Mounting debt: the long economic boom enabled school districts nationwide to fund expensive reforms and hefty pay raises. Now, however, they are finding it nearly impossible to cut costs and balance their budgets. What makes it so tough for districts to downsize?
Fullerton, Jon
In April 2003,Joseph Olchefske, a nationally recognized reformer,
announced his intention to resign as superintendent of the Seattle
Public Schools. Surprisingly, given his background in investment banking
and his previous experience as the school district's chief
financial officer, Olchefske was felled by a financial crisis. In the
fall of 2002, the school district had discovered an unexpected $23
million deficit for the previous fiscal year. The district was on track
to ledger another $12 million deficit for the 2002-03 fiscal year.
About a month later, Dennis Chaconas was fired as superintendent of
the Oakland, California, public schools. New software, installed so that
the school district could better understand its finances, had uncovered
a $40 million deficit from the previous year. The deficit for the
current year was expected to be equally large. To keep the district
solvent, the state of California provided a $100 million line of credit
and took over the district's operations, stripping the school board
of all but advisory powers and appointing an administrator to replace
Chaconas. Although Oakland had long been known as a troubled school
district, it had appeared to be moving in the right direction under
Chaconas. Teacher turnover was down and test scores were up.
Unlike the financial chicanery that doomed corporate titans like
Enron and WorldCom (now MCI), intentional corruption does not seem to
have been behind either of these crises. Deliberate malfeasance has
played a role in many a school district's financial distress (as in
Compton, California), but Seattle and Oakland fell into difficulty while
they seemed to be on the upswing. Why can even school districts that are
apparently healthy suddenly find themselves on the verge of insolvency?
This question will become increasingly urgent in the coming months,
given the grim budget outlook that most states are facing. The problem
is particularly acute in California (the primary focus of this article),
where the state government, which largely dictates K-12 spending, is in
the midst of a financial crisis.
The specific path to financial distress is, of course, unique in
each case. Any number of factors, from excessively generous concessions
at the bargaining table to a fiscal crisis at the state level, can throw
a district into financial turmoil. The common way of dealing with these
crises is to focus on the immediate causes of financial distress and to
treat them as a straight-forward management problem. However, such
crises are more properly understood as the result of underlying
political and legal realities that prevent districts from managing their
finances properly.
Four general factors can interact to create financial instability.
First, the dynamics of public funding and the budgeting process
encourage school districts to spend their entire funding allocation,
creating a cost structure that is difficult to adjust down when revenue
drops or fails to grow at an expected rate. Second, districts are
constrained in how they can spend money and in the financial engineering
options open to them. Third, the lack of attention afforded to the nuts
and bolts of financial management in K-12 public education can result in
naive oversight and inadequate management-information systems that can
delay appropriate responses to emerging financial crises. Finally,
school district finances are lodged within a larger political
environment. Politicians and state officials may find ways to help push
districts over the financial edge in order to accomplish their own
purposes.
The Downsides of Incrementalism
Given that school districts largely do not have to face the
vagaries of "selling" their services to fickle consumers, one
might think that balancing the budget would be fairly straight-forward.
Not so. The typical district has a budgeting process that results in its
permanently "living on the edge," with revenues just matching
costs. When hard times arrive, it is difficult for districts to adjust
for a variety of reasons.
The first reason is the use of incremental budgeting. That is,
school districts generally determine their current year's budget by
taking the previous year's budget and adding or subtracting
incremental spending to each major item. By contrast, zero-based
budgeting asks managers to examine the services they are required to
deliver and then build up their cost structure from scratch. Another
strategy, activity-based costing and its derivatives, separates the
costs of various activities within a business. Then, by looking at
external benchmarks and generating ideas internally, managers search for
ways to reduce the costs of these activities while delivering the same
level of service (if such a level of service is even needed). The goal
of using these budgeting methods is to ensure that the organization
aligns its costs with its strategy and most valuable activities.
The downsides of the incremental approach are obvious when they are
compared with methods that are more tightly focused on value. Making
piecemeal changes to district priorities through a fragmented series of
increments based on last year's budget will not ensure that the
organization is carrying out the strategically correct activities or
that it is executing them in a cost-effective manner. Thus when cuts
need to be made, in the name of "fairness" they are often
imposed as flat percentage cuts to each department across the board,
ignoring both the relative efficiency and the relative importance of
various departments. This method in fact provides an incentive for
inefficiency: the fatter a department gets, the better it can survive
the inevitable budget cycles.
