Valuing teachers: how much is a good teachers worth?
Hanushek, Eric A.
For some time, we have recognized that the academic achievement of
schoolchildren in this country threatens, to borrow President Barack
Obama's words, "the U.S.'s role as an engine of
scientific discovery" and ultimately its success in the global
economy. The low achievement of American students, as reflected in the
Program for International Student Assessment (PISA) (see "Teaching
Math to the Talented," features, Winter 2011), will prevent them
from accessing good, high-paying jobs. And, as demonstrated in another
article in Education Next (see "Education and Economic
Growth," research, Spring 2008), lower achievement means slower
growth in the economy. From studying the historical relationship, we can
estimate that closing just half of the performance gap with Finland, one
of the top international performers in terms of student achievement,
could add more than $50 trillion to our gross domestic product between
2010 and 2090. By way of comparison, the drop in economic output over
the course of the last recession is believed to be less than $3
trillion. Thus the achievement gap between the U.S. and the world's
top-performing countries can be said to be causing the equivalent of a
permanent recession.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED
According to the president in this year's State of the Union
address, this is "our generation's Sputnik moment," the
time when we realize the urgent need to step up the performance of our
education system. Only today, unlike in the 1950s, we have a clear idea
of what it takes to improve achievement. The quality of the teachers in
our schools is paramount: no other measured aspect of schools is nearly
as important in determining student achievement. The initiatives we have
emphasized in policy discussions--class-size reduction, curriculum
revamping, reorganization of school schedule, investment in
technology--all fall far short of the impact that good teachers can have
in the classroom. Moreover, many of these interventions can be very
costly.
Indeed, the magnitude of variation in the quality of teachers, even
within each school, is startling. Teachers who work in a given school,
and therefore teach students with similar demographic characteristics,
can be responsible for increases in math and reading levels that range
from a low of one-half year to a high of one and a half years of
learning each academic year.
But while most parents are able to distinguish a good teacher from
a bad one, few have any idea what difference it makes in the lives of
their children. And researchers do not help, tending to talk in terms of
standard deviations of achievement and effect sizes, phrases that simply
have no meaning outside of the rarefied world of research. Here, I
translate the researchers' shorthand into concepts that might be
more readily understood: the impact of teachers on the earnings of
individuals and on the future of the economy as a whole relatively few
successful experiences with either approach as compared to considerable
wishful thinking, particularly among school personnel.
Measuring Teachers' Impact
Many of us have had at some point in our lives a wonderful teacher,
one whose value, in retrospect, seems inestimable. We do not pretend
here to know how to calculate the life-transforming effects that such
teachers can have with particular students. But we can calculate more
prosaic economic values related to effective teaching, by drawing on a
research literature that provides surprisingly precise estimates of the
impact of student achievement levels on their lifetime earnings and by
combining this with estimated impacts of more-effective teachers on
student achievement.
Let's start with the researcher's point of view. With a
normal distribution of performance (the classic bell curve), a standard
deviation is simply a more precise measure of how spread out the
distribution is. Somebody who is one standard deviation above average
would be at the 84th percentile of the distribution. If we then turn to
the labor market, a student with achievement (as measured by test
performance in high school) that is one standard deviation above average
can later in life expect to take in 10 to 15 percent higher earnings per
year.
That estimate may be deemed conservative for two reasons. First, it
does not account for increases in years of education that may result
from having a higher level of performance early on. Also, the estimate
is based on information from people's wages and salaries early in
their careers, before they have reached their full earnings potential.
Other calculations that take into account earnings throughout entire
careers estimate 20 percent increases over the course of a lifetime.
Does 10 to 15 percent amount to much? For the average American
entering the labor force, the value of lifetime earnings for full-time
work is currently $1.16 million. Thus, an increase in the level of
achievement in high school of a standard deviation yields an average
increase of between $110,000 and 5230,000 in lifetime earnings.
How do increases in teacher effectiveness relate to this?
Obviously, teacher quality is not the only factor that affects student
achievement. The student's own motivations and support from family
and peers play crucial roles as well. But researchers have worked hard
to isolate the impact of teachers from these other influences. Rigorous
studies consistently show that the impact of a more-effective teacher is
substantial A high-performing teacher, one at the 84th percentile of all
teachers, when compared with just an average teacher, produces students
whose level of achievement is at least 0.2 standard deviations higher by
the end of the school year. In fact, the impact of having such a teacher
could plausibly be as large as 0.3 standard deviations.
