economic prosperity. We find that
differences in achievement and attainment account for 20 to 35 percent
of the current variation in per-capita GDP among states, with average
years of schooling and achievement levels making roughly even
contributions. In a sense, this estimate is surprisingly large, because
both labor and capital are free to move across states--and thus tend to
equalize rewards to workers with different skills. But our results are
quite consistent with those obtained from similar analyses of the role
of student-achievement levels in explaining differences in economic
performance across countries (see "Education and Economic
Growth," research, Spring 2008).
Gains from Educational Improvement
The fact that the achievement level of a state's workers is a
key driver of its economic performance suggests that the gains from
improved school quality could be substantial. Just how large would they
be? We consider a range of improvements in student achievement and
estimate the economic impact for each of the 50 states and for the
nation as a whole. The various scenarios include:
1) Bringing every state up to the best state in the United States
(Minnesota)
2) Bringing every state up to the best state in its region
3) Bringing all students in each state up to the NAEP basic
achievement level
4) Bringing each state up to the best state, but assuming others do
not make any gains at all, thereby isolating the direct impact of a
state's efforts.
The calculations of the economic impact are straightforward. First,
we estimate the expected growth of a state's economy if the current
skill level of workers were to remain unchanged. Then we compare this
growth path to the one that would be achieved with better schools (and
subsequently improved skill levels). The gains in GDP are discounted (at
3 percent per year), so that near-term gains are given more weight than
gains in the more distant future. The resulting present values of income
gains can be compared directly to current state GDP levels.
Our projections account for the fact that improvement in worker
skills is not instantaneous. First, we assume that education reforms
take 10 years to be fully effective, with student skills improving
steadily over that time. Second, the labor force improves only as new,
moreskilled students replace retiring less-skilled workers. We assume
that 2.5 percent of the labor force retires each year and that these
workers are replaced by bettereducated ones, implying that the labor
force does not fully reach its ultimate new skill level for 50 years (10
years of reform followed by 40 years of retirements).
Figure 5 displays the economic gains from each reform scenario for
the United States as a whole over the expected lifetime of a person born
today (80 years), expressed in trillions of 2015 dollars. If all states
improved their schools to the point where average student achievement
matched that of the top state, Minnesota, the overall gains would be $76
trillion, or more than four times the current GDP of the United States.
An alternative way to view this is that the nation would, on average,
see a 9 percent higher level of GDP across the next 80 years. Such an
increase is easily large enough to allow even the most cash-strapped
state to meet current demands for public services while maintaining a
balanced budget. In 2095, the GDP would be more than 36 percent larger
than would be seen without school-quality improvements.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The projected economic impact of the school-improvement reforms
varies considerably across the country, according to differences in the
current economic position and knowledge-capital stock of each state. For
example, Figure 6 shows the gains in economic outcomes that result when
all states are brought up to the skill level of top-performing Minnesota
(Scenario 1). This improvement means the least in North Dakota and
Massachusetts, whose students are currently very close to that level,
and the most in Alabama and Mississippi, where achievement levels are
lowest. If California's students could perform at the same level as
Minnesota's, the benefits to the state would exceed $16 trillion,
assuming other states reached the Minnesota level. Even in North Dakota
and Massachusetts, the current value of gains over the next 80 years
would amount to 70 percent of current state GDP.
We find somewhat smaller gains from having each state meet the
achievement level of the best state in its region (Scenario 2). This
growth is necessarily less than that of the first scenario, because the
achievement levels of the regional leaders vary widely. Nonetheless, the
aggregate gains from Scenario 2 still have a present value of more than
$35 trillion, almost twice the nation's current GDP.
Scenario 3 essentially projects the results of realizing the
achievement goals of NCLB--getting all students to a basic level of
academic proficiency--but by the year 2025. The gains from all states
getting students to the NAEP basic achievement level are roughly twice
current GDP, or about the same as for Scenario 2.