Nevertheless, as the political scientist Aaron Wildavsky pointed
out years ago, the incremental approach has a lot going for it in the
governmental sphere. First, it is simpler than the other approaches.
Large urban school districts are complex, multilevel organizations with
hundreds of sources of revenue, each with its own set of requirements
and constraints. During the 2001-02 school year, the Los Angeles Unified
School District received funding from well over 200 federal and state
grants and entitlement programs. Any attempt at zero-based budgeting
would require decisionmakers to understand and work within the
constraints imposed by these funding streams, each of which is typically
earmarked for a specific group of students or a particular school
program. Much of the remaining money is devoted to salaries, largely for
teachers. In short, most of the school district's funding is
already spoken for. This makes zero-based budgeting or even
activity-based costing almost pointless from a budget officer's
point of view, since so little of a district's funds are available
for reallocation.
These value-oriented reviews can also be dangerous for managers in
the public sphere to undertake. School boards and superintendents are
justifiably hesitant to mobilize too many stakeholders against them at
once by saying, "Let's rethink our whole approach." In
normal years, the incremental approach enables district leaders to limit
the political stresses around budgeting by focusing on a few specific
changes. As a result, the incremental approach is likely to lead a long
and healthy life in school district budgeting. Unfortunately, this also
means that school districts will be exposed to all the flaws of
incrementalism: spending patterns that are poorly aligned to strategic
priorities; fragmented educational programs; and little ability to
quickly restructure resources across departments and schools.
Use It or Lose It
School districts also face strong incentives to spend their entire
funding allocation in any given year. In the private sector, profits are
good. They can be used to grow the business, to provide a cushion during
downturns, or to reward investors. School districts, however, are
reluctant to generate surpluses (the public sector's analogue for
profits). Like most government agencies, school districts operate under
conditions of "use it or lose it." The assumption is that if
they don't spend the money, they didn't need it. Even if a
school district were to control its costs enough to generate a
significant surplus, the extra funds would immediately become a target
for outside interests. Large surpluses suggest to politicians that too
much money is being put into the schools and to unions that too little
is being paid to teachers.
For instance, in 2002, after a spring of difficult cost-cutting,
administrators in Los Angeles discovered that the school district had a
substantially larger ending balance than projected. The union saw this
as proof that the district could afford raises for teachers and that
some unpopular budget cuts, such as increases in class size, were
unnecessary. In the spring of 2003, union-backed candidates ousted two
incumbent school board members. This was the result of several factors,
but the previous year's budget cuts and unexpectedly large ending
balance played a significant role in mobilizing the union. It is thus
little wonder that districts attempt to "kiss" a zero or a
statutorily established minimum balance every year.
The most popular way of soaking up excess revenues is to increase
salaries and to hire additional school personnel, especially in
districts that have difficulty attracting and retaining qualified
teachers. Thus in June 2000, during the best of financial times for
California, the Oakland school district gave teachers a 24 percent
salary increase (in addition to the normal step increases). While
increasing teachers' salaries pleases teachers and their unions,
hiring additional teachers makes class sizes more manageable, pleasing
parents and teachers alike. Moreover, reductions in class size are at
times encouraged by the state through significant financial support, as
in California. As a result, districts' personnel costs tend to keep
pace with growth in district revenues. For example, during the five-year
period from 1996-97 to 2001-02, increases in personnel costs outstripped
increases in district revenues in 14 of the 20 largest California school
districts (see Figure 1). While such changes are politically popular and
can improve a district's ability to recruit qualified teachers,
they are difficult to reverse. Personnel costs are notoriously
"sticky"--easy to increase but hard to reduce.
Slippery Revenues
The problem with building up costs to match revenues is that school
districts do not generate their own revenues and cannot control their
service obligations.
At one time, the majority of school funds came from the local
community in the form of property taxes. The movement to equalize spending among rich and poor communities changed all that. In 1950
localities provided about 57 percent of the revenues available to school
districts. By 2000 their share had dropped to 43 percent (see Figure 2).
Even this significantly understates the decline in local influence over
school district revenues. Many states, including California, Florida,
and Texas, either place caps on local property-tax rates or redistribute property-tax receipts when they exceed a certain level. Localities
cannot simply raise property-tax rates to the level they feel is
necessary to fund the schools.