Those impacts attenuate somewhat over time, however. The
literature, though less than definitive, suggests that perhaps 70
percent of the gains achieved that year are retained in the long run by
the student. The persistence of achievement gains is important, because
the more sustained that these increases are, the greater the positive
impact teachers will have on the lifetime skills and therefore the
earnings of students. Put together, this evidence suggests that a
teacher in the top 16 percent of effectiveness will have a positive
impact (as compared to an average teacher) on longer-term student
achievement that is 70 percent of the immediate gain, which as noted is
at least 0.2 standard deviations. That lower bound of the estimated
effect is what we will use as we calculate the economic worth of a
teacher by combining a teacher's impact on achievement with the
associated labor market returns.
Let's start with some conservative estimates of the impact on
an individual student. Take a good but not great teacher, one at the
69th percentile of all teachers rather than at the 50th percentile (that
is, a teacher who is half a standard deviation above the average). She
produces an increase of $10,600 on each student's lifetime
earnings. Even a modestly better than average teacher (60th percentile)
raises individual earnings by $5,300, compared to what would otherwise
be expected.
While those numbers are not trivial, they burgeon dramatically once
we recognize that every student in the class can expect such increases
in earnings. Consider, for example, a teacher with a class of 20
students. Under such circumstances, the teacher at the 60th percentile
will-each year-raise students' aggregate earnings by a total of $
106,000. The impact of one at the 69th percentile (as compared to the
average) is $212,000, and one at the 84th percentile will shift earnings
up by more than $400,000.
But there is also symmetry to these calculations. A very low
performing teacher (at the 16th percentile of effectiveness) will have a
negative impact of $400,000 compared to an average teacher.
Moreover, the economic value of an effective teacher grows with
larger classes, as do the economic losses of an ineffective teacher.
Figure 1 illustrates the aggregate impact on students' lifetime
earnings for higher- and lower-performing teachers. As we will discuss
below, these results are all very large compared with, for instance, the
$52,000 annual salary U.S. teachers were paid on average in 2008.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
An Alternate Thought Experiment
We can also approach this valuation calculation from the
perspective of the impact of teacher effectiveness on the U.S. economy
as a whole, rather than just on the future earnings of students. As
noted above, student achievement, which provides a direct measure of
later quality of the labor force, is strongly related to economic
growth. Improving achievement leads to a better prepared workforce and
to greater growth, and this growth translates into higher levels of
national income.
Starting again with the estimates of the difference in
effectiveness of teachers, it is possible to calculate the long-term
economic impact of policies that would focus attention on the
lowest-quality teachers from U.S. classrooms. Let us propose the
following thought experiment: What would happen if the very lowest
performing teachers could be replaced by just average teachers? Based on
the estimates of variation in teacher quality identified above, Figure 2
shows the overall achievement impact through a cycle of K-12
instruction. Assuming the upper-bound estimate of teachers' impact,
U.S. achievement could reach that in Canada and Finland if we replaced
with average teachers the least effective 5 to 7 percent of teachers,
respectively. Assuming the lower-bound estimate of teachers'
impact, U.S. achievement could reach that in Canada and Finland if we
replaced with average teachers the least effective 8 to 12 percent of
teachers, respectively.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Here the estimated value almost loses any meaning. Closing the
achievement gap with Finland would, according to historical experience,
have astounding benefits, increasing the annual growth rate of the
United States by 1 percent of GDP. Accumulated over the lifetime of
somebody born today, this improvement in achievement would amount to
nothing less than an increase in total U.S. economic output of $112
trillion in present value. (That was not a typo-$112 trillion, not
billion.)
Admittedly, these estimates are subject to some uncertainty. So if
you think those that are given here are too high, even though they are
based on the best of contemporary research, then just cut them in half.
You will still have effects on growth of one-half of 1 percent per year,
which produces impacts of $56 trillion over the lifetime of today's
child. In other words, to make the very large effects disappear, you
have to make either the very strong assumption that student learning has
little effect on the U.S. economy or the equally strong assumption that
teachers have little impact on students.