The results for Scenario 4 represent what happens if one state acts
on its own to improve school quality while all other states do not. This
is an important perspective to consider, since no state that commits to
a path of reform can necessarily expect others to join in, even though
that would be desirable. In any given state, some of the students who
profit from the improved quality of its schools will move out of the
state. While the better-educated out-migrants will boost the economy of
their new states, their native states will experience a brain drain.
So, what if a single state improves but others do not? Will it
still benefit? Figure 5 shows that the single-state improvement strategy
(summed up across all states) yields a gain of $46 trillion. When we
compare this present value to that of Scenario 1, where all states move
to perform at the level of the best state, we see that joint action
yields gains that are 65 percent larger than the gains that would accrue
to each state acting on its own. That is, aggregate rewards are smaller
if any state acts without comparable efforts by others; at the same
time, even the gains of acting independently are substantial.
Summing Up
Clearly, the United States stands to reap enormous economic gains
from improving its schools. The goals for boosting student achievement
considered in the separate scenarios of this paper are within the
feasible range for most states. The largest gains would come from a
coordinated improvement in performance, since states are all linked by
flows of people over time. But even if states act individually, they can
promote a better economic future for their residents through education
reform. The gains projected here not only make the residents of each
state better-off but also show how states' fiscal problems can be
tackled when knowledge capital increases.
A key feature of this analysis is that we built in realistic
patterns of movements of the labor force across U.S. states and of the
dynamics of school improvement. Simply put, raising the achievement of
today's students has no immediate impact on a state's economy,
because these students are not yet in the labor force. But as the skills
of today's students improve, the skills of tomorrow's workers
advance as well. Realizing these gains does require a sustained
commitment on the part of a state's political leaders. But such
commitment to better schools has already given rise to dramatic gains in
the United States (for instance, in Massachusetts) and abroad (as in
South Korea). If we are to achieve prolonged economic growth in our
nation, we have little choice but to strengthen the skills of our
people.
by ERIC A. HANUSHEK, JENS RUHOSE, and LUDGER WOESSMANN
Eric A. Hanushek is senior fellow at the Hoover Institution at
Stanford University and research associate at the National Bureau of
Economic Research. Jens Ruhose is an economist at Leibniz University
Hannover. Ludger Woessmann is professor of economics at the University
of Munich and director of the Ifo Center for the Economics of Education.
Internal and External Migration (Figure 3)
(3a) In 2010, the percentage of state residents born in their current
state ranged from nearly 80 percent in Louisiana to less than 20
percent in Nevada.
Percentage of population
born in state of residence
Louisiana 77%
Michigan 76%
Ohio 74%
Average 55%
Arizona 31%
Alaska 30%
Nevada 17%
(3b) The percentage of state residents born in the United States also
varied widely, from nearly 100 percent in West Virginia to 70 percent
in California.
Percentage of population
born in the United States
West Virginia 99%
Montana 99%
North Dakota 98%
Average 85%
New Jersey 75%
New York 75%
California 70%
NOTES : Average is weighted by state population. In addition to the
average, each figure presents data for the states with the three
largest and three smallest shares.
SOURCE: Authors' calculations based on data from the American Community
Survey
Note: Table made from bar graph.
Up to $76 Trillion in Gains (Figure 5)
If all states improved their schools to the point where average student
achievement matched that of the top state, Minnesota, the overall gains
would be $76 trillion. If each state lifted its student performance to
that of the highest-performing state in its region, or alternatively so
that all of its students achieved at least a basic level of proficiency
on the National Assessment of Educational Progress, the economic impact
would be reduced but still large ($36 trillion and $32 trillion
respectively). If each state were to reach Minnesota's achievement
level on its own, the state-specific gains would sum to $46 trillion.
Economic impact of improving student performance
Gains in trillions
of dollars
All states to U.S. best (MN) $76
All states to regional best $36
All states to at leasst NAEP basic $32
Each state on its own to U.S. best (MN) $46
SOURCE: Authors' calculations
Note: Table made from bar graph.