The situation has reached an extreme in California. First, the
California Supreme Court's 1971 Serrano decision required the state
to make school spending between rich and poor districts more equitable.
Second, Proposition 13, which the voters passed in 1978, placed a cap on
property taxes. Finally, in 1988, Proposition 98 required the state to
spend a minimum amount of the general fund on education. As a result,
the share of school spending from local revenues dropped from 62 percent
in 1970 to 31 percent in 2000 (see Figure 3). With no real power over
revenues, local school boards in California face little incentive to
conserve on costs as a means to lower tax rates.
K-12 education is the largest line item in most state budgets,
representing 22 percent of total state spending and more than a third of
general fund expenditures (money that comes from state taxes and is not
earmarked for specific purposes). Thus school district funding is tied
to the sources of state general funds--typically receipts from sales
taxes and income taxes. In turn, these receipts are closely tied to
state economic conditions, even more closely than property taxes are.
Therefore, when states face significant deficits, funding for education
must be cut. And, unlike some other government agencies, which can
choose to reduce services by letting roads go unpaved, releasing
prisoners early, or turning away indigents in search of health care, the
schools cannot simply stop educating kids. They must serve all students
within their area, and they have a multitude of mandates they must
fulfill whatever their funding situation.
When an economic downturn hits, school districts suffer revenue
cuts, but cutting costs is difficult. The typical district spends more
than 80 percent of its revenues on salaries and benefits, and salaries
tend to ratchet only one way--up. In addition, as Michael Podgursky
recently noted in these pages (see "Fringe Benefits," Check
the Facts, Summer 2003), districts often provide generous
defined-benefit plans to both current employees and retirees. With
double-digit annual increases in health-care expenses, the relative cost
of benefits to school districts can be expected to rise substantially.
What's more, many school districts have almost unlimited
obligations to provide health benefits to their retirees. In 2002, the
Los Angeles school district had estimated liabilities of $4.8 billion in
unfunded benefits for its current and future retirees, an amount greater
than the value of its net assets.
A final complexity in the district budgeting process comes from its
timing. Many school districts are required to settle on a budget before
they know what their revenue will be. In the spring of 2003, due to a
large projected deficit and the difficult cuts it implied, the state of
California had not adopted a budget by July 1, the deadline for school
districts to turn in their budgets--budgets that are based,
theoretically, on the funding elucidated in the state budget. This
places a further brake on school boards' ability to cut costs
aggressively. It can be hard for board members to justify taking
political heat for unpopular cuts before knowing exactly how large the
revenue gap will be.
When a Dollar Is Not a Dollar
One of the fundamental principles of financial management in the
private sector is that money is fungible. In other words, a dollar
received as revenue from a customer can be used for many things. Part of
it pays for the good or service received by the customer. But the profit
from that revenue may also be reinvested in the company or paid out to
shareholders and to the firm's employees.
By contrast, large public school districts receive a substantial
portion of their revenues in the form of categorical or restricted
funds. Each of these revenue streams has strict limitations on how the
money can be spent. For instance, federal Title I funding for
compensatory education must be spent only on low-performing students,
unless the entire school qualifies as a Title I school. From the
legislator's point of view, this makes perfect sense: legislation
was enacted and programs created with the intent of targeting a
particular group or solving a particular problem. Such monies are
intended to "supplement, not supplant" existing district
expenditures.
District managers, however, are faced with a crazy quilt of funding
streams for purposes that match the district's strategic priorities
only by happenstance, if at all. In order to achieve the district's
goals, good managers will attempt to find ways to use categorical and
restricted monies that are not in line with the district's aims to
free up other funds that can then be used to pursue its priorities.
The result is what I will call the "dance of
supplantation." District managers attempt to use restricted,
categorical funding to free up unrestricted, general-fund monies while
the providers of revenue attempt to prevent them from doing so. Managers
performing this dance with too much gusto can suddenly find they have
danced over a cliff. Money they were counting on being able to use might
be withheld. Worse, money they have already spent may need to be paid
back. For instance, in 1991 the Richmond Unified School District in
California went bankrupt. One of the contributing factors was
superintendent Walter Marks's overly aggressive repurposing of
funds. The district found that it had to repay the state for $4 million
that had been earmarked for desegregation efforts and then
inappropriately spent.