What Would It Take?
The majority of our teachers are hardworking and effective. The
previous estimates point clearly to the key imperative of eliminating
the drag of the bottom teachers. Here we can offer several alternatives.
One approach might be better recruitment so that ineffective or
poor teachers do not make it into our schools. Or, related, we could
improve the training in schools of education so that the average
teaching recruit is better than the typical recruit of today.
Unfortunately, we have relatively few successful experiences with either
approach as compared to considerable wishful thinking, particularly
among school personnel.
An alternative might be to change a poor teacher into an average
teacher. This approach is in fact today's dominant strategy.
Schools hope that through mentoring of incoming teachers, teachers,
professional development, or completion of further graduate schooling,
ineffective teachers can be transformed into acceptable (average)
teachers. Again, however, the existing evidence is not very reassuring.
While such efforts undoubtedly help some teachers, there is no
substantial evidence that certification, in-service training,
master's degrees, or mentoring, programs systematically make a
difference in whether teachers are in fact effective at driving student
achievement.
The final option is a clearer evaluation and retention strategy for
teachers. Today, obtaining an entry job into teaching is virtually
tantamount to an indefinite contract that stays in force regardless of
actual effectiveness in the classroom. Yet the calculations above show
the enormous value to individuals and society of "deselecting"
the least effective teachers.
Is such a policy change feasible? If we contemplate asking 5 to 10
percent of teachers to find a job at which they are more effective so
they can be replaced by teachers of average productivity, states and
school districts would have to change their employment practices. They
would need recruitment, pay, and retention policies that allow for the
identification and compensation of teachers on the basis of their
effectiveness with students. At a minimum, the current dysfunctional
teacher-evaluation systems would need to be overhauled so that
effectiveness in the classroom is clearly identified. This is not an
impossible task. The teachers who are excellent would have to be paid
much more, both to compensate for the new riskiness of the profession
and to increase the chances of retaining these individuals in teaching.
Those who are ineffective would have to be identified and replaced. Both
steps would be politically challenging in a heavily unionized
environment such as the one in place today.
Salary Politics
The above discussion also highlights the difficulties in recruiting
high-quality teachers, due in Part to me difficulties of paying them
well. Collective bargaining mechanisms do not provide incentives for the
best people to enter or remain in the profession and likely hold the
average pay down: given the uniform salary structure, increases in
salary are bound to be unrelated to increases in effectiveness, making
large pay raises politically problematic. This is likely one of the main
reasons that teacher salaries now lag those in other professions. In the
1940s, the salaries of male teachers were slightly above the average pay
for all male college graduates, and female teachers had higher salaries
than 70 percent of other female college graduates. Today, despite the
collective bargaining process, the salaries of male teachers are at the
30th percentile of the distribution of all college graduates, and women
who teach are at the 40th percentile of their college-educated peers.
Teachers' salaries today are based on credentials and years of
experience, factors that are at best weakly related to productivity. In
a competitive marketplace, a firm must compensate employees according to
their productivity or risk bankruptcy. Yet no school district goes out
of business if it retains ineffective teachers and pays them as much as
effective ones. Salaries become political footballs, and it is often
awkward for politicians to explain why a large pay increase goes equally
to ineffective and effective teachers.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The challenge of implementing reform of the teaching profession
remains considerable. Most of the benefits of implementing the
"thought experiment" explored here would be fully realized
only many decades later, while the costs of economic, and especially
political, reform must be paid at the beginning. These costs would be
steep, as they would likely negatively affect some of the most vocal
constituents in education policy: current teachers.
The magnitude of the above valuations of teacher effectiveness,
however, suggest that we should be willing to consider more radical
reforms than have been commonplace in recent decades. Salaries several
times higher than those paid teachers today would be economically
justified if teachers were compensated according to their effectiveness.
But unless we can replace the current system with one that better links
teacher recruitment, compensation, and retention to effectiveness, we
should expect both our schools and our economy to underperform relative
to their potential. The cost to the nation at a time of intensifying
international competition is high indeed.
Eric A. Hanushek is a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution,
Stanford University.