The dance of supplantation takes on special importance when
districts enter times of financial crisis. Unlike private businesses,
where a surplus in one division can provide cash for the whole company,
districts cannot typically use, say, their surplus nutrition funds to
pay for instruction, or vice versa. During the recent financial crisis
in Oakland, one of the strategies proposed by the board and
superintendent was to repurpose bond monies intended for construction to
the general fund, in repayment for general-fund monies already spent for
construction. Perhaps not surprisingly, the state attorney general
disallowed this maneuver. This took away Oakland's last alternative
to a state loan and takeover.
In California, districts are further constrained in that they do
not have full access to their reserves. Districts are required to
deposit reserves with their local counties to prevent them from
foolishly investing the funds. (Until 1994, nothing prevented the
counties from making foolish investments. That's when Orange County
lost its school districts' funds as well as its own after a series
of highly speculative trades plunged the county into bankruptcy.) In
addition, some special funds held by the county, such as workers'
compensation, cannot be used for other purposes once the district has
paid into them. So even if a district has overfunded a particular
reserve, it does not have access to that money in times of need. While
this eliminates the temptation to raid funds for short-term gain, it
also places limits on districts' financial flexibility. When a
district finds itself in financial trouble, it must respond with one
hand tied behind its back.
The Perils of Instructional Leadership
While the budgeting and finance issues discussed above make it easy
for districts to get into financial trouble, poor financial management
skills among district staff and incomplete information flow can turn
what would have been a painful budget-cutting exercise into insolvency.
It begins at the top. While public companies can ensure that their
boards of directors are stocked with financial know-how, this is not
possible for elected school boards. As a result, many school boards lack
basic financial literacy. The complicated structuring of district
revenues and the lack of single, consolidated financial reports further
undermine board members' ability to monitor the financial
situation. Finally, the frequent turnover of boards and superintendents
limits institutional memory. Any expertise board members have
accumulated is lost as they move on.
Moreover, boards tend to hire superintendents who may not have a
deep level of financial expertise themselves. In the private sector,
CEOs are expected both to provide strategic direction for a company and
to ensure that the finances are in order. Business leaders would scoff
at the idea that the financial side of a business should be isolated
from the production side. In the world of education, however, the
ability to provide "instructional leadership" is considered
separate from and more important than mere financial management. This
can result in weak financial oversight. Dennis Chaconas, the former
superintendent in Oakland, admitted that he relied on others to deal
with the financial aspects of the district. "I concentrated on
academics," he told the Oakland Tribune. "I thought that was
the most important issue facing the district." In Seattle, Moss
Adams Advisory Services, brought in to determine what went wrong, noted
that the explicit "kids first" focus of the district resulted
in an organizational culture that did not take financial management
seriously enough--despite the superintendent's considerable
experience with finance. Such an environment can result in middle
managers not being held accountable, even if they fail to stay within
budget or to make needed cuts.
Compounding the naivete of top management can be a general dearth
of talent in the business departments themselves. While there are many
fine CFOs and business managers in America's school districts, the
overall pool of talent in the finance department is not comparable to
the private sector. The reasons are not hard to discern. First, many
critical business managers in large school systems rose into these
positions "through the ranks" and may have started out in an
unrelated position, such as teacher or principal. While such an organic
process of "growing your own" can result in strong employees
who know the specific issues and details of their district, these
employees have not been exposed to approaches outside of the closed
world of education and have not gone through the professional crucible of working for a large accounting firm, as many private-sector managers
do. As a result these administrators may inherit inefficient and
tremendously outdated processes with no clear ideas on how to improve
them.
Second, it is not even clear why business managers from the private
sector would want to work for a school district. As discussed above,
financial management (and human-resources management and
information-technology management) is typically not considered a
"core" activity for a district. Moreover, it is often
politically difficult to pay such managers substantially more than
managers on the instructional side of the district. The result is that
good business managers can get a lot more money doing the same job
outside of the public school system (see Figure 4). This is not true of
even the finest teachers, who would be hard pressed to find a similar
teaching job at a greater salary outside of a public school. Unless and
until school districts are willing to pay competitive salaries, we can
expect them to be short on business talent.
Since information technology is not considered a core activity
either, large school districts are notorious for having antiquated
information systems. Large private companies with thousands of employees
will typically have accounting and personnel systems that connect the
budget to ongoing financials to human resources to operations to sales.
The technology behind such systems is generally based on a few standard
platforms (SAP, PeopleSoft, Oracle) and installed by a major IT service
provider (IBM Global Services, Accenture).
School districts, however, often have multiple, cobbled-together
systems developed over a long period of time and based on nonstandard architecture. As a result, budgeting systems do not connect
automatically with accounting systems, and both may be isolated from the
human-resources systems that track who is hired, when, and for how much.
The combination of weak financial expertise and outdated IT systems
results in problems being uncovered late and critical degrees of freedom
being lost. Unless departments devote substantial time and effort to
coordinating data flow, it is easy for the number of people hired to
exceed the number of positions in the budget. Overspending can continue
undetected for months. Oakland provides a dramatic example of this,
discovering that it was in trouble only after it was already $40 million
in the hole. At this point, Oakland was already underwater and, unless
the district were able to free up other restricted monies, it would
ultimately need a bailout.
The fix is to install newer and more-integrated IT systems. This
can be quite expensive (potentially more than $100 million for the
largest districts) and is an easy political target. Interested parties
might want to spend the money required on teacher salaries rather than
on expensive new systems for the district bureaucrats.
The Usefulness of Insolvency
School districts are unavoidably part of a larger political
environment. Cities, counties, and state legislators and regulators all
have political interests in the schools that may or may not line up with
the interests of a school district's current board and management.
In fact, these outside actors might secretly applaud a district's
financial collapse because of the opportunities it creates.
Although some states have "academic bankruptcy" laws, it
is difficult for a district to be taken over for failure of its
education system. This is because many factors aside from the quality of
a school district contribute to students' academic performance.
Financial mismanagement, however, is much more clear-cut. If a district
cannot make payroll or pay its bills, its operations will cease unless
someone steps in to provide the needed liquidity. Since schools cannot
simply stop operating, as a business would, state or county governments
find themselves having to step in to provide a loan to the district.
This hands politicians a much more palatable excuse to take over a
district than "academic bankruptcy." Allowing a district
management team that has already shown questionable financial judgment
to continue in office would put state monies directly at risk.
For instance, in 1995 the Illinois legislature handed the
governance of Chicago schools to the mayor at least partly as a result
of a massive deficit. Newark, Cleveland, Compton, Detroit, East St.
Louis, and Philadelphia have all been the subjects of outside
intervention in which fiscal mismanagement was one of the arguments for
action. For those in favor of significant changes to district governance
or management, bankruptcy can be a good thing.
What Is to Be Done?
Using bankruptcy or severe deficit spending as a tool for gaining
control of schools is, unfortunately, quite expensive for the state and
for the students. Either the state or the district will have to make up
the deficit, and the bankrupt school district will find itself even more
financially constrained than before, with today's students
receiving fewer resources on account of yesterday's mistakes. So
what can be done to prevent such occurrences in the future?
First it is important to understand that most of the problems
discussed here have been structural issues resulting from how school
systems are governed and regulated. As long as school board members are
elected, we cannot guarantee that districts will have either the
knowledge or the will to manage their finances well. We also cannot
eliminate the multitude of political interests and pressures that shape
budgeting decisions. Given this situation, there is a set of realistic
reforms that states and districts could undertake right now, as well as
deeper reforms that would change the very structure of school districts
and thus get closer to the roots of the problem.
Let me discuss the more realistic reforms. First, the state and
federal finance systems for schools tend to be too complex and impose
far too many limitations on how districts can spend their money. The
current move toward block grants by state and federal agencies is a
welcome one, as it has the potential to allow districts sufficient
flexibility to pursue their strategic goals and to reallocate money as
needed.
Second, board members should demand of their superintendents both
instructional leadership and financial expertise. District leaders
should also undertake the appropriate training to make themselves better
financial managers. In addition, the leadership should bring in
independent outside financial and business experts to monitor district
finances before a crisis erupts. States can help districts in this
process by requiring financial training for new school board members.
After receiving the appropriate training and hearing from outside
experts, school district officials might end the practice of
"starving" their business functions in order to focus on
instruction and would install IT systems that provided adequate
surveillance of the overall operations of the district. These systems
should reliably track revenues, positions, and spending on a timely
basis.
Finally, districts should develop robust multiyear financial
projections and contingency plans that clearly specify how the district
will adjust if expected funding does not come through. The projections
should incorporate accurate (as opposed to ad hoc or historical)
projections of students and staffing requirements. Contingency plans
should be made part of salary negotiations.
Now let's look at some deeper, more structural reforms that
could lessen the likelihood of financial crises. First, appointed (as
opposed to elected) school boards would eliminate some of the multitude
of political interests and pressures that shape budgeting decisions.
While such boards certainly provide no guarantee of solvency, whoever
appoints the board could ensure that there is an adequate amount of
financial know-how present. Of course, such boards also represent a
dramatic step away from the relatively direct democratic control of
schools that predominates now and that many communities prize. A turn
towards appointed boards would be a major, and hotly contested, shift.
Second, choice-based reforms such as charter schools and vouchers,
if thoroughly implemented (and combined with more rational state
funding), could eliminate a significant amount of the complexity
associated with district finances. Each school would need to balance
only its own budget. In addition, the closer connection between schools
and parents could counteract the upward pressure that special interests
exercise on the budget. Most important, individual school-level
governance would lower the consequences of financial failure. Unlike
school districts, individual schools that pursued only
"instructional leadership" to the detriment of fiscal
stability could simply go out of business, their place taken by more
responsible peers. Unfortunately, if the state does not fund such
reforms at the appropriate level or ensure some level of competence on
the part of suppliers before they open schools, there may not be enough
responsible peers available to pick up the slack.
Of course, a lot more is at stake in each of these structural
reforms than better financial management. These reforms will not (and
should not) be judged solely on this one dimension, and their political
palatability varies dramatically across the country. However, as long as
school boards are elected and school districts are political
battlegrounds, it will be difficult to ensure that school systems manage
their finances responsibly.
Soaking Up Revenue (Figure 1)
When school districts face a rosy financial picture, they tend to
spend any additional revenues on higher salaries
and more teachers rather than saving money for a rainy day. In
California, many of the state's largest school districts
saw increase in personnel and revenue costs that exceeded their
increase in enrollment.
% Increase (*)
Personnel
Cost Revenue
School District Increase Increase
Elk Grove 41 26
Sacramento 41 32
Oakland 52 40
Long Beach 33 26
Los Angeles 28 26
(*) Increases from 1996-97 school year to 2001-02 school year. Cost
and revenue increase are calculated per average daily attendance to
adjust for changes in enrollment.
They are also adjusted for inflation.
SOURCE: California Department of Education
The Decline of Local Funding (Figure 2)
Nationwide, the movement to equalize spending between wealthy and poor
school districts has shifted
the funding of public education from the local to the state level. Thus
districts are now dependent on
a more volatile source of revenue, making it increasingly difficult to
keep their budget balanced.
% Share of Total School Funding
School Year Federal State Local
1949-1950 3 40 57
1959-1960 4 39 57
1969-1970 8 40 52
1979-1980 10 47 43
1989-1990 6 47 47
1999-2000 7 50 43
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Education
The California Experience (Figure 3)
The famed Proposition 13 placed a cap on local property taxes in
California--just one
reason why the local share of school funding was cut in half between
1970 and 2000
% Share of Total School Funding
School Year Federal State Local
1969-1970 6 32 62
1979-1980 11 66 23
1989-1990 7 67 26
1999-2000 9 60 31
SOURCE: U.S Department of Education
Lacking Financial Talent (Figure 4)
Skilled financial managers can earn substantially more in the private
sector than
they can working for a school district, creating a dearth
of talent in the business department that can lead to sloopy financial
controls.
CFO Base Pay 2002
Industry Annual Salary (in thousands of dollars)
Government/
Non-Profit (*) $170
Oakland Schools
Business
Officer $178
LA Schools
CFO $205
Education (*) $217
Health Care (*) $288
Financial
Services (*) $315
Computer
Services (*) $323
Retail/
Wholesale (*) $366
(*) Nationwide average for industry, Education average is primarily for
higher education
SOURCE: Tim Reason, "Facing the Bear: The 2002 Compensation Survey,"
CFO.com, November 1, 2002. Source data from Mercer Human Resources
Consulting,
Oakland Unified School District, and Los Angeles Unified School District
-Jon Fullerton is a vice president of the Urban Education
Partnership, based in Los Angeles, California.